Skip to main content
Log in

More Unequal in Income, More Unequal in Wellbeing

  • Published:
Social Indicators Research Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This study focuses on the long-term trend in happiness by income level in the United States. General Social Survey data suggest that in the past, rich and poor Americans were not only more equal in terms of income, but also in terms of their subjective wellbeing: the happiness gap between the poor and the rich has been increasing. Today’s poor suffer greater relative unhappiness than the poor of past decades. The gap between the poor and the rich is substantial, approximately 0.4 on a 1–3 happiness scale. The increase in the happiness gap is striking: comparing the 1970s to the 2000s, the gap has widened by about 40 % between the poor and the rich, and by about 50 % between the middle class and the rich.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. We use the terms subjective wellbeing and happiness interchangeably. Happiness, life satisfaction, and subjective wellbeing do overlap. Although they are to some degree distinct, in the happiness literature it is customary to treat these concepts interchangeably (see e.g., Veenhoven 2008; Frey and Stutzer 2002; Diener and Lucas 1999; Radcliff 2013).

  2. There was a lively discussion between Veenhoven and Delhey, and it resulted in many papers (http://scholar.google.com/scholar?q=veenhoven+delhey+inequality). This debate, however, is beyond the scope of this article, which deals with the US and changes over time, not cross-sectional comparisons across countries. The results of the present study do not necessarily conflict with Berg and Veenhoven (2010), who found that across nations there is no correlation between income inequality and average happiness. It is even possible that income inequality can add to average happiness in many countries by increasing the pie, though probably not anymore in the US—some economists think that current levels of inequality in the US are bad for the economy. Income inequality can actually hurt the economy, not only society (The Economist 2012a, b, 2013). Stevenson and Wolfers (2008) found happiness inequality to be decreasing, but they did not establish a connection with income inequality. Easterlin (2001) focused on happiness by income, but only at one point in time. Blanchflower and Oswald (2004) looked at change over time, but at the effect of income on happiness, not on the effect of income inequality on happiness inequality.

  3. General reduction of inequality in happiness or reduction between some two groups, say racial groups, can co-exist with increasing inequality in the happiness across income groups. Taking Using a public health analogy, the life expectancy gap between Blacks and Whites has decreased but the life expectancy gap between the educated and the uneducated has increased (Meara et al. 2008).

  4. We are grateful for this suggestion to an anonymous reviewer who pointed out a need: “to find a convincing way of handling trends other than the increase in inequality, which may be causing changes in the level and distribution of happiness.”

  5. However, the Easterlin Paradox is observed in many countries, and our explanation may not hold up across the board—we are grateful for this point to Richard Easterlin.

References

  • Alesina, A., Di Tella, R., & MacCulloch, R. (2004). Inequality and happiness: are Europeans and Americans different? Journal of Public Economics, 88, 2009–2042.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Attanasio, O., Hurst, E., & Pistaferri, L. (2012). The Evolution of Income, Consumption, and Leisure inequality in the US, 1980–2010. Tech. rep., National Bureau of Economic Research.

  • Bartal, I., Decety, J., & Mason, P. (2011). Empathy and pro-social behavior in rats. Science, 334, 1427–1430.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Berg, M., & Veenhoven, R. (2010). Income inequality and happiness in 119 nations. repub.eur.nl.

  • Bjørnskov, C., Dreher, A., Fischer, J. A., Schnellenbach, J., & Gehring, K. (2013). Inequality and happiness: When perceived social mobility and economic reality do not match. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 91, 75–92.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Blanchflower, D., & Oswald, A. (2003). Does inequality reduce happiness? Evidence from the states of the USA from the 1970s to the 1990s. Mimeographed, Warwick University.

  • Blanchflower, D., & Oswald, A. (2004). Well-being over time in Britain and the USA. Journal of Public Economics, 88, 1359–1386.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Blanchflower, D. G., & Oswald, A. J. (2011). International happiness: A new view on the measure of performance. The Academy of Management Perspectives, 25, 6–22.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bok, D. (2010). The politics of happiness: What government can learn from the new research on well-being. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Brickman, P., Coates, D., & Janoff-Buman, R. (1978). Lottery winners and accident victims: Is happiness relative? Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 36, 917–927.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Campbell, A., Converse, P. E., & Rodgers, W. L. (1976). The quality of American life: Perceptions, evaluations, and satisfactions. New York: Russell Sage Foundation.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cassidy, J. (2013). American inequality in six charts. New York: The New Yorker.

    Google Scholar 

  • Chokshi, N. (2009). Education costs rising faster than health care. Washington: The Atlantic.

    Google Scholar 

  • Davis, J. A. (1966). The campus as a frog pond: An application of the theory of relative deprivation to career decisions of college men. American Journal of Sociology, 72, 17–31.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Davis, J. A., Smith, T. W., & Marsden, P. V. (2007): General Social Surveys, 1972–2006 [Cumulative File], Inter-university Consortium for Political and Social Research.

  • Delhey, J., & Dragolov, G. (2014). Why inequality makes Europeans less happy: The role of distrust, status anxiety, and perceived conflict. European Sociological Review, 30, 151–165.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Delhey, J., & Kohler, U. (2010). Is happiness inequality immune to income inequality? New evidence through instrument-effect-corrected standard deviations. Social Science Research, 40(3), 742–756.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Delhey, J., & Urlich, K. (2006). From nationally bounded to Pan-European inequalities? On the importance of foreign countries as reference groups. European Sociological Review, 22, 125–140.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Desmond, M. (2015). Severe deprivation in America: An introduction. RSF 1(2):1–11. http://www.rsfjournal.org/doi/full/10.7758/RSF.2015.1.2.01. Retrieved 12 Jan 2016.

  • Diener, E., & Lucas, R. R. (1999). Personality and subjective well-being. In E. Kahneman, E. Diener, & N. Schwarz (Eds.), Well-being: The foundations of hedonic psychology (pp. 213–229). New York: Russell Sage Foundation.

    Google Scholar 

  • Diener, E., Suh, E. M., & Lucas, R. E. (1999). Subjective well-being: Three decades of progress. Psychological Bulletin, 125, 276–302.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Easterlin, R. A. (1974). Does economic growth improve the human lot? In P. A. David & M. W. Reder (Eds.), Nations and households in economic growth: Essays in honor of Moses Abramovitz (Vol. 89, pp. 98–125). New York: Academic Press Inc.

    Google Scholar 

  • Easterlin, R. A. (2001). Income and happiness: Towards a unified theory. The Economic Journal, 111, 465–484.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Easterlin, R. A., McVey, L. A., Switek, M., Sawangfa, O., & Zweig, J. S. (2010). The happiness–income paradox revisited. Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences, 107, 22463–22468.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Easterlin, R. A., Morgan, R., Switek, M., & Wang, F. (2012). China’s life satisfaction, 1990–2010. Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences, 109, 9775–9780.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Edelman, P. (2012). So rich, so poor: Why it’s so hard to end poverty in America. New York: The New Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Edin, K. J., & Shaefer, H. L. (2015). $2.00 a Day: Living on almost nothing in America. Boston: Houghton Mifflin Harcourt.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ferrer-i-Carbonell, A., & Frijters, P. (2004). How important is methodology for the estimates of the determinants of happiness? Economic Journal, 114, 641–659.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fischer, C. S. (2008). What wealth-happiness paradox? A short note on the American case. Journal of Happiness Studies, 9, 219–226.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fischer, C. S. (2010). Made in America: A social history of American culture and character. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Frank, R. H. (2010). Hey, big spender: You need a surtax. New York: New York Times.

    Google Scholar 

  • Frank, R. (2012). The Darwin economy: Liberty, competition, and the common good. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Frank, R. H. (2014). The vicious circle of income inequality. New York: New York Times.

    Google Scholar 

  • Frey, B. S., & Stutzer, A. (2002). What can economists learn from happiness research? Journal of Economic literature, 40(2), 402–435.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gilbert, D. L. (2011). The American class structure in an age of growing inequality (8th ed.). Los Angeles, CA: Pine Forge Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gould, E., & Davis, A. (2015). Persistent poverty’s largest cause is inequality, not family structure. August 10. https://thesocietypages.org/families/2015/08/10/poverty-caused-by-inequality-not-family-structure/. Retrieved 17 Feb 2015.

  • Graham, C., & Felton, A. (2006). Inequality and happiness: Insights from Latin America. Journal of Economic Inequality, 4, 107–122.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Helliwell, J., Layard, R., & Sachs, J. (2012). World happiness report. New York: The Earth Institute, Columbia University.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hout, M. (2004). Getting the most out of the GSS income measures. Washington: National Opinion Research Center.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kahneman, D., & Tversky, A. (1979). Prospect theory: An analysis of decision under risk. Econometrica, 47, 263–291.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ligon, E. ([1989] 1994). The development and use of a consistent income measure for the General Social Survey. National Opinion Research Center, The University of Chicago

  • Massey, Douglas S. (2007). Categorically unequal: The American stratification system. New York: Russell Sage Foundation.

    Google Scholar 

  • Meara, E. R., Richards, S., & Cutler, D. M. (2008). The gap gets bigger: changes in mortality and life expectancy, by education, 1981–2000. Health Affairs, 27, 350–360.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Michalos, A. (1985). Multiple discrepancies theory (MDT). Social Indicators Research, 16, 347–413.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Myers, D. G. (2004). Exploring psychology. London: Macmillan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ng, Y.-K. (1997). A case for happiness, cardinalism, and interpersonal comparability. The Economic Journal, 107, 1848–1858.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nussbaum, M. C. (2006). Conversations with History: Martha Nussbaum. https://www.youtube.com/watch?v=Qy3YTzYjut4&list=PLDmIbYyjfK8BAq8q-ZYzakLXnGtQ8PS0I&index=147.

  • O’Connell, M. (2004). Fairly satisfied: Economic equality, wealth and satisfaction. Journal of Economic Psychology, 25, 297–305.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Oishi, S., Kesebir, S., & Diener, E. (2011). Income inequality and happiness. Psychological Science, 22, 1095–1100.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Oishi, S., Schimmack, U., & Diener, E. (2012). Progressive taxation and the subjective well-being of nations. Psychological Science, 23, 86–92.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Okulicz-Kozaryn, A., Holmes IV, O., & Avery, D. R. (2014). The subjective well-being political paradox: Happy welfare states and unhappy liberals. Journal of Applied Psychology, 99(6), 1300–1308.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Oshio, T., & Kobayashi, M. (2010). Income inequality, perceived happiness, and self-rated health: Evidence from nationwide surveys in Japan. Social Science and Medicine, 70, 1358–1366.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Oshio, T., & Kobayashi, M. (2011). Area-level income inequality and individual happiness: Evidence from Japan. Journal of Happiness Studies, 12, 633–649.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pickett, K. E. & Wilkinson, R. G. (2014). Income inequality and health: A causal review. Social Science & Medicine, 128, 316–326.

    Google Scholar 

  • Piketty, T. (2014). Capital in the 21st century. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Putnam, R. D. (2001). Bowling alone: The collapse and revival of American Community. New York, NY: Simon & Schuster.

    Google Scholar 

  • Putnam, Robert D. (2015). Our kids: The American dream in crisis. New York: Simon & Schuster.

    Google Scholar 

  • Radcliff, B. (2013). The political economy of human happiness: How voters’ choices determine the quality of life. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Schulz, W. (1995). Multiple-discrepancies theory versus resource theory. Social Indicators Research, 34, 153–169.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sen, A. (2000). Development as freedom. New York: Anchor Books.

    Google Scholar 

  • Shaefer, H. L., Edin, K., & Talbert, E. (2015). Understanding the dynamics of $2-a-day poverty in the United States. RSF: The Russell Sage Foundation Journal of the Social Sciences, 1(1):120–38. http://www.rsfjournal.org/doi/full/10.7758/RSF.2015.1.1.0. Retrieved 12 Jan 2016.

  • Snowdon, C. (2010). The spirit level delusion: Fact-checking the left’s new theory of everything. Ripon: Little Dice.

    Google Scholar 

  • Stevenson, B., & Wolfers, J. (2008). Happiness inequality in the United States. Tech. rep., National Bureau of Economic Research.

  • Stevenson, B., & Wolfers, J. (2009). The paradox of declining female happiness. American Economic Journal: Economic Policy, 1, 190–225.

    Google Scholar 

  • Stiglitz, J. E. (2012). The price of inequality: How today’s divided society endangers our future. New York: WW Norton & Company.

    Google Scholar 

  • Stiglitz, J. E. (2013). Student debt and the crushing of the American dream. New York: The New York Times.

    Google Scholar 

  • Stiglitz, J., Sen, A., & Fitoussi, J. (2009). Report by the Commission on the measurement of economic performance and social progress. www.stiglitz-sen-fitoussi.fr.

  • The Economist. (2011). The rich and the rest What to do (and not do) about inequality. Economist.

  • The Economist. (2012a). For richer, for poorer. The Economist.

  • The Economist. (2012b). True progressivism. The Economist.

  • The Economist. (2013). Having your cake; Less inequality does not need to mean less efficiency. The Economist.

  • Tricomi, E., Rangel, A., Camerer, C., & O’Doherty, J. (2010). Neural evidence for inequality-averse social preferences. Nature, 463, 1089–1091.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Veenhoven, R. (2005). Return of inequality in modern society? Test by dispersion of life-satisfaction across time and nations. Journal of Happiness Studies, 6, 457–487.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Veenhoven, R. (2008). Sociological theories of subjective well-being. In M. Eid & R. Larsen (Eds.), The science of subjective well-being: A tribute to ed Diener (pp. 44–61). New York: The Guilford Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Veenhoven, R., & Ehrhardt, J. (1995). The cross-national pattern of happiness: Test of predictions implied in three theories of happiness. Social Indicators Research, 34, 33–68.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Veenhoven, R., & Vergunst, F. (2013). The Easterlin illusion: economic growth does go with greater happiness. Munich Personal RePEc Archive, Paper No. 43983.

  • Wilkinson, R. G., & Pickett, K. E. (2006). Income inequality and population health: A review and explanation of the evidence. Social Science and Medicine, 62, 1768–1784.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wilkinson, R. G., & Pickett, K. E. (2010). The spirit level: Why equality is better for everyone. London: Penguin.

    Google Scholar 

  • Winkelmann, L., & Winkelmann, R. (2010). Does inequality harm the middle class? Kyklos, 63, 301–316.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wynne, C. (2004). Animal behaviour: Fair refusal by capuchin monkeys. Nature, 428, 140–140.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Yellen, J. (2006). Economic inequality in the United States. Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco (FRBSF) Economic Letter, 2006-33-34 (December 1, 2006).

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Adam Okulicz-Kozaryn.

Additional information

We thank Ruut Veenhoven. We take full responsibility for any errors or weaknesses that remain.

Appendices

Appendix 1: Additional Descriptive Statistics

See Figs. 3, 4, 5, 6 and Tables 3, 4, 5.

Fig. 3
figure 3

Distribution of real income by year. These values are estimated based on a categorical variable and imputed, so caution is necessary in interpretation

Fig. 4
figure 4

Distribution of happiness by year. This distribution, in contrast to income, does not change dramatically over time. It is consistently true that most people are pretty happy, some are very happy and few are not too happy

Fig. 5
figure 5

Happiness by quintiles of income: happiness is stable for the rich and declining for the poor. Series are smoothed with a 9-year moving average (4 years back, current year, and 4 years ahead)

Fig. 6
figure 6

Happiness by deciles of income. Results are similar to those in Fig. 5: happiness is stable for the rich and declining for the poor

Table 3 Variable definitions
Table 4 Summary statistics
Table 5 Correlation matrix

Appendix 2: Other Variables by Income Quintiles Over Time

See Figs. 7, 8 and 9.

Fig. 7
figure 7

Generalized trust: “Generally speaking, would you say that most people can be trusted or that you can’t be too careful in dealing with people?” The higher the value, the more trust. There is little difference by income, but a very clear pattern in the overall trend exists as documented by many others (e.g., Putnam 2001): Americans report lower trust than in the past

Fig. 8
figure 8

Support for government action to reduce income differences. The higher the value, the greater the support. Numbers 1–5 shown at the right side of the graph denote income quintiles. As expected, the poorer the group, the more support there is for reducing income differences. Yet, the biggest increase in favor of redistribution is among the richest

Fig. 9
figure 9

Opinions about fairness. The higher the value, the more agreement that “people try to take advantage of you as opposed to be fair.” Along with the increasing income gap, there was an increase amongst the poorest in the opinion that people are taken advantage of. Numbers 1–5 shown at the right side of the graph denote income quintiles

Appendix 3: Happiness by Original Income Measures

See Fig. 10.

Fig. 10
figure 10

Happiness by original income measures. 95 % CI shown. The top row shows the two earliest income measures (gss names: income72 and income77). The bottom row shows the latest income measures (gss names: income98 and income06). Vertical lines are drawn to aid interpretation. In all years happiness for the richest is approximately 2.4. But there is a change for the poorest: in the 1970s it was approximately 2.0, but in the last decade it was below 2.0 (about 1.9). There are also some interesting irregularities: for instance, the least happy are not the poorest

Appendix 4: Comparison of Inequality Measures from GSS and from Census

Gini data from the Census Bureau come from Table F-4 “Gini Indexes for Families, by Race and Hispanic Origin of Householder: 1947 to 2014,” available at https://www.census.gov/hhes/www/income/data/historical/inequality. Note that this gini index is for families (in this paper we use family income from the GSS). Furthermore, it is worth noting that from 1947 until 1972, when the GSS series began, the gini decreased only slightly and reached a low of 0.348 in 1968 before increasing, through to the present day. Data are plotted in graph 1. The correlation between the two series is 0.85. There is a spike in the GSS gini, another reason to rerun the analyses without the post-recession years. Yet, both series show a virtually identical linear trend as shown by fitted values (Fig. 11).

Fig. 11
figure 11

Comparison of the gini calculated from the GSS family income variable used in this paper with the official gini from the Census Bureau

Data on income quintiles from the GSS and the Census are shown in Figs. 12 and 13. The Census data use 2011 constant dollars. The GSS uses 1986 constant dollars. The quintiles are more uneven for the GSS series. Incomes are estimates in the GSS and, for many years, not very continuous but rather, are presented more discretely. This limitation is unfortunate, particularly because these are the only data available that are consistent series and go back as far in time. The series are especially inconsistent in earlier years when there were fewer income categories, and so the cutoff points for quantiles are coarser. The fit between the two series is not close; to check whether the results might have been due to quantization, we reran the analyses using 3 and 7 classes (see “Appendix 5”). Results are similar.

Fig. 12
figure 12

Quintiles of income from GSS. 1986 constant dollars

Fig. 13
figure 13

Upper limits for family income fifths. 2011 CPI-U-RS adjusted dollars. Source: US Census Bureau, Table F1, see the link for data footnotes: http://www.census.gov/hhes/www/income/data/historical/families

Appendix 5: Robustness Checks: Using 3 and 7 Classes

Stata (the statistical software used in this study) performs quantization (assigns variable values into quantiles) in a peculiar way by checking whether it passes the appropriate percentile for given quantile and if it does not, it uses the lower quantile for categorization. This yields non-optimal cutoff points when a variable has few levels. For instance, in 1972 real income has the following distribution:

Income

Frequency

Percent

Cumulative percent

2707

123

8.34

8.34

8122

165

11.19

19.54

13,537

160

10.85

30.39

18,951

160

10.85

41.25

24,366

192

13.03

54.27

30,458

217

14.72

69

37,226

159

10.79

79.78

43,994

103

6.99

86.77

50,763

63

4.27

91.04

60,915

67

4.55

95.59

74,452

33

2.24

97.83

109,355

32

2.17

100

Total

1474

100

 

Hence, an optimal solution is to classify only the first two categories (2707, 8122) into the first quintile (they constitute 19.54 percent of the distribution), but Stata takes the third category as well (13,573), because it does not reach 20 % after taking the first two. This peculiar approach has been documented on the Stata listserv by Stata’s foremost expert Nick Cox http://www.stata.com/statalist/archive/2012-06/msg01193.html, and at http://www.stata.com/statalist/archive/2012-06/msg01187.html. An obvious question is what if the study’s result—that the poor and rich are more unequal in happiness—is due to this strange clustering? We use 3 and 7 bins as a robustness check. Results hold up as shown in Tables 6 and 7.

Table 6 OLS regressions of happiness: using tertiles
Table 7 OLS regressions of happiness: using tertiles

Appendix 6: Family Income Versus Personal Income

There are theoretical and technical reasons for using family income as opposed to individual income, but for robustness, we discuss here the results using personal income. With respect to family income reported here there is a rather smooth gradient: the richer the group, the smaller the decrease in happiness over time, and as a result the bigger the gap in happiness. With respect to respondents’ income, this is still true when comparing the first quintile to the others: the poorest people became less happy over time. Richer groups remained more flat in their happiness, so the happiness gap between the poorest and the rest has increased. The key difference in results when using personal income is that all richer income groups remained at about the same happiness levels over time, so whatever happiness differences there were in the 1970s, they remained after the 2000s. In addition, the very richest group became slightly less happy, though not nearly by as much as the poorest group. The three middle quintiles remained most stable over time. For the reasons mentioned above, family income is a better measure, and we base our overall conclusions on the family income variable. These results do not generalize entirely when using personal income. In particular, the happiness gap between the richest and middle class has not increased if individual income is used instead of family income.

Finally, we reran models using family income divided by the natural log of the number of people in the household +1 (to avoid zero from ln(1)). The effect of family income on happiness depends in part on the number of people in a household. The rationale for dividing family income by the natural log of the number of people in a household is to scale the effect to reflect the diminishing marginal effect of each additional member of a household on family income (the addition of each subsequent member of a household “costs” less).

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Okulicz-Kozaryn, A., Mazelis, J.M. More Unequal in Income, More Unequal in Wellbeing. Soc Indic Res 132, 953–975 (2017). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11205-016-1327-0

Download citation

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11205-016-1327-0

Keywords

Navigation