Skip to main content
Log in

The paradox of information and voter turnout

  • Published:
Public Choice Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

The most prominent explanation for the paradox of voter turnout is that citizens are willing to bear the cost of voting because they perceive a benefit (e.g., fulfilling a civic duty or expressing themselves) that is independent of the election outcome. However, a separate literature highlights the empirical importance of information for voter participation, and existing explanations for this are that uninformed citizens either expect smaller benefits from voting, or defer strategically to peers who know more. This paper simply points out that, while either of these theories offers a plausible explanation for the importance of information, neither is robust if the motivation for voting is unrelated to the election outcome. This is because citizens with positive net voting costs should abstain, no matter how well informed, while those with negative net voting costs should vote, no matter how poorly informed. Thus, the purported resolution to the turnout paradox raises a new paradox of information and voter turnout. Intuitively, the quality of a vote should matter only if the vote is somehow instrumental, suggesting that future work should continue to explore instrumental rationales for voting.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Kirchgässner and Pommerehne (1993) raise a third criticism, which is that if the incentive for voting is divorced from its impact on the election outcome, there is no reason to expect citizens to vote in a particular way. A citizen could just as well vote for her least favorite alternative as for her most favorite alternative, for example, if her vote makes no difference one way or the other. Alternatively, a citizen could vote for herself as a write-in candidate, as recommended lightheartedly by Tullock (1975).

  2. For reviews of this rather large literature, see Aldrich (1993), Blais (2000), (Mueller 2003, chap. 14), Feddersen (2004), Geys (2006), and Goldfarb and Sigelman (2010).

  3. For example, see Palfrey and Rosenthal (1985), Aldrich (1993), Blais (2000), Tullock (2000), Mueller (2003), Geys (2006), and Goldfarb and Sigelman (2010). The expressive voting hypothesis of Brennan and Lomasky (1993) and the group-based ethical rationales emphasized by Feddersen (2004) deepen the interpretation of the duty term, but still are divorced from electoral outcomes. Levine and Palfrey (2007) attribute costly voting to errors in voters’ cost-benefit analysis, modeled by an additive utility term that plays the same mechanical role as civic duty.

  4. Geys (2006) also reports evidence from meta analysis that closeness matters.

  5. See also the empirical applications in (McMurray 2013, 2015).

  6. Although Tenn (2007) warns that these findings might be spurious, due to a selection effect.

  7. Coupé and Noury (2004) also document how a lack of information leads individuals to respond less completely to surveys.

  8. Mixed strategies could be allowed here, but would not be used in equilibrium. Similarly, strategies could be functions of \(s_{i}\) in addition to \(q_{i}\) and \(c_{i}\), but would be invariant to \(s_{i}\) in equilibrium.

  9. In games of Poisson population uncertainty, the finite set of citizens who actually play the game is a random draw from an infinite set of potential citizens, for whom strategies are defined (see Myerson 1998). The distribution of opponent behavior is therefore the same for any two individuals within the game (unlike a game between a finite set of players),implying that a best response for one citizen is a best response for all.

  10. Brennan (2011) argues on philosophical grounds that uninformed citizens should feel a sense of duty not to vote.

References

  • Aldrich, J. (1993). Rational choice and turnout. American Journal of Political Science, 37(1), 246–278.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ashenfelter, O., & Kelley, S. J. (1975). Determinants of participation in presidential elections. Journal of Law and Economics, 18, 695–733.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Banerjee, A. V., Kumar, S., Pande, R., & Su, F. (2011). Do informed voters make better choices? Experimental evidence from urban India. Manuscript, NBER Political Economy Meeting papers. http://www.nber.org/confer/2010/POLf10/Pande_Banerjee_Kumar_Su.pdf.

  • Bartels, L. M. (1996). Uninformed votes: Information effects in presidential elections. American Journal of Political Science, 40(1), 194–230.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Blais, A. (2000). To vote or not to vote? The merits and limits of rational choice theory. Pittsburgh: University of Pittsburgh Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Brennan, J. (2011). The ethics of voting. Princeton, New Jersey: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Brennan, G., & Lomasky, L. (1993). Democracy and decision. New York: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Condorcet, M. (1785). Essai sur l’application de l’analyse a la probabilite’ des decisions rendues a la pluralite’ des voix (Iain McLean & Fiona Hewitt, Trans.). Paris: De l’imprimerie royale (1994).

  • Coupé, T., & Noury, A. (2004). Choosing not to choose: On the link between information and abstention. Economics Letters, 84, 261–265.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dee, T. (2004). Are there civic returns to education? Journal of Public Economics, 88(9–10), 1697–1720.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Degan, A., & Merlo, A. (2011). A structural model of turnout and voting in multiple elections. Journal of the European Economic Association, 9(2), 209–245.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Downs, A. (1957). An economic theory of democracy. New York: Harper and Row.

    Google Scholar 

  • Feddersen, T. J. (2004). Rational choice theory and the paradox of not voting. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 18(1), 99–112.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Feddersen, T. J., & Pesendorfer, W. (1996). The swing voter’s curse. The American Economic Review, 86(3), 408–424.

    Google Scholar 

  • Filer, J. E., Kenny, L. W., & Morton, R. B. (2003). Redistribution, income, and voting. American Journal of Political Science, 37(1), 63–87.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fiorina, M. (1989). Restrospective voting in American national elections. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gerber, A. S., Huber, G. A., Biggers, D. R., & Hendry, D. J. (2015). Why don’t people vote in primaries? Assessing theoretical explanations for reduced participation in primary elections: Manuscript. New Haven: Yale University.

    Google Scholar 

  • Geys, B. (2006). ‘Rational’ theories of voter turnout: A review. Political Studies Review, 4, 16–35.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Goldfarb, R. S., & Sigelman, L. (2010). Does ‘civic duty’ ‘solve’ the rational choice voter turnout puzzle? Journal of Theoretical Politics, 22, 275.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Grofman, B. (1993). Is turnout the paradox that ate rational choice theory? In B. Grofman (Ed.), Information, participation, and choice. Ann Arbor, Michigan: University of Michigan Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kirchgässner, G., & Pommerehne, W. W. (1993). Low-cost decisions as a challenge to Public Choice. Public Choice, 77(1), 107–115.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Larcinese, V. (2007). Does political knowledge increase turnout? Evidence from the 1997 British general election. Public Choice, 131(3–4), 387–411.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lassen, D. (2005). The effect of information on voter turnout: Evidence from a natural experiment. American Journal of Political Science, 49(1), 103–118.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Leighley, J. E., & Nagler, J. (1992). Individual and systemic influences on turnout: Who votes? 1984. Journal of Politics, 54(3), 718–740.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Levine, D. K., & Palfrey, T. R. (2007). The pardox of voter participation? A laboratory study. The American Political Science Review, 101(1), 143–158.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Matsusaka, J. (1995). Explaining voter turnout patterns: An information theory. Public Choice, 84, 91–117.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • McMurray, J. C. (2013). Aggregating information by voting: The wisdom of the experts versus the wisdom of the masses. The Review of Economic Studies, 80(1), 277–312.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • McMurray, J. C. (2015). Ideology as opinion: Polarization in a spatial model of common-value elections. Provo: Brigham Young University.

    Google Scholar 

  • Milligan, K., Moretti, E., & Oreopoulos, P. (2004). Does education improve citizenship? Evidence from the United States and the United Kingdom. Journal of Public Economics, 88(9–10), 1667–1695.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mueller, D. C. (2003). Public Choice III. New York: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Myerson, R. (1998). Population uncertainty and poisson games. International Journal of Game Theory, 27, 375–392.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Myerson, R. (2000). Large poisson games. Journal of Economic Theory, 94, 7–45.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Oliveros, S. (2013). Abstention, ideology and information acquisition. Journal of Economic Theory, 148(3), 871–902.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Palfrey, T. R., & Poole, K. T. (1987). The relationship between information, ideology, and voting behavior. American Journal of Political Science, 31(3), 511–530.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Palfrey, T. R., & Rosenthal, H. (1985). Voter participation and strategic uncertainty. The American Political Science Review, 79(1), 62–78.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Riker, W. H., & Ordeshook, P. C. (1968). A theory of the calculus of voting. American Political Science Review, 62, 25–42.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Settle, R. F., & Abrams, B. A. (1976). The determinants of voter participation: A more general model. Public Choice, 27, 81–89.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Squire, P., Wolfinger, R. E., & Glass, D. P. (1987). Residential mobility and voter turnout. American Political Science Review, 81(1), 45–66.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Straits, V. C. (1990). The social context of voter turnout. Public Opinion Quarterly, 54, 64–73.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Strate, J. M., Parrish, C. J., Elder, C. D., & Ford, C. (1989). Life span civic development and voting participation. American Political Science Review, 82(2), 443–464.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tenn, S. (2007). The effect of education on voter turnout. Political Analysis, 15, 446–464.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Triossi, M. (2013). Costly information acquisition. Is it better to toss a coin? Games and Economic Behavior, 82, 169–191.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tullock, G. (1975). The paradox of not voting for oneself. The American Political Science Review, 69(3), 919–919.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tullock, G. (2000). Some further thoughts on voting. Public Choice, 104, 181–182.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wattenberg, M., McAllister, I., & Salvanto, A. (2000). How voting is like taking an SAT test: An analysis of american voter rolloff. American Politics Research, 28, 234–250.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wolfinger, R. E., & Rosenstone, S. J. (1980). Who votes?. New Haven: Yale University Press.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Joseph McMurray.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

McMurray, J. The paradox of information and voter turnout. Public Choice 165, 13–23 (2015). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11127-015-0288-1

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11127-015-0288-1

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation