Skip to main content
Log in

Contracts for venture capital financing with double-sided moral hazard

  • Published:
Small Business Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Using a Nash bargaining approach, we analyze the financing contract between the entrepreneur and the venture capitalist with double-sided moral hazard in a start-up enterprise. Our results show that there exists an optimal contract set between the entrepreneur and the venture capitalist, in which all contracts achieve an identical second-best social state. Within the optimal contract set, there exists continuum of joint debt-equity financing. The pure equity financing contract exists in the optimal contract set when the ratio of total social surplus to the amount of investment is greater than a threshold.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Throughout the paper, we use the phrases “optimal effort” and “equilibrium effort” interchangeably.

  2. With complete information when efforts are observable and verifiable, the entrepreneur and the VC would be compensated by their respective actual effort. In this case, their optimal effort levels are determined by the following condition:

    \( \underset{L,K}{\max}\kern0.5em \gamma S\left(L,K\right)=\gamma \left({R}_{\varepsilon }+c\sqrt{LK}-F-\frac{L^2}{2\eta }-\frac{K^2}{2\theta}\right), \)

    where γ = αα(1 − α)(1 − α) is a constant and S(L, K) is the gross social surplus that deducts from the project output the initial investment and effort costs of both parties. To find the optimal effort levels, we take the first-order condition, which gives \( \Big\{{\displaystyle \begin{array}{l}{L}^{\ast }=\frac{c}{2}{\theta}^{\frac{1}{4}}{\eta}^{\frac{3}{4}}\\ {}{K}^{\ast }=\frac{c}{2}{\theta}^{\frac{3}{4}}{\eta}^{\frac{1}{4}}\end{array}}\operatorname{} \).

  3. Throughout the paper we use the terms “agreed effort” and “expected effort” interchangeably.

  4. Lemma 1 describes the ideal yet inexecutable entrepreneurial contract form, and Proposition 1 presents the executable contract set (which nests the ideal contract) by introducing conditional social surplus. Only if conditional and actual social surplus are equal, the project output is shared in the same fashion between the ideal contract and the executable contract. The contract is fair in the sense that both parties are compensated by the actual cost of effort. The fairness of contracts in this context is more specific than that discussed in literature such as Fairchild (2011b) who relates it more generally to reciprocity, empathy, and trust.

  5. In Figure 4 the following assumptions are made regarding the transfer payment: \( T\left(\widehat{L},\widehat{K}\right)=1.5\times \alpha F=0.15 \) in \( M\left({H}_1^{\ast}\right) \), \( T\left(\widehat{L},\widehat{K}\right)=\alpha F=0.1 \) in \( M\left({H}_2^{\ast}\right) \), \( T\left(\widehat{L},\widehat{K}\right)=0.5\times \alpha F=0.05 \) in \( M\left({H}_3^{\ast}\right) \), and\( T\left(\widehat{L},\widehat{K}\right)=0\times \alpha F=0 \) in \( M\left({H}_4^{\ast}\right) \).

  6. The subset \( M\left({H}_4^{\ast}\right) \) excludes the scenarios when α is between 0.83 and 0.99 because of the negative social surplus (the transfer payment is out of its boundary). Such scenarios are not in the optimal contract set by definition.

  7. The subset \( M\left({H}_3^{\ast}\right) \) excludes the scenarios when α is between 0.91 and 0.99 because of the negative social surplus.

  8. Generally, in subsets M(H1*) and M(H3*), the relationships shown in Fig. 4 are not necessarily linear, and the share of social surplus received by the entrepreneur is usually (but not always) greater than the share of project output.

References

  • Binmore, K., Rubinstein, A., & Wolinsky, A. (1986). The Nash bargaining solution in economic modelling. RAND Journal of Economics, 17(2), 176–188.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bengtsson, O. (2012). Financial contracting in US venture capital: overview and empirical evidence. In D. Cumming (Ed.), The Oxford handbook of venture capital (pp. 478–508). New York: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bengtsson, O., & Sensoy, B. A. (2015). Changing the nexus: the evolution and renegotiation of venture capital contracts. Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis, 50(03), 349–375.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Boadway, R., O. Secrieru, M. Vigneault (2005). A search model of venture capital, entrepreneurship, and unemployment. SSRN Working Paper, available at https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.744105

  • Casamatta, C. (2003). Financing and advising: optimal financial contracts with venture capitalists. Journal of Finance, 58(5), 2059–2086.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chemla, G., Habib, M. A., & Ljungqvist, A. (2007). An analysis of shareholder agreements. Journal of the European Economic Association, 5(1), 93–121.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cheung, S. N. S. (1969). The theory of share tenancy. Chicago: University of Chicago Press reprinted in June 2000 by Arcadia Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Coase, R. H. (1937). The nature of the firm. Economica, 4(16), 386–405.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cumming, D. J. (2005). Capital structure in venture finance. Journal of Corporate Finance, 11(3), 550–585.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cumming, D. J. (2007). United States venture capital financial contracting: foreign securities, in Hirschey, John, and Makhija (ed.) Issues in corporate governance and finance (Advances in financial economics, Volume 12), Emerald Group Publishing Ltd, 405–444.

  • Cumming, D. (2008). Contracts and exits in venture capital finance. Review of Financial Studies, 21(5), 1947–1982.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cumming, D., & binti Johan, S. A. (2008). Preplanned exit strategies in venture capital. European Economic Review, 52(7), 1209–1241.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cumming, D., Schmidt, D., & Walz, U. (2010). Legality and venture capital governance around the world. Journal of Business Venturing, 25(1), 54–72.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • De Bettignies, J. E. (2008). Financing the entrepreneurial venture. Management Science, 54(1), 151–166.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • De Bettignies, J. E., & Brander, J. A. (2007). Financing entrepreneurship: bank finance versus venture capital. Journal of Business Venturing, 22(6), 808–832.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fairchild, R. (2011a). An entrepreneur’s choice of venture capitalist or angel-financing: a behavioral game-theoretic approach. Journal of Business Venturing, 26(3), 359–374.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fairchild, R. (2011b). Fairness norms and self-interest in venture capital/entrepreneur contracting and performance. International Journal of Behavioural Accounting and Finance, 2(1), 4–20.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fenn, G., N. Liang, S. Prowse (1998). The role of angel investors in financing high-tech start-ups, Unpublished Manuscript, Federal Reserve Board.

  • Gilson, R. J., & Schizer, D. M. (2003). Understanding venture capital structure: a tax explanation for convertible preferred stock. Harvard Law Review, 116(3), 874–916.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hartmann-Wendels, T., Keienburg, G., & Sievers, S. (2011). Adverse selection, investor experience and security choice in venture capital finance: evidence from Germany. European Financial Management, 17(3), 464–499.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hellmann, T. (1998). The allocation of control rights in venture capital contracts. RAND Journal of Economics, 29(1), 57–76.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hellmann, T. (2002). A theory of strategic venture investing. Journal of Financial Economics, 64(2), 285–314.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hellmann, T. (2006). IPOs, acquisitions, and the use of convertible securities in venture capital. Journal of Financial Economics, 81(3), 649–679.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hirsch, J., & Walz, U. (2013). Why do contracts differ between venture capital types? Small Business Economics, 40(3), 511–525.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Inderst, R., & Muller, H. M. (2004). The effect of capital market characteristics on the value of start-up firms. Journal of Financial Economics, 72(2), 319–356.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kaplan, S. N., Martel, F., & Strömberg, P. (2007). How do legal differences and experience affect financial contracts? Journal of Financial Intermediation, 16(3), 273–311.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kaplan, S. N., & Strömberg, P. (2003). Financial contracting theory meets the real world: an empirical analysis of venture capital contracts. Review of Economic Studies, 70(2), 281–315.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Landier, A. (2002). Start-up financing: From banks to venture capitalists, Working Paper, University of Chicago.

  • Lerner, J., & Schoar, A. (2005). Does legal enforcement affect financial transactions? The contractual channel in private equity. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 120(1), 223–246.

    Google Scholar 

  • Modigliani, F., & Miller, M. H. (1958). The cost of capital, corporation finance and the theory of investment. American Economic Review, 48(3), 261–297.

    Google Scholar 

  • Nahata, R., Hazarika, S., & Tandon, K. (2014). Success in global venture capital investing: do institutional and cultural differences matter? Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis, 49(04), 1039–1070.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nash, J. (1950). The bargaining problem. Econometrica, 18(2), 155–162.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nash, J. (1953). Two-person cooperative games. Econometrica, 21(1), 128–140.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Osintsev, Y. (2010). Venture financing of start-ups: a model of contract between VC fund and entrepreneur. Economic Annals, 55(187), 61–86.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Reid, G. C. (1996). Fast growing small entrepreneurial firms and their venture capital backers: an applied principal-agent analysis. Small Business Economics, 8(3), 235–248.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Repullo, R., & Suarez, J. (2004). Venture capital finance: a security design approach. Review of Finance, 8(1), 75–108.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Roth, A. E. (1979). Axiomatic models of bargaining. New York: Springer-Verlag.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Schmidt, K. M. (2003). Convertible securities and venture capital finance. Journal of Finance, 58(3), 1139–1166.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tirole, J. (2001). Corporate governance. Econometrica, 69(1), 1–35.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tirole, J. (2006). The theory of corporate finance. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Utset, M. A. (2002). Reciprocal fairness, strategic behavior and venture survival: a theory of venture capital-financed firms. Wisconsin Law Review, 2002(1), 45–168.

    Google Scholar 

  • Yousfi, O. (2013). Does PLS solve moral hazard problems? Journal of Islamic Economics, Banking and Finance, 9(3), 11–26.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

Hui Fu thanks his supervisor, Professor Tian Cunzhi, for his guidance, support, and continuing encouragement throughout his Ph.D. studies at Jinan University.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding authors

Correspondence to Hui Fu or Yunbi An.

Appendix

Appendix

1.1 Proof of Proposition 2

According to the basic form for the financing contract in Proposition 1, the expected effort levels in contract are \( \left(\widehat{L},\widehat{K}\right) \) for the entrepreneur and the VC. At arbitrary effort levels L and K, the entrepreneur receives:

$$ {R}_{\mathrm{en}}=\alpha S\left[\left(L,K\right)\left|\left(\widehat{L},\widehat{K}\right)\right.\right]+\frac{{\widehat{L}}^2}{2\eta }, $$

and the entrepreneur’s cost for effort is:

$$ {g}_{\mathrm{en}}(L)=\frac{L^2}{2\eta }. $$

Thus, the social surplus received by the entrepreneur is:

$$ {R}_{\mathrm{en}}-{g}_{\mathrm{en}}(L)=\alpha S\left[\left(L,K\right)|\left(\hat{L},\hat{K}\operatorname{}\right)\right]+\frac{{\hat{L}}^2}{2\eta }-\frac{L^2}{2\eta }. $$

Similarly, the social surplus received by the VC is:

\( {R}_{\mathrm{vc}}-F-{g}_{\mathrm{vc}}(K)=\left(1-\alpha \right)S\left[\left(L,K\right)|\left(\hat{L},\hat{K}\right)\right]+\frac{{\hat{K}}^2}{2\theta }-\frac{K^2}{2\theta}\cdotp \) Since both the entrepreneur and the VC are rational, they would choose the optimal effort levels \( \tilde{L} \) and \( \tilde{K} \) to maximize their respective social surplus:

$$ \Big\{{\displaystyle \begin{array}{l}\overset{\sim }{L}=\arg \underset{L}{\max}\kern0.5em \alpha S\left[\left(L,K\right)|\left(\hat{L},\hat{K}\right)\operatorname{}\right]+\frac{{\hat{L}}^2}{2\eta }-\frac{L^2}{2\eta },\forall K\\ {}\overset{\sim }{K}=\arg \underset{K}{\max}\kern0.5em \left(1-\alpha \right)S\left[\left(L,K\right)|\left(\hat{L},\hat{K}\right)\operatorname{}\right]+\frac{{\hat{K}}^2}{2\theta }-\frac{K^2}{2\theta },\forall L\end{array}}\operatorname{} $$

According to the first-order conditions, the equilibrium solution is:

$$ \left\{\begin{array}{l}\tilde{L}=\frac{c}{2}{\left[\left(1-\alpha \right)\theta \right]}^{\frac{1}{4}}{\left(\alpha \eta \right)}^{\frac{3}{4}}={\left(1-\alpha \right)}^{\frac{1}{4}}{\left(\alpha \right)}^{\frac{3}{4}}{L}^{\ast}\\ {}\tilde{K}=\frac{c}{2}{\left[\left(1-\alpha \right)\theta \right]}^{\frac{3}{4}}{\left(\alpha \eta \right)}^{\frac{1}{4}}={\left(1-\alpha \right)}^{\frac{3}{4}}{\left(\alpha \right)}^{\frac{1}{4}}{K}^{\ast}\end{array}\right.. $$

1.2 Proof of Proposition 3

As per the basic form of the financing contract as in Proposition 1 and the assumption of \( S\left(\tilde{L},\tilde{K}\right)>0 \), the transfer payment \( T\left(\hat{L},\hat{K}\right) \) must make both the entrepreneur and the VC receive a positive social surplus. According to Corollary 2, we have the following:

$$ \left\{\begin{array}{l}{S}_{\mathrm{en}}\left(R,\widehat{L},\widehat{K}\right)=\alpha S\left(\tilde{L},\tilde{K}\right)-T\left(\widehat{L},\widehat{K}\right)+T\left(\tilde{L},\tilde{K}\right)>0\\ {}{S}_{\mathrm{vc}}\left(R,\widehat{L},\widehat{K}\right)=\left(1-\alpha \right)S\left(\tilde{L},\tilde{K}\right)+T\left(\widehat{L},\widehat{K}\right)-T\left(\tilde{L},\tilde{K}\right)>0\end{array}\right. $$

which gives:

$$ \left\{\begin{array}{l}T\left(\widehat{L},\widehat{K}\right)>\alpha F-\left(1-\alpha \right)S\left(\tilde{L},\tilde{K}\right)\\ {}T\left(\widehat{L},\widehat{K}\right)<\alpha F+\alpha S\left(\tilde{L},\tilde{K}\right)\end{array}\right.. $$

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Fu, H., Yang, J. & An, Y. Contracts for venture capital financing with double-sided moral hazard. Small Bus Econ 53, 129–144 (2019). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11187-018-0028-2

Download citation

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11187-018-0028-2

Keywords

JEL classification

Navigation