Skip to main content
Log in

Evaluation of the Matching Process of Disabled People Through a Macroeconomic Approach: the Italian Case

  • Published:
Applied Spatial Analysis and Policy Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This paper estimates a spatial matching function for disabled people by using a panel of 20 Italian regions over the period 2006–2011. According to the results obtained, in the regional labour market analysed there is a congestion effect among unemployed disabled people, due to an excess of unemployed disabled people compared to available vacancies.

In terms of policy, it is necessary to promote policy actions aimed at supporting private firms in their production processes, especially for those with a high number of temporary layoff hours.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. In the Appendix A we report some information on the Law 68/99.

  2. By market conditions we mean levels of new matches, vacancies stocks and unemployment stocks.

  3. After implementing the SDM without checking for a spatial process in the error term, Lottman (2012) finds that residuals are characterized by spatial correlation. This result suggests that the model with only exogenous variables lagged in the space, captures partially the spatial autocorrelation in the data. Consequently, it is relevant to consider the spatial process in terms of error, too.

  4. Lottman (2012) criticizes the use of a binary contiguity matrix because it is not sufficient to fully capture the spatial relationships among geographical units; on the contrary she suggests to use a matrix that takes into account commuting between different local labour markets. In the case of geographical units such as provinces, local labour markets, or smaller geographical units, the use of a matrix that takes into account the phenomenon of commuting (commuting that takes place within a region) is justified; in the case of larger geographical units (such as regions) it does not seem reasonable to think of a commuting to work that goes beyond neighboring regions. For this reason in our case the use of a binary contiguity matrix seems justified, as it takes into account commuting between adjacent regions. In addition, it is difficult to think about a matrix that takes into account commuting in the case of disabled people.

  5. A binary contiguity matrix is preferable, in the case of disabled workers, to a matrix that takes into account commuting among distant regions, for the following two reasons:

    • disabled people are not readily available to mobility (Raia 2006). Disabled people by their nature are obviously not very mobile, as they are often dependent on their household, and their medical care is also linked to their residence;

    • disabled people who is looking for work through Law 68/99 must register in the employment centers of residence, therefore migration following cyclical unemployment is unlikely.

  6. We use a set of instrument variable L(lnU, lnV, WlnU, WlnV, W 2 lnU, W 2 lnV, T 2 lnM), that is, regressing WlnM on L(lnU, lnV, WlnU, WlnV, W 2 lnU, W 2 lnV) and TlnM on L(lnU, lnV, WlnU, WlnV, W 2 lnU, W 2 lnV, T 2 lnM), where with W2 we indicate the second-order binary contiguity matrix (Anselin 1988). In the case of temporally lagged dependent variable, we use as additional instrument the temporal lag of second order of dependent variable (T 2 lnM) (see Hsiao 2003).

  7. In this case, ISFOL does not make a distinction between unemployed people who are looking for a job and unemployed people who are not looking for a job; for this reason, unemployment variable will be distorted upwards.

  8. Through the agreements, that are signed by the interested parties (workers, employers, provincial offices for the employment of disabled workers and authorities that promote labour integration), it is possible to define a personalized program of interventions to overcome barriers related to the inclusion in the workplace. The agreements represent the tool by which the law seeks to promote the integration targeted, through a gradual labour integration of people with disabilities, aimed at the achievement of the employment obligations.

  9. The inclusion of disabled people in the labour market formally takes place through public employment centers, which are involved in the matching process between supply and demand for the employment of disabled people.

  10. Wilthagen’s definition connects the term flexicurity with a form of public policy aimed at disadvantaged workers groups. In particular, we refer to a policy strategy that combines both the flexibility of the labour market and workers’ safety with emphasis on the most vulnerable groups inside and outside the labour market (Wilthagen and Rogoswski 2002; Wilthagen and Tros 2004).

References

  • Agovino, M., & Garofalo, A. (2014). Flexicurity index for disabled people: evidence from Italy. Rivista Internazionale di Sceinze Sociali, 4, 357–382.

  • Agovino, M., & Rapposelli, A. (2012). Employment of disabled people according to Law 68/99. A multidimensional analysis at regional level. Rivista Internazionale di Scienze Sociali. vol. 1/2012.

  • Agovino, M., & Rapposelli, A. (2013). Inclusion of disabled people in the Italian labour market: an efficiency analysis of Law 68/99 at regional level. Quality and Quantity, 47(3), 1577–1588.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Agovino, M., & Rapposelli, A. (2014). Employment of disabled people in the private sector. An analysis at the level of Italian Provinces according to article 13 of Law 68/99. Quality and Quantity, 48(3), 1537–1552.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Akaike, H. (1973). Information theory and an extension of the maximum likelihood principle. In B. N. Petrov & F. Csaki (Eds.), 2nd international symposium on information theory (pp. 267–281). Budapest: Akademiai Kiado.

    Google Scholar 

  • Anderson, P., & Burgess, S. (2000). Empirical matching functions: estimation and interpretation using state-level data. The Review of Economics and Statistics, 82(1), 93–102.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Anselin, L. (1988). Spatial econometrics: Methods and models. Dordrecht: Kluwer.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Arellano, M., & Bover, O. (1995). Another look at the instrumental-variable estimation of error-components models. Journal of Econometrics, 68, 29–52.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Arellano, M., & Bond, S. R. (1991). Some tests of specification for panel data: Monte Carlo evidence and an application to employment equations. Review of Economic Studies, 58, 277–297.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Blundell, R. W., & Bond, S. R. (1998). Initial conditions and moment restrictions in dynamic panel data models. Journal of Econometrics, 87, 115–143.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Boone, J. & Van Ours, J.C. (2004), Effective active labour market policies. CEPR Discussion No. 4707.

  • Broersma, L., & Van Ours, J. C. (1999). Job searchers, job matches and the elasticity of matching. Labour Economics, 6(1), 77–93.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Burda, M. C. (1993) Modelling exits from unemployment in Eastern Germany: a matching function approach. CEPR Discussion Papers 800, C.E.P.R. Discussion Papers.

  • Burda, M., & Profit, S. (1996). Matching across space: evidence on mobility in the Czech Republic. Labour Economics, 3, 255–278.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Burdett, K., Coles, M. & Van Ours, J.C. (1994) Temporal aggregation bias in stock-flow models. CEPR Discussion Papers n. 967.

  • Burgess, S., & Profit, S. (2001). Externalities in the matching of workers and firms in Britain. Labour Economics, 8, 313–333.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Coe, D., & Snower, D. (1997). Policy complementarities: the case for fundamental labour market reform. IMF Staff Papers, 44, 1–35.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Coles, M. G., & Smith, E. (1996). Cross-section estimation of the matching function: evidence from England and Wales. Economica, 63, 589–597.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Coles, M. G., & Smith, E. (1998). Marketplaces and matching. International Economic Review, 39, 239–254.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Elhorst, J. P., & Fréret, S. (2009). Evidence of political yardstick competition in France using a two-regime spatial Durbin model with fixed effects. Journal of Regional Science, 49(5), 931–951.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • European Commission (2006a) Effective European active labour market policies. In: European Commission (eds.), Employment in Europe (pp. 119–172).

  • European Commission. (2006b). Employment in Europe 2006. Brussels: European Commission.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fahr, R. & Sunde, U. (2001a) Strategic hiring behavior in empirical matching. IZA Discussion Paper, n. 320.

  • Fahr, R. & Sunde, U. (2001b) Disaggregate matching finctions. IZA Discussion Paper, n. 335.

  • Fahr, R. & Sunde U. (2002) Employment status, endogenous regional mobility, and spatial dependencies in labor markets. IZA Discussion Paper, n.521.

  • Fahr, R. & Sunde, U. (2003) Spatial aspects of job creation: evidence from Western Germany. Royal Economic Society Annual Conference 75.

  • Fahr, R., & Sunde, U. (2004). Occupational job creation: patterns and implications. Oxford Economic Papers, 56, 407–435.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fahr, R., & Sunde, U. (2006a). Regional dependencies in job creation: an efficiency analysis for Western Germay. Applied Economics, 38, 1193–1206.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fahr, R., & Sunde, U. (2006b). Spatial mobility and competition for jobs: some theory and evidence for Western Germany. Regional Science and Urban Economics, 36, 803–825.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fahr, R., & Sunde, U. (2009). Did the Hartz reforms speed-up the matching process? A macro-evaluation using empirical matching functions. German Economic Review, 10(3), 284–316.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gregg, P., & Petrongolo, B. (2005). Stock-flow matching and the performance of the labor market. European Economic Review, 49, 1987–2011.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hays, J. C., Kachi, A., & Franzese, R. J. (2009). A spatial model incorporating dynamic, endogenous network interdependence: a political science application. Statistical Methodology, 7, 406–428.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hynninen, S. M. (2005). Matching across space: evidence from Finland. Labour, 19(4), 749.765.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hsiao, C. (2003) Analysis of panel data. 2nd edition, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press (Econometric Society monograph no. 34).

  • Ilmakunnas, P., & Pesola, H. (2003). Regional labour market matching functions and efficiency analysis. Labour, 17, 413–437.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kano, S., & Ohta, M. (2005). Estimating a matching function and regional matching efficiencies: Japanese panel data for 1973–1999. Japan and the World Economy, 17, 25–41.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lottman, F. (2012). Spatial dependencies in German matching functions. Regional Science and Urban Economics, 42, 27–41.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Martin, J., & Grubb, D. (2001). What works and for whom: a review of OECD countries’ experiences with active labour market policies. Swedish Economic Review, 8, 9–56.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ministry of Employment (2006–2007) Quarta relazione al parlamento sullo stato di attuazione della legge 12 marzo 1999, n. 68, Norme per il diritto al lavoro dei disabili. Roma.

  • Ministry of Employment (2008–2009) Quinta relazione al parlamento sullo stato di attuazione della legge 12 marzo 1999, n. 68, Norme per il diritto al lavoro dei disabili. Roma.

  • Ministry of Employment (2010–2011) Quinta relazione al parlamento sullo stato di attuazione della legge 12 marzo 1999, n. 68, Norme per il diritto al lavoro dei disabili. Roma.

  • Orlando, N., & Patrizio, M. (2006). Il collocamento mirato dei disabili: l’applicazione della legge 68/1999 nella Provincia di Bolzano. In G. Parodi (Ed.), Aspetti socioeconomici della disabilità (pp. 179–216). Roma: ARACNE editrice.

    Google Scholar 

  • Petrangolo, B., & Pissaridies, C. (2001). Looking into the black box: a survey of the matching function. Journal of Economic Literature, 39, 390–431.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Raia, S. (2006). Collocamento obbligatorio? Questioni del futuro prossimo. In G. Parodi (Ed.), Aspetti socioeconomici della disabilità (pp. 179–216). Roma: Aracne editrice.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rey, S. J., & Montouri, B. D. (1999). US regional income convergence: a spatial econometric perspective. Regional Studies, 33(2), 143–156.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schwarz, G. (1978). Estimating the dimension of a model. Annals of Statistics, 6, 461–464.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stevens, M. (2007). New microfoundations for the aggregate matching function. International Economic Review, 48(3), 847–868.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wilthagen, T., & Rogoswski, R. (2002). The legal regulation of transitional labour markets. In B. Gazier & G. Schmid (Eds.), The dynamics of full employment (pp. 233–273). Cheltenham: Edwar Elgar.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wilthagen, T., & Tros, F. (2004). The concept of flexicurity: a new approach to regulating employment and labour markets. European Review of Labour and Research, 10(2), 166–186.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to M. Agovino.

Appendices

Appendix A

Law 68/1999: Some Clarifications

Law 68/1999 is addressed to: “the working-age people suffering from physical, mental or sensory and intellectual disabilities, resulting in a reduced capacity to work by more than 45 %…”, “Disabled from work with a degree of incapacity of more than 33 %…”, “the blind or the deaf-mute…”, “war invalids, civil war invalids and disabled for service with disabilities ascribed from the first to the eighth category…”.

The prerequisite to take advantage of the benefits provided by Law 68/99 is the inclusion in the compulsory employment lists, that are held by the Employment Services of the provincial governments. Employment services usually enroll the applicant in the lists of compulsory employment conditionally to further assessment of disability by health care bodies. Next to the entering, the disabled person is then able to join job opportunities that come to the Employment Service from both public bodies and private companies, by filling out the reservation form.

Appendix B

In this Appendix we present the limitations of our analysis on the estimation of the matching function.

First of all, this matching function specification follows the hypothesis of the random matching approach. This approach, defined stock-stock approach, assumes that agents are matched randomly at any point in time, regardless of the duration of the research. It is opposite to another approach defined stock-flow approach, which assumes that unemployed people have complete information about possible jobs. Either they find a job instantaneously or they wait until new vacancies arrive on the market. Consequently, the stock-flow approach does not take into account only stocks but also inflows into unemployment and vacancies (Lottman 2012). The stock-stock approach has been widely criticized (see Coles and Smith 1998; Gregg and Petrongolo 2005; Petrangolo and Pissaridies 2001; Fahr and Sunde 2009), because it implicitly assumes an underlying undirected and random search process leading to matches between homogeneous unemployed and homogeneous vacancies.

In our case, we refer to the stock-stock approach due to unavailability of data on unemployed disabled people’s inflows and on specific vacancies for disabled people. The choice of the stock-stock approach represents a first limit of our analysis.

Another limitation, also highlighted by empirical literature, is represented by the choice of the dependent variable, as the variable used to measure matches tends to exclude the amount of employed job searchers. In many empirical studies this variable is omitted due to data unavailability (Broersma and Van Ours 1999). Many studies use total hires as a proxy for the number of matches, as hires include not only the unemployed who find a job but also persons out of the labour force flowing into a job and the flow of employed workers who are looking for another job. As a result, matching concerns the vacancies and all job seekers and we no longer have the matching of vacancies and unemployed job seekers. In particular, Broersma and Van Ours (1999) conclude that it is important to distinguish between employed people looking for jobs and unemployed people looking for a job, as if this distinction is not taken into account it produces a biased estimate of the parameters of the matching function. This distinction is relevant when we consider the spatial lag of vacancies among the regressors of the matching function. In particular, Fahr and Sunde (2002, 2003) find that the sign of the coefficient of spatially lagged vacancies depends on the type of dependent variable used: the effect is positive for all hires and hires of people who are already employed, while it is negative for unemployment outflows into employment. In our case we do not have information on the construction of the matching variable for disabled people, as ISFOL data does not explain whether the matching variable includes total hires (hires of those who are already employed and outflows of unemployed into employment) or only unemployment outflows into employment; therefore, the sign of the spatial lag of vacancies allow us to identify which type of dependent variable we are using.

Another issue of our empirical analysis is the temporal aggregation of data (Hynninen 2005). Since the matching function describes a process that is continuous in time, the use of data referring to discrete time introduces a problem of bias in the parameters estimates of the matching function. In particular, a greater aggregation of data will result in a greater bias (Burdett et al. 1994). It is advisable, therefore, to use highly disaggregated data over time (such as monthly or quarterly data). In fact, data with high temporal frequency are rarely available, especially when evaluating a matching function for disabled workers. In our case, as in other empirical works on the matching function, we have no data with less than annual frequency.

A final issue is related to the aggregation of spatial data (Hynninen 2005; Kano and Ohta 2005). The spatial aggregation of data was discussed and rejected by the empirical literature: at the level of local labour markets, it is preferred to work with disaggregated data (Burgess and Profit 2001; Coles and Smith 1996; Ilmakunnas and Pesola 2003; Hynninen 2005). Spatially disaggregated data are justified by the idea that the aggregate economy is a collection of distinct and heterogeneous spatially labour markets which suffer from many frictions. Spatially disaggregated data allow to examine the spatial aspects of the matching function and the weight of the interactions between the different local labour markets within an economy. On the basis of these considerations, many scholars have enriched the basic matching function with the spatial lag of regressors (unemployment, vacancies) with the objective to evaluate spillovers between different local labour markets (Burda and Profit 1996; Burgess and Profit 2001; Ilmakunnas and Pesola 2003). However, in our study disaggregated data are available only from regional level.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Agovino, M., Rapposelli, A. Evaluation of the Matching Process of Disabled People Through a Macroeconomic Approach: the Italian Case. Appl. Spatial Analysis 10, 139–159 (2017). https://doi.org/10.1007/s12061-015-9176-9

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s12061-015-9176-9

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation