Skip to main content
Log in

Trade, Politics, and the Poor: Is Sen Right and Bhagwati Wrong?

  • Published:
Studies in Comparative International Development Aims and scope Submit manuscript

An Erratum to this article was published on 17 January 2017

Abstract

The current debate between two of the world’s finest economists—Amartya Sen and Jagdish Bhagwati—has not only roiled India but also attracted global attention. Is trade liberalization associated with improved welfare outcomes for the poor, as Bhagwati contends? Or is Sen correct that policymakers in liberalizing economies need to change their governance priorities to focus on redistribution? This analysis draws on existing literature to develop testable hypotheses that attempt to resolve the Sen–Bhagwati divide. Using fixed effect panel regressions and simultaneous equation models, we find that although there is empirical support for both arguments, the results on balance favor Sen: The positive relationship between trade and improved poverty is conditional upon more equitable distributions of income. In effect, Bhagwati’s predictions about the beneficial impacts of openness on social welfare occur only in a subset of developing nations, findings which have very different implications for the poor in developing countries.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. New York Times “Rival Economists in Public Battle Over Cure for India’s Poverty” August 21, 2013.

  2. Amartya Sen refers to this as creating “two Indias,” one for the rich and one for the poor. See “Two Indias” New York Times. September 6, 2013.

  3. Aisbett (2007, p. 40) persuasively argues that cross-country comparisons are useful for examining the trade-poverty relationship because “it is very difficult to prove in the case of an individual country exactly which factor or combination of factors was responsible for its success or lack thereof.”

  4. Both infant mortality and life expectancy are used as broad measures of poverty (e.g., Ross 2006; McGuire 2010); they serve as proxies for the quality and presence of health and welfare programs, poverty and socioeconomic status, availability of clean drinking water, and environmental and social barriers that prevent access to basic health services.

  5. Some development scholars argue that the standard measures can improve without having any meaningful impact on the livelihoods (and freedoms) of the poor (Nussbaum and Sen 1993; Sen 1999).

  6. See Acemoglu and Robinson’s (2013) discussion of how various economists consider that good economic policies will overcome and often eliminate government inefficiencies. For example, Bhagwati and Panagariya (2013) argue that the policy focus should be on reducing industrial tariffs, agricultural protections, etc. Once overall productivity improves government can play a small but efficient role in directing social policies.

  7. The bottom line is that the recent trend of inequality research has focused on institutions that privilege power rather than emphasizing supply and demand. Even Piketty has recently backtracked on his central thesis in Capital in the Twenty-First Century to argue that “institutional changes and political shocks—which to a large extent can be viewed as endogenous to the inequality and development process itself—played a major role in the past and it will probably be the same in the future” (Piketty 2015, p. 48).

  8. Their logic is supported by two strands of empirical work in political economy: (1) studies finding that public goods are undersupplied when inequality is high (Easterly 2007; Perotti 1993; 1996; Waldmann 1992); (2) scholars providing evidence that high inequality is associated with the persistence of weak conflict-mediating institutions such as an ineffective (or absent) judiciary, corrupt bureaucracy, unbalanced media, and civil liberties and political rights which are arbitrarily administered (Easterly et al. 2006; Rodrik 1999).

  9. See Chandra (2002) and Blouin et al. (2007) for examples. Their analyses suggest that trade hurts the poor as knowledge spillovers in health lead to demands for specialized health care. This occurs through greater imports and domestic reproduction of health supplies, pharmaceuticals, equipment, insurance, and direct health services such as cross-border telehealth services (e.g., telediagnostics), movement of consumers to countries providing diagnosis and treatment, and cross-border movement of health care providers.

  10. We thank the authors for providing their dataset and replication files.

  11. Unless noted otherwise, the variables used in the analysis come from the Owen and Wu (2007) dataset. We updated this dataset for the years 2000 and 2005 by using data from Penn World Table 7.1 (Heston et al. 2012), from which the original data were also obtained.

  12. Owen and Wu utilize life expectancy by sex, while we use a combined measure.

  13. There may be some question as to how representative national life expectancy rates are of the health of the poor since the national rates reflect the entire population, including all income groups. Since poor countries are populated primarily by low-income individuals, however, the national rates should fairly closely mirror the actual rate among the nation’s poor.

  14. Bhagawati and Panagariya (2013, p. 183) argue the best way to improve the poor’s health conditions is to make cash transfers to senior female household members.

  15. Available at http://www.barrolee.com/. Accessed July 24, 2009.

  16. We multiply Ethnic Fractionalization by 100 to generate an index between 0 and 100.

  17. An effective instrument must be correlated with the endogenous variable but have no direct relationship with the dependent variable (Savun and Tirone 2011, p. 239). Electricity production satisfies the first criterion, as it is has been widely shown to be highly correlated with economic growth, even if the causal relationship between the two is still under analysis (Payne 2010). Although the second consideration, the exclusion restriction, is inherently untestable, existing research indicates that electricity consumption satisfies this requirement by having a direct impact on economic growth and an indirect impact on social development (see Leung and Meisen 2005).

  18. This data includes interpolated observations of income distribution for some of the years with missing observations, which is not uncommon in studies utilizing inequality data (see, for example, Rueda and Pontusson 2000). Missing observations for the period up to and including 1995 are interpolated based on the assumption that any changes between two observations are evenly distributed across the interval separating the two. Observations after 1995 use averages for years 2000 and 2005 incorporating all available observations in the preceding 5 years.

  19. The SERF index captures the degree to which a country has achieved the highest level of social and economic rights possible given its capacity. It does so by comparing estimates of what a country should be able to achieve (in the form of an estimated “Achievement Possibility Frontier”) to its observed values in each area. The difference between the two values is a reflection of the inclusiveness and effectiveness of the state’s policies and institutions. Available at http://www.serfindex.org/overview, accessed March 2, 2015.

  20. For a description of the SERF Index methodology, see Fukuda-Parr et al. (2009) and Randolph et al. (2001).

  21. As a measure which is slow to change over time, income inequality is highly correlated with both country and year fixed effects. The use of both of these fixed effects, as we do in models 1–1 through 2–2, would therefore risk type I bias by artificially attenuating the estimated coefficient on income inequality. For models 3–1 and beyond, we therefore drop the year fixed effects while maintaining those for individual countries.

  22. Due to the small sample sizes (75 observations) and the fact that most countries only have one observation, we drop country fixed effects from the models. We also omit the top and bottom 5 % of the distribution of the full SERF dataset to reduce the influence of outliers of the estimates, although the observed trends are consistent when these observations are included.

  23. We also confirm that the estimated conditional marginal effects are statistically different from one another by using post-estimation testing.

  24. The two sets of estimations differ upon whether trade can actual be harmful; openness does not have negative effects on poverty outcomes in the inequality models but appears to have detrimental effects on well-being when SERF is low.

  25. Narendra Modi unveils broad policy priorities, asks ministers to set 100-day agenda. (2014, May 29). The Hindustan Times. Retrieved from http://search.proquest.com/docview/1529942160?accountid=11091.

References

  • Acemoglu D, Robinson J. Why nations fail: the origins of power, prosperity, and poverty. New York: Crown Business; 2012.

    Google Scholar 

  • Acemoglu, D. and Robinson, J. Economics versus politics: pitfalls of policy advice. Massachusetts Institute of Technology Working Paper Series; 2013.

  • Aisbett E. Why are the critics so convinced that globalization is bad for the poor? In: Harrison A, editor. Globalization and poverty. Chicago: University of Chicago Press; 2007. p. 33–86.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Alesina A, Baqir R, Easterly W. Public goods and ethnic divisions. Q J Econ. 1999;114:1243–84.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Alesina A, Devleeschauwer A, Easterly W, Kurlat S, Wacziarg R. Fractionalization. J Econ Growth. 2003;8:155–94.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Amiti M, Davis DR. Trade, firms, and wages: theory of evidence. Review of Economic Studies. 2012;79:1–36.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Barro RJ, Lee JW. International data on educational attainment: updates and implications. Manuscript: Harvard University; 2000.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Baum, C.F., M.E. Schaffer and S. Stillman. Ivreg2: State module for extended instrumental variables /2SLS, GMM and AC/HAC, LIML, and k-class regression. Boston College Department of Economics, Statistical Software Components S425401. Downloadable from http://ideas.repec.org/c/boc/bocode/s425401.html; 2007.

  • Bell A, Jones K. Explaining fixed effects: random effects modeling of time-series cross-sectional and panel data. Political Science Research and Methods. 2015;3:133–53.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bergh, A & Nilsson, T. Globalization and absolute poverty: a panel data study. IFN Working Paper; 2011.

  • Bhagwati J, Panagariya A. Why growth matters: how economic growth in India reduced poverty and the lessons for other developing countries. New York: Public Affair; 2013.

    Google Scholar 

  • Blouin C, Heymann J, Drager N, editors. Negotiating across boundaries: promoting health in a globalized world, vol. 20. Montrreal, CA: McGill-Queens UP; 2007.

    Google Scholar 

  • Brambor T, Clark WR, Golder M. Understanding interaction models: improving empirical analyses. Polit Anal. 2006;14:63–82.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bussmann M. The effect of trade openness on women’s welfare and work life. World Dev. 2009;37:1027–38.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Caldwell JC. Education as a factor in mortality decline: an examination of Nigerian data. Popul Stud. 1979;33:395–413.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Castilho M, Menéndez M, Sztulman A. Trade liberalization, inequality, and poverty in Brazilian states. World Dev. 2012;40:821–35.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chandra R. Trade in health services. Bulletin of world health. Organization. 2002;80:158–63.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cornia GA. Globalization and health: results and options. Bull World Health Organ. 2001;79:83.

    Google Scholar 

  • Davis DR, Mishra P. Stolper-Samuelson is dead: and other crimes of both theory and data. In: Harrison A, editor. Globalization and poverty. Chicago: University of Chicago Press; 2007. p. 87–108.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Deininger KW, Squire LA. New data set measuring income inequality. The. World Bank Econ Rev. 1996;10:565–91.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dollar D, Kraay A. Trade, growth, and poverty. Econ J. 2004;114:F22–49.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dreze J, Sen A. An uncertain glory: India and its contradictions. Princeton UP: Princeton; 2013.

    Google Scholar 

  • Easterly W. Inequality does cause underdevelopment: insights from a new instrument. J Dev Econ. 2007;84:755–76.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Easterly W, Ritzan J, Woolcock M. Social cohesion, institutions, and growth. Econ Polit. 2006;18:103–20.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Engerman, S. L. and Sokoloff, K. L Factor endowments, inequality, and paths of development among new world economies. NBER Working Paper. 2002;9259.

  • Figini P, Santarelli E. Openness, economic reforms, and poverty: globalization in developing countries. The Journal of Developing Areas. 2006;39:129–51.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Filmer D, Hammer JS, Pritchett LH. Weak links in the chain: a diagnosis of health policy in poor countries. The World Bank Research Observer. 2000;15:99–224.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fukuda-Parr S, Lawson-Remer T, Randolph S. An index of economic and social rights fulfillment: concept and methodology. Journal of Human Rights. 2009;8:195–221.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Goldberg PK, Pavcnik N. The response of the informal sector to trade liberalization. J Dev Econ. 2003;72:463–96.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Goldberg, P. K., & Pavcnik, N. Trade, inequality, and poverty: what do we know? Evidence from recent trade liberalization episodes in developing countries (No. w10593). Natl Bur Econ Res; 2004.

  • Harrison, A. Globalization and poverty. No. w12347. Natl Bur Econ Res; 2006.

  • Harrison A, Hanson G. Who gains from trade reform? Some remaining puzzles. J Dev Econ. 1999;59:25–154.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hasan R, Mitra D, Ural BP. Trade liberalization, labor-market institutions and poverty reduction: evidence from Indian states. In India Policy Forum. 2007;3:71–122.

    Google Scholar 

  • Heston, A, Summers, R. and Allen, B. Penn World Table Version 7.1, Center for international comparisons of production, income and prices at the University of Pennsylvania; 2012.

  • Hobcraft J. Women’s education, child welfare, and child survival: a review of the evidence. Health Transition Review. 1993;3:159–75.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hoekman, B. and Winters, A. H. Trade and employment: stylized facts and research findings. World Bank Publications; 2005.

  • Jamison E, Jamison D, Hanushek E. The effects of education quality on income growth and mortality decline. Econ Educ Rev. 2007;26:771–88.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kovak, B. Overestimating the effect of complementarity on skill demand. B.E. J Econ Anal Policy. 2011;11.

  • Lake DA, Baum MA. The invisible hand of democracy political control and the provision of public services. Comparative Political Studies. 2001;34:587–621.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Leung CS, Meisen P. How electricity consumption affects social and economic development by comparing low, medium and high human development countries. GENI: San Diego, CA; 2005.

    Google Scholar 

  • Levine DI, Rothman D. Does trade affect child health? J Health Econ. 2006;25:538–54.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • MacDonald, R. and Majeed, M.T.. Distributional and poverty consequences of globalization: a dynamic comparative analysis for developing countries; 2010.

  • Maertens, M, Liesbeth, C., and Swinnen, J. F. M. Globalisation and poverty in Senegal: a worst case scenario? Eur Rev Agric Econ. 2011;jbq053.

  • Marshall, M. G. & Jaggers, K. Polity IV Data Set. [Computer file] College Park, MD: Center for International Development and Conflict Management, University of Maryland; 2002. Available from http://www.cidcm.umd.edu/polity/data/

  • Martens P, Akin SM, Maud H, Mohsin R. Is globalization healthy: a statistical indicator analysis of the impacts of globalization on health. Glob Health. 2010;6.

  • McGuire, J. W.Wealth, health, and democracy in East Asia and Latin America. Cambridge University Press; 2010.

  • Mukherjee N, Kriekhaus J. Globalization and human wellbeing. International Political Science Review. 2011;33:150–70.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • North DC, Wallis JJ, Weingast BR. Violence and social orders. Cambridge: Cambridge UP; 2013.

    Google Scholar 

  • Nussbaum M, Sen A. The quality of life. Oxford: Oxford UP; 1993.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Owen, A. L. & Wu, S. Is trade good for your health? Review of International Economics. 2007;15:660–682.

  • Payne JE. A survey of the electricity consumption-growth literature. Appl Energy. 2010;87:723–31.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Perotti R. Political equilibrium, income distribution, and growth. Review of Economic Studies. 1993;60:755–76.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Perotti R. Growth, income distribution, and democracy: what the data say. J Econ Growth. 1996;1:149–87.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Piketty T. About capital in the twenty-first century. Am Econ Rev. 2015;105:48–53.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Porto GG. Using survey data to assess the distributional effects of trade policy. J Int Econ. 2006;70:140–60.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Randolph S, Fukuda-Parr S, Lawson-Remer T. Economic and social rights fulfillment index: country scores and rankings. Journal of Human Rights. 2001;9:230–61.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rodriguez, F., & Rodrik, D. Trade policy and economic growth: a skeptic’s guide to cross-national evidence. In NBER Macroeconomics Annual. MIT Press. 2001;15:261–338.

  • Rodrik D. Where did all the growth go? External shocks, social conflict, and growth collapses. J Econ Growth. 1999;4:385–412.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Roeder, P.G. Ethnolinguistic fractionalization (ELF) indices, 1961 and 1985. Available from http//:weber.ucsd.edu/-proeder/elf.htm; 2001.

  • Ross M. Is democracy good for the poor? Am J Polit Sci. 2006;50:860–74.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rueda D, Pontusson J. Wage inequality and varieties of capitalism. World Politics. 2000;52:350–83.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Savun B, Tirone DC. Foreign aid, democratization and civil conflict: how does democracy aid affect civil conflict? Am J Polit Sci. 2011;55:233–46.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sen A. Development as freedom. Oxford: Oxford UP; 1999.

    Google Scholar 

  • Smith, R., Blouin, C. and Drager, N. International trade in health services and the GATS. World Bank Group; 2006.

  • Tsai MC. Economic and non-economic determinants of poverty in developing countries: competing theories and empirical evidence. Canadian Journal of Development Studies. 2006;27:267–85.

    Google Scholar 

  • Verhoogen E. Trade, quality upgrading and wage inequality in the Mexican manufacturing sector. Q J Econ. 2008;123:489–530.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Waldmann RJ. Income distribution and infant mortality. Q J Econ. 1992;107:1283–302.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wood A. Openness and wage inequality in developing countries: the Latin American challenge to east Asian conventional wisdom. World Economic Review. 1997;11:35–57.

    Google Scholar 

  • World Health Organization. Primary health care: now more than ever. World health report. http://www.who.int/whr/2008/whr08_en.pdf ; 2008.

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Nita Rudra.

Additional information

Author biographies had been missing and these information were now added after the reference list.

An erratum to this article is available at http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/s12116-017-9234-1.

Electronic supplementary material

ESM 1

(DOCX 29 kb)

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Rudra, N., Tirone, D.C. Trade, Politics, and the Poor: Is Sen Right and Bhagwati Wrong?. St Comp Int Dev 52, 1–22 (2017). https://doi.org/10.1007/s12116-016-9231-9

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s12116-016-9231-9

Keywords

Navigation