Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

A decomposition of US business sector TFP growth into technical progress and cost efficiency components

  • Published:
Journal of Productivity Analysis Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

A problem with index number methods for computing TFP growth is that during recessions these methods show declines in TFP. This is rather implausible since it implies technological regress. We develop a new method to decompose TFP growth into technical progress and inefficiency arising from the short run fixity of capital and labour, and apply this to new data on the US corporate nonfinancial sector and the noncorporate nonfinancial sector. The analysis sheds light on sources of the productivity growth slowdowns over the period 1960–2014.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. See Jorgenson and Griliches (1967) or Balk (1998).

  2. Examples of technical regress in history include the loss of hydraulic mining techniques following the decline of the Roman Empire (Wilson 2002) and the loss of boat building technologies following societal collapse in Easter Island (Diamond 1995).

  3. Puzzling about their empirical results which seemed to show “technological degradation” for countries with very low capital-labour ratios, Kumar and Russell (2002) pithily ask the following: “Does knowledge decay? Were “blueprints” lost?”

  4. See Gordon (2016), Mokyr et al. (2015), Byrne et al. (2016), and Syverson (2016).

  5. The use of nonparametric methods for estimating technical progress can be traced back to Diewert (1980; 264); Diewert (1981); Diewert and Parkan (1983; 153–157) and Tulkens (1993; 201–206). Subsequent contributions to this “sequential” approach (where past observations on the production unit up to and including the current period are used to determine the best practice technology) include Färe et al. (1985), Tulkens and Eeckaut (1995), Suhariyanto and Thirtle (2001), Shestalova (2003) and Casu et al. (2013).

  6. We assume Ct > 0 for each t.

  7. The convexity assumption is not required in the one output case. If we assume that the best practice technology can be represented by the conical free disposal hull (FDH) of past observations, then the corresponding best practice unit cost function is still defined by (2). For references to the FDH approach to nonparametric production theory, see the pioneering contributions by Tulkens (1986, 1993) and his coauthors and the subsequent papers by Diewert and Fox (2014) (2017). Our approach can be viewed as applying cost data to Tulkens’ (1993; 201–206) sequential FDH measurement of efficiency and local technical progress approach.

  8. This approximation will become more adequate for the later observations in our sample.

  9. A reason for assuming constant returns to scale is that when we try to generalize our framework to a nonconstant returns to scale framework, we run into the problem that some of our linear programs may not have a feasible solution.

  10. This definition follows Balk (1998; 28). Note that e1 is equal to unity.

  11. Note that we are using cost efficiency rather than technical efficiency. Technical efficiency does not require price information and is therefore useful in many data constrained contexts, but prices do contain information. Ideally, such information should be always used when available.

  12. This type of cost based measure of technical progress can be traced back to Salter (1960). Balk (1998; 58) defined a family of indexes similar to that defined by (6) by using the best practice total cost function in place of the best practice unit cost function. The definitions (6)–(13) are specializations (to the case of one output) of the cost function based definitions used by Diewert (2011; 181–182) Diewert (2012; 223–225) to decompose total cost growth into explanatory factors using a reference best practice cost function. What is missing in Diewert’s decompositions is the change in cost efficiency term εt defined by (5).

  13. This will ensure that the resulting measure of technical progress satisfies the time reversal property; i.e., if we reverse the role of time and recalculate the measure of technical progress, we obtain the reciprocal of the original measure when we take the geometric average.

  14. Fisher (1922) defined his ideal index as the geometric mean of the corresponding Laspeyres and Paasche indexes and noted that the resulting index satisfied the time reversal test.

  15. If the number of outputs is equal to one, then the family of indexes defined by (10) reduces to a Konüs (1939) true cost of living index family in the case of homothetic preferences where c(w,t) is the consumer’s unit utility expenditure function using period t preferences and output is interpreted as a utility level. Shephard (1953) developed this theory of input price indexes for the case of a constant returns to scale production function.

  16. This implies that we are choosing a particular unit of measurement for aggregate output.

  17. Of course, Eq. (20) can be rearranged to give a decomposition of real output of the production unit in period t, yt, into the product of the period t input level Xt times the period t level of cost efficiency Et times the period t level of technology Tt. This is similar to Kohli’s (1990) decomposition of nominal GDP into the product of explanatory factors. See also Fox and Kohli (1998) for a similar decomposition.

  18. Diewert and Fox (2018b) also use these data to analyze factors that explain value added growth.

  19. The published data for this sector did not allow Diewert and Fox to decompose real value added into gross output and intermediate input components.

  20. A key difference between this data set and many national and international productivity data bases is the breadth of assets included. Specifically, we consider land, inventories and monetary balances as assets that generate services used in production, whereas data bases such as EUKLEMS and World KLEMS do not; see Jorgenson and Timmer (2016). We note that the Australian Bureau of Statistics produces an experimental KLEMS data base which includes land and inventories; see ABS (2015).

  21. The year t Fisher chain link input index is defined as γt* ≡ [(wt−1·xt wt·xt)/(wt−1·xt−1 wt·xt−1)]1/2.

  22. These percentages are actually percentage points. The corresponding geometric average rate of growth for our nonparametric rate of input growth γt was 1.881% per year while the corresponding Fisher index rate of input growth γt* was 1.886% per year.

  23. We thank John Fernald for suggesting taking averages over these sub-periods.

  24. For issues related to the explicit modelling of capacity utilization in the context of nonparametric frontiers, see e.g. Färe et al. (1989), De Borger et al. (2012) and references therein.

  25. Recall that the year t cost efficiency factors et are defined by (4), the year t change in cost efficiency factors εt defined by (5), the year t measures of technical progress τt defined by (9), the nonparametric input price index βt defined by (13), the nonparametric input quantity (or volume) index γt defined by (14) and the nonparametric total factor productivity growth factor for year t, TFPGt ≡ [yt/yt−1]/γt is defined by (15).

  26. The corresponding geometric average rates of growth for our nonparametric rate of input growth γt was 1.137% per year while the corresponding geometric average Fisher index rate of input growth γt* was 1.166% per year.

  27. Evidently it took the noncorporate sector some twenty years to fully recover from the effects of the first oil shock recession in 1973-74. Another possibility is that there is a considerable amount of measurement error in our data for this sector.

  28. Recall that Eqs. (17)–(19) in Section 2 converted the growth decomposition for TFP into the levels decomposition TFPt ≡ yt/Xt = EtTt defined by (20). Again define Xt* as the Fisher chained index level of input for year t and again define the Fisher index level of TFP in year t as TFPt* ≡ yt/Xt*. The Fisher input and productivity level series for the Noncorporate Nonfinancial Sector, Xt* and TFPt*, are also listed in Table 4 for comparison purposes.

  29. Note that yt, Xt and Xt* are measured in billions of constant 1960 dollars.

  30. The finding that cost inefficiency is so much bigger in the noncorporate sector can be at least partially explained by the fact that this sector uses land and structures much more intensively than the corporate sector, which uses machinery and equipment more intensively. Thus when there is a recession, due to the quasi-fixed nature of the land and structure inputs, the noncorporate sector cannot reduce their use of these inputs.

  31. This is the discussion paper version of the current paper.

References

  • ABS (2015) Experimental estimates of industry level KLEMS multifactor productivity. Australian Bureau of Statistics Information Paper, Cat. No. 5260.0.55.003, Canberra

  • Aghion P, Howitt P (1992) A model of growth through creative destruction. Econometrica 60:323–51

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Aiyar S, Dalgaard C-J, Moav O (2008) Technological progress and regress in pre-industrial times. J Econ Growth 13:125–144

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Balk BM (1998) Industrial price, quantity and productivity indices. Kluwer Academic Publishers, Boston

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Byrne DM, Fernald JG, Reinsdorf MB (2016) Does the United States have a productivity slowdown or a measurement problem? Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco Working Paper 2016-03

  • Casu B, Ferrari A, Zhao T. (2013) Regulatory Reform and Productivity Change in Indian Banking Review of Economics and Statistics 95(3):1066–1077

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Christensen LR, Jorgenson DW (1969) The measurement of U.S. real capital input, 1929–1967. Rev Income Wealth 15:293–320

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • De Borger BK, Kerstens DP, Van de Woestyne I (2012) Static efficiency decompositions and capacity utilization: integrating economic and technical capacity notions. Appl Econ 44:4125–4141

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Diamond, J (1995) Easter’s end. Discover, 16(8): 63-69

  • Diewert WE (1980) Capital and the theory of productivity measurement Am Econ Rev 70:260–267

    Google Scholar 

  • Diewert WE (1981) The theory of total factor productivity measurement in regulated industries. In: Cowing T, Stevenson R (eds.) Productivity measurement in regulated industries. Academic Press, New York, NY, pp 17–44

    Google Scholar 

  • Diewert WE (2011) Measuring productivity in the public sector: some conceptual problems. J Product Anal 36:177–191

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Diewert WE (2012) The measurement of productivity in the nonmarket sector. J Product Anal 37:217–229

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Diewert WE (2014) Decompositions of profitability change using cost functions. J Econom 183:58–66

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Diewert WE, Fox KJ (2014) Reference technology sets, free disposal hulls and productivity decompositions. Econ Lett 122:238–242

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Diewert WE, Fox KJ (2016) A Decomposition of U.S. business sector TFP growth into technical progress and cost efficiency components. Vancouver School of Economics Discussion Paper 16-04. University of British Columbia

  • Diewert WE, Fox KJ (2017) Decomposing productivity indexes into explanatory factors. Eur J Oper Res 256:275–291

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Diewert WE, Fox KJ (2018a) Alternative user costs, productivity and inequality in US business sectors. In: Greene WH, Khalaf LA, Makdissi P, Sickles R, Voia M-C (eds.) Productivity and inequality. Springer, Cham, pp 21–69

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Diewert WE, Fox KJ, Grifell-Tatj‚ E, Lovell CAK, Sickles R (2018b) Decomposing value added growth into explanatory factors. The Oxford handbook of productivity analysis. Oxford University Press, New York, NY, Chapter 19, pp 625–662

    Google Scholar 

  • Diewert WE, Parkan C (1983) Linear programming tests of regularity conditions for production functions. In: Eichhorn W, Henn R, Neumann K, Shephard RW (eds.) Quantitative studies on production and prices. Physica-Verlag, Vienna, pp 131–158

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Eaton J, Kortum S (1999) International technology diffusion: theory and measurement. Int Econ Rev 40:537–70

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Färe R, Grabowski R, Grosskopf S. (1985) "Technical Efficiency in Philippine Agriculture" Applied Economics 17:205–214

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Färe R, Grosskopf S, Kokkelenberg E (1989) Measuring plant capacity, utilization and technical change: a nonparametric approach. Int Econ Rev 30:655–66

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Färe R, Grosskopf S, Norris M, Zhang Z (1994) Productivity growth, technical progress, and efficiency change in industrialized countries. Am Econ Rev 84:66–83

    Google Scholar 

  • Farrell MJ (1957) The measurement of production efficiency. J R Stat Soc Ser A 120:253–278

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fisher I (1922) The making of index numbers. Houghton-Mifflin, Boston

    Google Scholar 

  • Fox KJ, Kohli U (1998) GDP growth, terms of trade effects and total factor productivity. J Int Trade Dev Econ 7:87–110

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Grossman G, Helpman E (1991) Innovation and growth in the global economy. MIT Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Gordon R (2016) The rise and fall of American Growth: The U.S. standard of living since the civil war. Princeton University Press, New Jersey

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Jorgenson DW, Griliches Z (1967) The explanation of productivity change. Rev Econ Stud 34:249–283

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jorgenson DW, Timmer M (2016) World KLEMS. Harvard University and the University of Groningen. http://www.worldklems.net/index.htm

  • Kohli U (1990) Growth accounting in the open economy: parametric and nonparametric estimates. J Econ Soc Meas 16:125–136

    Google Scholar 

  • Konüs AA (1939) The problem of the true index of the cost of living. Econometrica 7:10–29

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kortum S (1997) Research, patenting, and technological change. Econometrica 65:1389–1419

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Krüger JJ (2016) Revisiting the world technology frontier: a directional distance function approach. J Econ Growth, https://doi.org/10.1007/s10887-016-9136-5

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kumar S, Russell RR (2002) Technological change, technological catch-up, and capital deepening: relative contributions to growth and convergence. Am Econ Rev 92:527–548

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mokyr J, Vickers C, Ziebarth NL (2015) The history of technological anxiety and the future of economic growth: is this time different? J Econ Perspect 29:31–50

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nelson RR, Phelps ES (1966) Investment in humans, technological diffusion, and economic growth. Am Econ Rev 56:69–75

    Google Scholar 

  • Olsson O (2000) Knowledge as a set in idea space: an epistemological view on growth. J Econ Growth 5:253–275

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Romer P (1990) Endogenous technological change. J Polit Econ 98:S71–S102

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Salter WEG (1960) Productivity and technical change. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, UK

    Google Scholar 

  • Shephard RW (1953) Cost and production functions. Princeton University Press, Princeton, NJ

    Google Scholar 

  • Shestalova V. (2003) Sequential Malmquist Indices of Productivity Growth: An Application to OECD Industrial Activities Journal of Productivity Analysis 19(2-3):211–226

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Suhariyanto K, Thirtle C. (2001) Asian Agricultural Productivity and Convergence, Journal of Agricultural Economics 52(3):96–110

    Google Scholar 

  • Syverson C (2011) What Determines Productivity? J Econ Lit 49:326–365

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Syverson C (2016) Challenges to mismeasurement explanations for the U.S. productivity slowdown. National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper 21974

  • Tulkens H (1986) La Performance Productive d’un Service Public. L’Actualité Econ 62:306–335

    Google Scholar 

  • Tulkens H (1993) On FDH efficiency analysis: some methodological issues and application to retail banking, courts, and urban transit. J Product Anal 4:183–210

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tulkens H, Eeckaut PV (1995) Nonparametric efficiency, progress and regress measures for panel data: methodological aspects. Eur J Oper Res 80:474–499

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Weitzman M (1998) Recombinant growth. Q J Econ 113:331–360

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wilson A (2002) Machines, power and the ancient economy. J Roman Stud 92:1–32

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

The authors thank three anonymous referees, John Fernald, Chad Syverson, and seminar participants at the Bureau of Economic Analysis, Society for Economic Measurement Conference 2016 (Thessaloniki) and the North American Productivity Workshop 2016 (Quebec City) for helpful comments. The first author gratefully acknowledges the financial support of the SSHRC of Canada, and both authors gratefully acknowledge the financial support of the Australian Research Council (DP150100830).

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Kevin J. Fox.

Electronic supplementary material

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Diewert, W.E., Fox, K.J. A decomposition of US business sector TFP growth into technical progress and cost efficiency components. J Prod Anal 50, 71–84 (2018). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11123-018-0535-9

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11123-018-0535-9

Keywords

JEL classification

Navigation