Skip to main content
Log in

Monopsony in the Labor Market, Minimum Wages and the Time Horizon: Some Unresolved Issues

  • Published:
Atlantic Economic Journal Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This article discusses development of optimal solutions for monopsony in the labour market for the long run (when labour and capital are both flexible). It is shown that binding minimum wages up to a certain degree pushes the monopsonists to choose a high capital intensity of production, just as high as or even higher than that chosen when there is no regulation for minimum wages. Thereby, we demonstrate the existence of re-switching effects in the tradition of Piero Sraffa. The second part of the paper recalculates and analyzes earlier results by making use of the rather general constant elasticity of substitution production function. Based on a numerical solution for optimal monopsony under different regimes (no minimum wage, minimum wages of different values, etc.), we formulate a two-period game between the government and the monopsonistic firm (‘minimum wage game’). Finally, we analyze the relationship between the elasticity of substitution on the one hand and likely levels of employment on the other hand, after introduction of minimum wages.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. An Internet search revealed that the article of Maurice (1974) has been cited since then only seven times (!), and adding our own makes eight.

  2. Assuming an upward sloped labour supply function. We do not consider the case of a non-linear function.

  3. The latter is the neo-classical wording for what Sraffa labels ‘techniques’. See Schefold (2005, p. 443).

  4. In the relevant literature (Barr 2009), one finds the argument that a monopsonist, once confronted with minimum wages at a level of a competitive wage rate or even with higher levels, will in principle react like a competitive firm. This statement is correct, but does not alter the fact that as such, the monopsonist remains the sole demander of labour and thereby continues to be a monopsonist.

  5. Notice that for μ → 0, the CES-function converges against Cobb-Douglas-function Y(K, L) = EL δ K 1 − δ, therefore, μ = 0 is included in the parameter space.

  6. One may use this method of calculation for every wage function w(L) which is continuously differentiable. For reasons of simplicity, we make use of the above introduced linear wage function.

  7. As the original pay-offs are identical for the government when establishing a minimum wage regime (3.600), one has to look for further discriminatory criteria such as expected corporate tax income or expected private investment.

References

  • Barr, T. (2009). Advanced intermediate microeconomics. a human centered approach. Online cf.: http://www.tavisbarr.com/index.php?page=textbook.

  • Barr, T., & Roy, U. (2008). The effect of labor market monopsony on economic growth. Journal of Macroeconomics, 30, 1446–1467.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Blümle, G. (1975). Theorie der Einkommensverteilung. Eine Einführung. Berlin: Springer Verlag.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Boal, W. M., & Ransom, M. R. (1997). Monopsony in the labor market. Journal of Economic Literature, 35(1), 86–112.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cahuc, P., Laroque, G. (2009). Optimal taxation and monopsonistic labor market: Does monopsony justify the minimum wage? Cahier no. 2009–21. Ecole Polytechnique: Centre National de la Recherche Scientifique, Department d’Economie, Palaiseau Cedex.

  • Card, D., & Krueger, A. B. (1997). Myth and measurement: The new economics of the minimum wage. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Manning, A. (2006). A generalized model of monopsony. The Economic Journal, 116(508), 84–100.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Maurice, S. C. (1974). Monopsony and the externally imposed minimum wage. Southern Economic Journal, 41(2), 283–287.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Metcalf, D. (2008). Why has the British national minimum wage had little or no impact on employment? British Journal of Industrial Relations, 50, 489–512.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Neumark, D., & Wascher, W. L. (2008). Minimum wages. Cambridge: MIT Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Schefold, B. (2005). Reswitching as a cause of instability of intertemporal equlibrium. Metroeconomica, 56(4), 438–476.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sell, F. L., & Ruf, E. K. (2014). Wie entwickelt sich die Kapitalintensität ohne und mit Mindestlohn? Das Monopson am Arbeitsmarkt bei mehreren variablen Produktionsfaktoren. WiSt, 43(10), 543–549.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgments

We thank Beate Sauer, Thomas Werner, Anne Oeking, Reinhard Neck, Maks Tajnikar, Petra Dosenovic Bonca and further participants of the session‚ ‘European Economics’ at the 77th International Atlantic Economic Conference held in Madrid, April 2–5, 2014 and two anonymous referees for their most valuable comments and suggestions. All remaining errors are ours.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Friedrich L. Sell.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Sell, F.L., Ruf, E.K. Monopsony in the Labor Market, Minimum Wages and the Time Horizon: Some Unresolved Issues. Atl Econ J 44, 75–90 (2016). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11293-016-9484-8

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11293-016-9484-8

Keywords

JEL

Navigation