Skip to main content
Log in

The Jeffords switch and legislator rolls in the U.S. Senate

  • Published:
Public Choice Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

On May 24, 2001 United States Senator James Jeffords announced that he was switching from Republican to independent and would vote with Democrats on organizational matters (i.e. votes deciding party membership and majority party status), effectively taking majority party control of the Senate from the Republicans and giving it to the Democrats. This created an unusually well controlled quasi-experimental opportunity for learning about the role of parties in the Senate—it held most important variables constant while one variable, majority status, changed. We use roll call data to evaluate the probability of individual members of each party being rolled on Senate final passage votes, before and after the switch. We find that, contrary to conventional wisdom on the Senate, majority status is an important factor in Senate decision-making. Our results show that Republicans were more likely to be rolled after the switch than they had been before, and that Democrats were less likely to be rolled than they had been before.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Other models of congressional decision-making leave out parties altogether. See, for example, Krehbiel 1998; see also Brady and Volden 1998.

  2. Also, Republicans were more successful than Democrats pre-switch, and Democrats were more successful than Republicans post-switch.

  3. There has never been a change in majority status in the House without a concurrent change in membership.

  4. A possible objection at this point is that Jeffords’s policy preferences might have changed, and that such a change in preferences explains our results, rather than the change in majority status. We maintain the assumption that his preferences did not change; we discuss reasons for this assumption later in the paper, when we report our empirical results.

  5. Jeffords’s given reason for switching was that the increasingly conservative Republican caucus made it difficult for him to remain moderate; as part of the switch, Democratic leaders guaranteed that they would be tolerant of his moderate positions, and also gave him a committee chairmanship (Jeffords 2001; Daschle and D'Orso 2003).

  6. The Senate was in the midst of working on the tax bill at the time of Jeffords’s announcement; part of his deal with Democrats was that the switch would not occur until after the Senate passed the bill (Jeffords 2001).

  7. One might also consider committee assignments as a fourth stage, in the sense that the committee assignment process might be seen as a quality filtering system that biases legislative outcomes (Crain 1990). However, we omit this stage and instead treat personal as fixed during a given legislative session.

  8. Senate Rule XIV allows senators to bypass committee consideration altogether and place measures directly onto the calendar; but bringing the bill up for floor consideration is all but impossible if the majority leader objects (Gold 2008; Sinclair 2007). Moreover, Rule XIV allows majority leaders to circumvent a committee if they do not trust it to do the party’s bidding—a practice that has grown more common, especially for high-priority items (Evans and Oleszek 2001; Oleszek 2004).

  9. Various Senate procedural experts describe votes on motions to table as instances in which senators are strongly predisposed to vote the party line, making tabling motions a tool primarily of majority leaders (Gold 2008; Marshall et al. 1999; Oleszek 2004; Tiefer 1989).

  10. Roll and roll rates (the ratio of rolls to final passage votes) are used widely in combination with one-dimensional spatial models to study negative agenda power. Carson et al. (2011), Cox and McCubbins (2005) and Jenkins and Monroe (2013) establish theoretical underpinnings of using rolls in this way (but see Krehbiel 2007 for a dissenting view).

  11. Neither M nor Mi represents the median member of their respective party caucus.

  12. This assumption reflects the idea that the majority’s procedural advantages, described in the previous section, make it less costly for the majority party to propose measures and push them toward final passage than it is for the minority party.

  13. More minimally, any partisan theory that assumes that the majority party has negative agenda control and that the minority party lacks complete negative agenda control is consistent with this argument.

  14. The set of votes used here is each Senate final passage vote on a Senate or House bill, a Senate or House joint resolution, an executive nomination, or a conference report. There were 26 votes in the pre-switch period and 18 votes in the post-switch period. Not all senators voted on every vote, although most voted on most of the votes.

  15. We use senators’ NOMINATE scores from the 107th Congress. Given that NOMINATE scores are derived from legislators’ roll call votes in a given Congress, and that our dependent variable is a roll call-based measure, our use of the NOMINATE-based Distance variable on the right hand side of the equation raises the concern that our findings might result from, essentially, using roll call votes to explain roll call votes. An alternative approach would be to use NOMINATE scores from the previous or subsequent congress as a way to circumvent this issue. However, turnover in Senate membership in the 2000 and 2002 elections was sufficiently large that many senators would drop out of our analysis if we used scores from the 106th or 108th Congress. Moreover, our use here is defensible: the Distance variable is a control variable rather than a test variable, so our conclusions do not rely on the Distance variable’s significance. When we estimate the model without the Distance variable the results of our hypothesis tests remain the same, with the slight caveat that the significance level of the Post-Switch Hypothesis test coefficient is 94.8 percent rather than 97.1 percent.

  16. More accurately, a legislator’s probability of being rolled is greater as the member’s ideal point is farther outside the protected interval (assuming, as is common in the literature, that status quos are uniformly distributed). Because different assumptions about the agenda-setter and floor veto players lead to different protected intervals, the appropriate control for ideological extremeness differs from one model to the next. Including all different possible permutations of this control would increase the length and complexity of the text and results—with, we believe, little payoff. In results not reported here, we have experimented with different permutations, and in no case has it made a difference in the inferences that we draw about the hypotheses. We thus report results using only the crude Distance variable defined above.

  17. Another possibility would be to drop the Distance variable and instead include a fixed effect dummy for each senator. With panel data such as ours, however, inclusion of such unit fixed effects “does not allow the estimation of time-invariant variables” and is inefficient (Plumper and Troeger 2007, pp. 124–125). Given that one of our key test variables, the dummy for Democratic senators, is time-invariant, we do not use fixed effects.

  18. Another potential estimation option is a negative binomial event count model. Though they are similar, King (1998) emphasizes that event count data (the number of positive outcomes out of an unknown or infinite number of trials) differs from grouped binary data (the number of positive outcomes out of a known number of trials) and recommends extended beta-binomial for the latter type of data.

  19. We drop subscripts from variable names in the rest of the discussion. The Pseudo R2 is 0.1168, the Log-likelihood is −1291.7813, and the number of observations is 198 because Jeffords is excluded from the analysis, since he was in the majority in each period. Including Jeffords makes no significant difference in the results.

  20. The linear combination test is a z-test of the proposition that sum of the coeficients equals zero.

  21. In a one-tailed test, the significance level is 97.1%; in all other cases discussed here, the significance level is over 99.999 %.

  22. At the suggestion of an anonymous reviewer, we also estimated this model without the Distance variable. The results are very similar, with two small exceptions: the Pseudo-R2 drops from 0.1168 to 0.096, and the significance level of the Dem-plus-Dem × PostSwitch sum drops from 97.1 to 94.7 %.

  23. Distance is held constant at its median value for members of each party.

  24. See Smith (2007) for an overview of the problems with parsing effects.

  25. The W-NOMINATE program is available at Voteview.com.

  26. We also estimated W-NOMINATE scores for each Senator in the 107th Congress across the entire period of our analysis; that is, we use all Senate roll call votes from the beginning of the 107th Congress until September 10th, 2001, so that we get one estimate for each senator (except Jeffords) for the entire pre- and post-switch period. We treat pre- and post-switch Jeffords as two different individuals, in order to contrast his pre- and post-switch voting behavior. The result is an estimated pre-switch (first-dimension) ideal point of .14, and a post-switch ideal point of −.095—which is a very small shift in voting behavior. To put this change in perspective, compare it to the ideal points of a few other prominent Senators from across the political spectrum, estimated across the same time period: Wellstone (−0.969); Kennedy (−0.813); Daschle (−0.719); Baucus (−0.098); Chafee (0.159); Specter (0.289); Lugar (0.715); Santorum (0.825); Helms (1.000).

  27. See Aldrich et al. (2002) and Aldrich et al. (2005) on measuring the extent to which conditional party government conditions are met.

References

  • Ainsworth, S., & Flathman, M. (1995). Unanimous consent agreements as leadership tools. Legislative Studies Quarterly, 20(2), 177–195.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Aldrich, J. H., Berger, M. M., & Rohde, D. W. (2002). The historical variability in conditional party government. In D. Brady & M. D. McCubbins (Eds.), Party, process, and political change in congress: New perspectives on the history of congress (pp. 1877–1994). Palo Alto: Stanford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Aldrich, J. H., & Rohde, D. W. (2000). The republican revolution and the house appropriations committee. Journal of Politics, 62(1), 1–33.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Aldrich, J. H., & Rohde, D. W. (2001). The logic of conditional party government: Revisiting the electoral connection. In L. C. Dodd & B. I. Oppenheimer (Eds.), Congress reconsidered (6th ed.). Washington, DC: Congressional Quarterly Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Aldrich, J. H., Rohde, D. W., & Tofias, M. W. (2005). One D is not enough: Measuring conditional party government. In D. Brady & M. D. McCubbins (Eds.), Process, party and policy making: Further new perspectives on the history of congress (pp. 1887–2002). Palo Alto: Stanford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bargen, A. (2003). Senators, status quos, and agenda setting: A spatial story of policy making in the U.S. Senate, 1953–1996. Paper presented at the Annual Meeting of the American Political Science Association, Philadelphia, PA.

  • Beth, R., Heitshusen, V., Heniff, B., & Rybicki, E. (2009). Leadership tools for managing the U.S. Senate. Paper presented at the Annual Meeting of the American Political Science Association, Toronto, Canada.

  • Binder, S. A. (1997). Minority rights, majority rule: Partisanship and the development of congress. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Binder, S. A. (1999). The dynamics of legislative gridlock, 1947-96. American Political Science Review, 93(3), 519–533. doi:10.2307/2585572.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Binder, S. A. (2003). Stalemate: Causes and consequences of legislative gridlock. Washington, D.C.: Brookings Institution Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Binder, S. A., & Smith, S. S. (1997). Politics or principle? Filibustering in the United States Senate. Washington, D.C.: Brookings Institution.

    Google Scholar 

  • Brady, D. W., & Volden, C. (1998). Revolving gridlock: Politics and policy from Carter to Clinton. Boulder, Colo: Westview Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Campbell, A. (2001). Party Government in the United States Senate. (Ph.D. Dissertation), University of California, San Diego.

  • Campbell, A. (2004). Fighting fire with fire: Strategic amending in the 105th Senate. Paper presented at the Annual Meeting of the American Political Science Association, Chicago, IL.

  • Campbell, A., Cox, G., & McCubbins, M. D. (2002). Agenda power in the U.S. Senate, 1877–1986. In D. Brady & M. D. McCubbins (Eds.), Party, process, and political change in congress: New perspectives on the history of congress. Palo Alto: Stanford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Carroll, R., & Kim, H. A. (2010). Party government and the “cohesive power of public plunder”. American Journal of Political Science, 54(1), 34–44.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Carson, J. L., Monroe, N. W., & Robinson, G. (2011). Unpacking agenda control in congress: Individual roll rates and the Republican revolution. Political Research Quarterly, 64(1), 17–30.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chiou, F. Y., & Rothenberg, L. S. (2003). When pivotal politics meets partisan politics. American Journal of Political Science, 47(3), 503–522.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Clinton, J., Jackman, S., & Rivers, D. (2004). The statistical analysis of roll-call data. American Political Science Review, 98, 355–370.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cox, G. W., & McCubbins, M. D. (2005). Setting the agenda: Responsible party government in the U.S. house of Representatives. Cambridge; New York: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Crain, W. M. (1990). Legislative committees: A filtering theory. In W. M. Crain & R. D. Tollison (Eds.), Predicting politics: Essays in empirical public choice. Ann Arbor, MI: University of Michigan Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Crespin, M. H., & Finocchiaro, C. J. (2008). Distributive and partisan politics in the U.S. Senate: An exploration of earmarks. In N. Monroe, J. M. Roberts, & D. W. Rohde (Eds.), Why not parties? Party effects in the United States Senate (pp. 1996–2005). Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Daschle, T., & D’Orso, M. (2003). Like no other time: The 107th congress and the 2 years that changed America forever (1st ed.). New York: Crown Publishers.

    Google Scholar 

  • Den Hartog, C., & Monroe, N. W. (2008). The value of majority status: The effect of Jeffords’s switch on asset prices of republican and democratic firms. Legislative Studies Quarterly, 33(1), 63–84.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Den Hartog, C., & Monroe, N. W. (2011). Agenda setting in the U.S. Senate: Costly consideration and majority party advantage. New York: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Evans, C. L. (1991). Leadership in committee: A comparative analysis of leadership behavior in the U.S. Senate. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Evans, C. L., & Lipinski, D. (2005). Obstruction and leadership in the U.S. Senate. In L. C. Dodd & B. I. Oppenheimer (Eds.), Congress reconsidered (8th ed.). Washington, DC: CQ Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Evans, C. L., & Oleszek, W. J. (2001). Message politics and senate procedure. In C. Campbell & N. Rae (Eds.), The contentious Senate. Landham, MD: Rowman and Littlefield.

    Google Scholar 

  • Finocchiaro, C. J., & Rohde, D. W. (2008). War for the floor: Partisan theory and agenda control in the U.S. house of representatives. Legislative Studies Quarterly, 33(1), 35–61.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gailmard, S., & Jenkins, J. A. (2007). Negative agenda control in the Senate and house: Fingerprints of majority party power. Journal of Politics, 69(3), 689–700.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gold, M. (2008). Senate procedure and practice (2nd ed.). Lanham: Rowman & Littlefield Publishers.

    Google Scholar 

  • Jayachandran, S. (2006). The Jeffords effect. Journal of Law and Economics, 49(2), 397–425.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jeffords, J. M. (2001). My declaration of independence. New York: Simon & Schuster.

    Google Scholar 

  • Jenkins, J. A., & Monroe, N. W. (2015). On measuring legislative agenda setting power. American Journal of Political Science.

  • King, G. (1998). Unifying political methodology: The likelihood theory of statistical inference. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Koger, G. (2010). Filibustering: A political history of obstruction in the house and Senate. Chicago: The University of Chicago Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Koger, G., & Fowler, J. (2006). Parties and agenda setting in the Senate, 1973–1998. Paper presented at the conference on party effects in the U.S. Senate, University of Minnesota, Minneapolis, MN.

  • Krehbiel, K. (1998). Pivotal politics: A theory of U.S. lawmaking. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Krehbiel, K. (2007). Partisan roll rates in a nonpartisan legislature. Journal of Law Economics and Organization, 23(1), 1–23.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lawrence, E. D., Maltzman, F., & Smith, S. S. (2005). Changing patterns of party effects in congressional voting. Paper presented at the Annual Meeting of the American Political Science Association, Washington, DC.

  • Lawrence, E. D., Maltzman, F., & Smith, S. S. (2006). Who wins? Party effects in legislative voting. Legislative Studies Quarterly, 31(1), 33–69.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lebo, M. J., McGlynn, A. J., & Koger, G. (2007). Strategic party government: Party influence in congress, 1789–2000. American Journal of Political Science, 51(3), 464–481.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lee, F. E. (2009). Beyond ideology: Politics, principles, and partisanship in the U.S. Senate. Chicago: The University of Chicago Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Lijphart, A. (1984). Democracies; patterns of majoritarian and consensus government in twenty-one countries. New Haven: Yale University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Marshall, B. W., Prins, B. C., & Rohde, D. W. (1999). Fighting fire with water: Partisan procedural strategies and the Senate appropriations committee. Congress and the Presidency, 26, 114–132.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Martinez, G. (2001, May 27, 2001). Moderates torn by parties; Senate defection shows conflict of middle ground. The Detroit News.

  • Matthews, D. R. (1960). U.S. Senators and their world. Chapel Hill: University of North Carolina Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • McCarty, N. M., Poole, K. T., & Rosenthal, H. (1997). Income redistribution and the realignment of American politics. Washington, D.C.: AEI Press, publisher for the American Enterprise Institute.

    Google Scholar 

  • Nicholson, S. P. (2005). The Jeffords switch and public support for divided government. British Journal of Political Science, 35, 343–356.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nokken, T. P., & Poole, K. T. (2004). Congressional party defection in American history. Legislative Studies Quarterly, 29, 545–568.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Oleszek, W. J. (2004). Congressional procedures and the policy process (6th ed.). Washington, D.C.: CQ Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Oppenheimer, B. I., & Hetherington, M. J. (2008). Catch 22: Cloture, energy policy, and the limits of conditional party government. In N. W. Monroe, J. M. Roberts, & D. W. Rohde (Eds.), Why not parties? Party effects in the United States Senate. Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Palmquist, B. (1997). Heterogeneity and dispersion in the beta-binomial model. Paper presented at the Annual Meeting of the American Political Science Association, Washington, DC.

  • Palmquist, B. (1999). Analysis of proportions data. Paper presented at the Annual Meeting of the Political Methodology Society, College Station, TX.

  • Plumper, T., & Troeger, V. E. (2007). Efficient estimation of time-invariant and rarely changing variables in finite sample panel analyses with unit fixed effects. Political Analysis, 15(2), 124–139.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Poole, K. T. (1998). Recovering a basic space from a set of issue scales. American Journal of Political Science, 42(3), 954–993.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Poole, K. T., & Rosenthal, H. (1997). Congress: A political-economic history of roll call voting. New York: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Prentice, R. L. (1986). Binary regression using an extended beta-binomial distribution, with discussion of correlation induced by covariate measurement errors. Journal of the American Statistical Association, 81(394), 321–327. doi:10.2307/2289219.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rawls, W. L. (2009). In praise of deadlock: How partisan struggle makes better laws. Baltimore: Woodrow Wilson Center Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ripley, R. B. (1969). Power in the Senate. New York: St. Martin’s Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Roberts, J. M. (2007). The statistical analysis of roll-call data: A cautionary tale. Legislative Studies Quarterly, 32(3), 341–360.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rohde, D. W. (1991). Parties and leaders in the postreform house. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Romer, T., & Rosenthal, H. (1978). Political resource-allocation, controlled agendas, and the Status Quo. Public Choice, 33(4), 27–43.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schiller, W. J. (1995). The art of manipulation: The use of senate parliamentary procedure to change policy outcomes. Paper presented at the Annual Meeting of the American Political Science Association, Chicago, IL.

  • Schiller, W. J. (2000). Trent lott’s new regime: filling the amendment tree to centralize power in the U.S. Senate. Paper presented at the Annual Meeting of the American Political Science Association, Washington, DC.

  • Schiller, W. J. (2001). Majority and minority rights in the Senate and the role of party leaders in internal governance. Paper presented at the Annual Meeting of the American Political Science Association, San Francisco, CA.

  • Sinclair, B. (1989). The transformation of the U.S. Senate. Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sinclair, B. (1997). Unorthodox lawmaking: New legislative processes in the U.S. congress. Washington, DC: CQ Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sinclair, B. (2001). The senate leadership dilemma: Passing bills and pursuing partisan advantage in a nonmajoritarian chamber. In C. Campbell & N. Rae (Eds.), The contentious Senate. Lanham, MD: Rowman and Littlefield.

    Google Scholar 

  • Smith, S. S. (1989). Call to order: Floor politics in the house and Senate. Washington, DC: Brookings Institution.

    Google Scholar 

  • Smith, S. S. (2005). Parties and leadership in the Senate. In P. J. Quirk & S. A. Binder (Eds.), American institutions of democracy: The legislative branch. New York, NY: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Smith, S. S. (2007). Party influence in Congress. Cambridge, New York: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Tiefer, C. (1989). Congressional practice and procedure: A reference, research, and legislative guide. New York: Greenwood Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wawro, G. J., & Schickler, E. (2006). Filibuster: Obstruction and lawmaking in the U.S. Senate. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgments

A previous version of this paper was presented at the 2005 Annual Meeting of the American Political Science Association, September 1–4, Washington, D.C. We thank John Aldrich, Cheryl Boudreau, Andrea Campbell, Dave Clark, Gary Cox, David Epstein, Bob Erikson, Karen Ferree, Clark Gibson, Will Heller, Simon Hix, Henry Kim, Thad Kousser, Gary Jacobson, Jonathan Katz, Jonathan Krasno, Jeff Lax, Michael McDonald, Mat McCubbins, Kathryn Pearson, Rose Razaghian, Dave Rohde, Brian Sala, Greg Wawro, and Nick Weller for helpful comments on previous versions and related projects. We also gratefully acknowledge financial support provided by NSF Grant # SES 9905224 (Principal investigators: Gary W. Cox and Mathew D. McCubbins.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Nathan W. Monroe.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Den Hartog, C., Monroe, N.W. The Jeffords switch and legislator rolls in the U.S. Senate. Public Choice 165, 25–43 (2015). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11127-015-0289-0

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11127-015-0289-0

Keywords

Navigation