1 Introduction

The medieval republics, the self-governed city states that emerged in Italy after AD 1000, are considered precursors of modern states in view of their early dismissal of the feudal apparatus and their innovative systems of public finance and economic regulations (e.g. Waley, 1969; Hohenberg & Lees, 1995; Epstein, 1999). Scholars have largely associated the distinctly different development paths in Italy to the presence of the republics in the North and the autocratic-feudal historical institutions in the South (e.g. Putnam et al., 1994). This paper takes a different perspective and studies the, hitherto largely neglected, comparative political economy of the territories historically ruled by these self-governed polities. We focus, in particular, on the origin and persistence of the very different socio-economic regulations implemented by the elites of the so-called “communal” and “maritime” republics. Our empirical analysis connects a variety of present-day socio-economic outcomes across spatially disaggregated northern Italian localities to the intensity and stability of exposure to the different types of republican “treatments” in these localities in pre-industrial times.

We advance a structural narrative, guided by a simple conceptual framework and supported by the historical evidence. Specifically, in the communal republics, small territorial size and the almost exclusive reliance on internal tax revenues from production and local trade meant that the elites in these polities had incentives to supply public goods and grant more personal and economic freedoms in order to elicit higher internal fiscal compliance from the population. In contrast, the larger territorial size of the maritime republics, coupled with the ability of the ruling merchants to extract rents from long-distance sea trade with their colonies abroad, implied a limited need to induce internal fiscal compliance, resulting in an opposite set of incentive-compatible strategies for these elites. The maritime polities were consequently characterized by more exclusive institutions, limited provision of public services, and personal and economic subjugation of vast segments of the population. The republics also differed in their expansion approaches: communal polities mostly aimed to stabilize territorial control and their fiscal base by also applying their inclusive regulations to the annexed territories, while the maritime polities engaged in more expansive and extractive colonial strategies.

The high level of political fragmentation and intense territorial competition between historical polities (see, Jones, 1981; Mokyr, 1992, 2016; Fukuyama, 2011) meant that, until the emergence of modern states in Europe, patterns of territorial control in pre-industrial times were fluid and often involved changes in borders (e.g. Strayer, 1970; Tilly, 1990). An important contribution of our study is the extraction and digitization of the complete political geography of Italy at yearly frequency during the AD 1000-1800 time period, including information on the origin, territorial dynamics, location of capitals, and disappearance of each independent political entity that existed within this 800-year period. We use this information on the changing spatial distribution of borders and on distance to the centers of power to build highly spatially disaggregated data on the political history of each locality (as measured by 5 \(\times\) 5 arcminute grid cells). This spatial disaggregation also allows to distinguish between the locations where a given polity came into being (i.e., the “seeds” of a republic), and the locations that were subsequently “annexed” to its territory. We measure the intensity of exposure to the rule of different polities and isolate the empirical implications of being forcefully controlled by either type of republic (communal or maritime), as well as the effect of historical instability in political rule in each location.

Our conceptual framework interprets the emergence of historical institutions with different degrees of inclusiveness as multiple “social contracts.” By this, we intend equilibria in which individual attitudes in the population and policies implemented by the ruling elites are mutually consistent and persist over time. Inclusive equilibria arise when the provision of productive regulation and fiscal compliance sustain each other, while in extractive equilibria, exploitation is coupled with fiscal avoidance. In line with this perspective, we study the legacy of local political history for public policies and attitudes today. The regression analysis is performed at the level of, the around 5000, municipalities in the North of the country, whose territories were all exposed to the rule of the medieval republics. Measuring local social contracts today, in terms of attitudes towards fiscal compliance and public good provision, at such disaggregated level is far from straightforward. We exploit municipal data on the share of households complying with the payment of a small (flat and not enforced) national television-radio tax that, we argue, represents the best available proxy for attitudes towards fiscal compliance at the local level. Data on the public provision of goods and services are extracted from municipal budgets. Finally, we collect information on the universe of surnames in each municipality and build measures of population diversity to explore the role of the differential attractiveness of the republican social contracts and historical migration.

In line with the structural origins and persistence of the divergent institutional configurations, our empirical findings show that variation in the intensity and stability of exposure of contemporary localities to different types of historical republican “treatments” still affects local social contracts today. A longer period of exposure to the rule of communal republics increases fiscal compliance and productive governance both in “seeds” and in annexed locations, while the opposite is true for the length of exposure to maritime rule, although this negative effect is detected only in annexed locations. Changes in the identity of rulers in a location can, according to the conceptual framework, impact policies and harm fiscal compliance, representing a main threat for the persistence of inclusive social contracts. In line with this view, we document that higher historical political instability has a robust negative effect on both fiscal compliance and the provision of public goods today. The results also carry over to the latent inclusivity of socio-economic institutions, as reflected by surname diversity. Our findings are robust to an extensive set of controls and checks, including a careful treatment of spatial auto-correlation. They are further confirmed with an IV strategy that exploits exogenous variation in exposure to the different polities due to the latent territorial competition and distance to the changing networks of republican centers of power. We next discuss a set of further results emerging from our analysis in light of the relevant literature.

Literature Our new database on local political history, the main empirical findings on the impact on today’s social contracts, and the additional results discussed below contribute novel insights to several recent strands of the literature on the deep determinants of political and economic development.

Relatively little is known about the historical emergence of different social contracts (that is, configurations sustained by different attitudes and policies, and the mechanisms of their persistence) and empirical evidence is scant (see Bowles, 2020; Bisin, 2020 for discussions). Our conceptualization is based on three elements that to date have not simultaneously been considered, but which we argue are necessary to understand the historical social contracts in the medieval republics. First, the process of state formation was under the control of (oligarchic) elites. As in Lizzeri and Persico (2004), Galor and Moav (2006) and Ashraf et al. (2020), discerning the economic interests of local elites is key to comprehending public policies and the inclusiveness of implemented institutions. Second, in pre-industrial times both extractive capacity and the provision of public services sharply declined with distance from centers of power (see, e.g., Cervellati et al., 2019), with important implications for the role of polity size in shaping the interests of the elites and for their strategies of territorial control.Footnote 1 Third, public policies and behavior within the population should be interpreted as jointly determined in the long run (as in, e.g., Benabou & Tirole, 2006; Tabellini, 2008; Bisin & Verdier, 2000; Besley, 2020).

This study furthermore contributes to the literature linking geography and history to diverging paths over the long term (see Ashraf & Galor, 2018; Michalopoulos & Papaioannou, 2020; Nunn, 2009 and 2020 for discussions). Historical evidence, discussed in Sect. 2, supports our structural narrative on the origin of multiple republican “treatments” and differences in observed inclusiveness. Historically, the emergence of the rule of law has been connected to the rise of merchant classes and the associated curbing of the extractive power of the landed (feudal) nobility (e.g., De Long & Shleifer, 1993; Acemoglu et al., 2005) and through the practice of more effective private-order bilateral contract enforcement (see, e.g., Greif, 1993). Our narrative qualifies these canonical arguments. As we discuss below, compared to the inter-city trade typical of the urban belt, long-distance sea trade in the maritime republics implied a more centralized control of returns in the hands of a minority of economically and politically powerful (vessel-owner) families (see also de Lara et al., 2008). This, and the extensive rents accruing from the colonies, favored the emergence of more extractive state capacity. Thus, both geography, i.e., more or less easy access to the sea, and historical contingencies, i.e., related to the ability of communal rulers to offer productive services and to the uncertain fortunes of long-distance trade and military expeditions, shaped the interests of local elites and the emerging social contracts.Footnote 2

Studies of historical republicanism have thus far relied on information on free cities or city charters (see Stasavage (2010, 2014); Bosker et al. (2013); Guiso et al. (2016); Belloc et al. (2016); Angelucci et al. (2020); Serafinelli and Tabellini (2022), among others). We offer a measurement of local exposure to these multiple republican treatments across the different locations in terms of intensity and stability at a high level of spatial disaggregation, which, following the conceptualization, also tracks the patterns and stability of forceful territorial annexation. Our results provide robust evidence of systematic differences in local policies, individual attitudes, and population diversity. The findings support, at the municipal level, the evidence advanced by Tabellini (2010), namely that regional differences in culture and policies persist within the same formal national institutions. In terms of mechanisms of historical persistence, in our conceptualization changes in the identity of rulers represent the main threat for the endurance of productive social contracts. In line with this perspective, we document that the number of polities ruling over a locality has a robust negative effect on the inclusiveness of current social contracts in terms of public good provision, individual compliance, and population diversity.Footnote 3

Our analysis also qualifies existing arguments on the role of formal political institutions. Differently from interpretations of institutions as rules or commitment devices (e.g., North, 1990; Acemoglu & Robinson, 2000), in our conceptual framework constraints on the executives are not necessary to sustain productive equilibria since, given a complying population, offering productive governance and limiting wasteful rent extraction can also be in the best interests of unconstrained ruling elites. In this perspective, though formal institutions are neither necessary nor sufficient for the emergence and persistence of productive equilibria (see also Greif & Laitin, 2004), constraints on the executive may help align expectations and favor equilibrium selection serving as a coordination device. In fact, as also discussed in Sect. 2, inclusive regulations have often persisted with the advent of lordships well after the end of republican experiences. To explore the possible role of early constraints on the executive in the selection of social contracts, we collect data on the identity of all historical chief administrators of each republic (e.g., “podestà,” “signori,” and “dogi”) and show that a higher administrative turnover in the early phases of emergence of the communal republics positively affects their duration.Footnote 4

Finally, our results intersect with investigations of the imprint of historical contingencies and geography on individual traits and population diversity. Existing evidence documents the historical drivers of trust (Nunn & Wantchekon, 2011), time preferences (Galor & Özak, 2016), loss aversion (Galor & Savitskiy, 2018), individualism (Bazzi et al., 2020), and familistic moral values (Enke, 2019), among others. We contribute to this stream of literature by showing that local political history impacts individual attitudes of fiscal compliance and also has significant, although heterogeneous, effects on measures of social capital and social cooperation.Footnote 5 Recent studies have explored population diversity on a global scale by isolating the role of long-run migrations out of Africa and genetic diversity (Ashraf & Galor, 2013; Ashraf et al., 2019a; b), the cross-country process of nation-state formation (Ahlerup & Olsson, 2012), and the long-term exposure to diseases on African etnicities (Cervellati et al., 2018). We provide evidence on the role of local productive or extractive institutions for the latent process of selected migration across densely populated historical localities. Our findings also suggest that the composition of the population, in terms of surname diversity, indirectly played a role in sustaining the different social contracts.Footnote 6

The paper is structured as follows. Section 2 discusses the predictions of the conceptual framework (a simple theoretical model is reported in the Appendix) and the historical evidence. Section 3 presents the data and the main patterns of the territorial emergence and historical evolution of the republics, as well as the measurement of local social contracts today. Section 4 provides the main empirical results, Sect. 5 details different robustness checks and further results, and Sect. 6 concludes.

2 Conceptual framework and historical evidence

Our conceptual framework considers the trade-off between rent extraction and public good provision by the ruling elites of a pre-industrial polity with imperfect state capacity over space, that is faced with endogenous fiscal compliance, or avoidance, in the population. A simple model, reported in the Appendix, illustrates the idea that both individual incentives to cover the cost of state capacity and the decisions of the elites depend on the expected level of fiscal compliance in the population at large. The resulting strategic complementarity between individual behavior and the choices of the elite allow for the possibility of multiple equilibria in terms of public policies and fiscal compliance; that is, different “social contracts.” In this section, we briefly discuss the main predictions, in line with historical evidence on the medieval republics. Historians have documented markedly different patterns of governance and social configurations within these polities. The existing evidence supports our structural narrative and predictions in terms of the interests of the ruling elites, economic and social regulations, strategies of territorial control, and patterns of selected migration.

2.1 The emergence of the republics and territorial control

At the beginning of the 11th century, particular historical contingencies profoundly changed the political landscape of the Italian peninsula. The investiture controversy between the Holy Roman Empire and the Church, and internecine wars for the imperial succession temporarily reduced the territorial grip of Holy Roman Emperors on Italian lands. This favored efforts to gain and stabilize self-governance and independence all over the peninsula. Historical circumstances led, however, to very different outcomes in the North, where the Emperor eventually had to withdraw and concede formal independence, and the South, were a successful strategic marriage stabilized the centralized feudal system.

Our conceptual framework focuses on the incentives of the rulers of the (nascent) self-governed polities, i.e., the republics. The model delivers insights on the role of the territorial size of these polities and on the optimal strategies of territorial control. A declining state capacity over space implies that productive social contracts are easier to sustain in polities of small territorial size. A further crucial element of the conceptual framework regards the varying treatment of annexed locations by the different republics. In line with the predictions, historians document that communal republics extended their regulation of economic and personal freedom to their annexed territories (see, e.g., Parker, 1996; Chittolini, 1989; Carboni, 2008). These polities “strove systematically to eliminate all intermediary and indirect forms of government and to organize their territories into lower-level districts run by officials from the city (podestà, vicari); the law, lower-level legislation, and the fiscal, juridical, and administrative rules of the city were extended to the countryside headed by the city” (Chittolini, 1989: 693).

In the maritime republics, in contrast, economic benefits were strictly confined to the population in the capital cities and, in particular, to the merchant elites that controlled the fleet. Medieval Italy was home to several self-governed maritime cities ruled by merchant elites, though not all of them succeeded as territorial polities. Pisa, Venice, and Genoa managed to develop from coastal cities into independent regional states in the Low Middle Ages, thanks also to fortunate military campaigns.Footnote 7 An increasing need for resources (particularly wood, grains and food), as well as an abundant labor force to operate the large man-powered fleet was met by heavily extracting from the hinterlands (Mallett & Hale, 1984). For instance, in 1423, 19,000 seamen were needed to operate Venice’s 3,000 merchant ships and the 43 major warships and 300 smaller ones that protected them (Chamberlin, 1982: 120). At that time, accounting for city revenues and those from inland (the Terraferma) and overseas (the Mar) territories, the Republic of Venice, or La Serenissima, was wealthier than either France or England (Braudel, 1979: 118-123). Cipolla (1994) argues that the relationship between maritime cities and their controlled territories in the 13th-14th centuries in many ways resembles that between the extractive European motherlands and their colonies up until the XIX century.

2.2 The historical social contracts

Our social contract perspective emphasizes that adopting productive, rather than extractive governance, is ultimately in the interests of the local elites. Specifically, elites’ incentives to accommodate a productive social contract are seen as instrumental to building state capacity. In line with this argument, Downing (1992), among others, argues that a need for resources, taxes, and credit in the newborn polities is key to explaining patterns of public governance in the communal republics (sometimes called “medieval constitutionalism”). In contrast, the maritime republics built their fiscal and military capacity on rents from (long-distance) sea trade. Crucially, this meant that local elites did not need to provide benefits to the populations exposed to their territorial rule and met their increasing demand for resources and manpower by implementing extractive colonial strategies.

Historians observe that the approaches of communal and maritime republics to public governance, regulation of access to economic activities, and personal freedom considerably diverged (e.g. Finer, 1999). In our model, the emergence of fiscal compliance requires the provision of benefits to the population. Historical evidence broadly supports this perspective for the communal republics, which developed fundamental innovations in public governance and social policies with their “counter-feudal and counter-monarchical theory and practice of government – Republicanism” (Finer, 1999: 951). Botero (1588) interprets the provision of “utility” to citizens as instrumental for independence and prosperity, which requires active participation of the populace. Carboni (2008: 19) stresses that taxation was “more accepted and tolerated by the taxpayers (..) [as] the spontaneous adhesions of citizens were higher.” Although outside the scope of our empirical investigation, comparable accounts exist for the case of the Dutch republics, for which our conceptual framework would similarly apply. To this regard, Van Zanden & Prak (2006: 118) observe that “citizens [of the Dutch republics] were prepared to pay relatively high taxes in return for the public goods they desired,” and that this also involved a wide range of productive regulations, from the protection of property rights to the supply of education and health services.

The maritime republics were similarly characterized by a self-governance and republican organization outside the control of the landed nobility and feudal system, though their fiscalia was more regressive and engineered to protect rents rather than to provide utility to the populace (Epstein, 1996). Illustrative of this is the well-studied case of Genoa in the early 14th century, and its need to address public debt accumulated from wars. The fiscal system was re-devised, essentially maintaining the wealth of the richest Genoese (those who could afford shares in the various compere) while taxes were raised on imports and subsistence goods. “Some tolls, the income from the entire Riviera Ponente, and taxes on markets, taverns, and butchers augmented the monies set aside to pay interest on the debt. [...] The gabelles and head tax were regressive, and much of the taxes on trade could be pushed off on prices charged to foreigners. Genoa provides a classic case of how public debt can facilitate the transfer of wealth from ordinary people to the rich, as well as defer taxes through borrowing” (Epstein, 1996: 190). In line with our argument, the populace in annexed locations was subject to extractive regulations and responded with fiscal avoidance. Similarly, Belfanti (2001: 300-302) reports that “the installation of Venetian representatives in the main cities was followed by legislative reforms and emendation of the urban statutes aimed at erasing all elements that contrasted openly with Venetian sovereignty.” The “Venetian government restricted itself to measures forbidding the sale on Venetian territory of cloth [and products] that could compete with its own output” as “Venice’s commercial supremacy, based upon a secular tradition of trade between Europe and the Levant, would not seem to have had any need of institutional support.”Footnote 8 Controlling the in-land territories required substantial effort, given the hiding of resources, elusion of duties, and recurrent uprisings and attempts to revolt by the population of ruled cities (see also Kirk, 2012).

2.3 Social inclusion and migration

Inclusive economic and social policies should be expected to favor, as mentioned, the resilience of the productive social contracts by attracting productive migrants. That the communal republics devised innovative legal regulations that increased economic and personal freedoms is well documented. Policies explicitly aimed to increase population size, the fiscal and military base, and attract skilled artisans and traders. Examples include the exemptions from payment of taxes for migrants (an early form of fiscal competition), a facilitated access to land ownership (Chittolini, 1989, and a granted freedom to conduct economic activities (Finer, 1999; Belfanti, 2001). In sharp contrast to the feudal system prevailing at the time, personal freedom was strategically used to increase the involvement of the population. For instance, thanks to the efforts of lawyer Bonaccorso da Soresina, Bologna was the first polity to fully abolish slavery in 1256 across its territory (including its contado and the annexed locations), an action that was soon replicated by other communal republics. Although formally ideologically motivated, this expensive policy consolidated the size of the free citizenry and the fiscal base of the newborn republic. The commune freed 6,000 slaves at market price with money raised within the city population. The former slaves’ “only” obligation was to reside in the territory of the republic and pay taxes. These new free citizens increased the total population of the capital city by more than a third. In contrast, in the maritime republics, slaves (and their trade) were heavily exploited, access to local manufacture and arts was kept insulated from foreigners, and trade was centrally regulated and controlled. In a well-studied case, in 1271 the Venetian elites banned the employment of foreign workers in the glass industry and, to further increase control, subsequently moved all production to Murano island, where it is located still today (see also Cipolla (1994)).

Extensive narratives support the view that within northern Italy migration between the republics was sizable. Exploiting data on invalids admitted to Florence’s hospitals between 1413 and 1456, Sandri (1988: 151) finds that 9.4% came from other communal republics. Historical accounts emphasize that migration was also driven by economic opportunities: “personal hardship could convince a worker to abandon what had been his land. Thus, [...] Sienese peasants oppressed by their debts and by the accentuated tax burden sought refuge in the countryside of Florence” (Balestracci, 1988: 167). Local elites often actively recruited foreign workers. For instance, “the urban communes negotiate even across large distances to promote in-migration of specialized workers [...]. [T]he commune [of Bologna in 1231] stipulates agreements with workers in the wool and silk sectors from several cities in Tuscany and Lombardy, in particular Verona and Lucca, offering interest-free loans, fiscal exemptions, and lodging support, which attracted about 150 masters with their families” (Barbero, 2009: 21).

Despite these extensive narratives, however, no formal evidence yet exists on the testable implication that productive social contracts should be associated to higher population diversity in the long run.

2.4 Persistence of the social contracts

Our conceptual framework highlights the instrumental role of formal institutions and constraints on the executive as coordination devices, though it also emphasizes that these are not necessarily persistent inclusive social contracts. Historians document the introduction of limits to the exercise of power in the communal republics, where “legal codes were promulgated to confine the violence of the overmighty” (Becker, 1981: 60). As a result, “the structure of authority in the communal republics was fundamentally more liberal and egalitarian than in contemporary regimes elsewhere in Europe” (Putnam et al., 1994: 125).Footnote 9

Delegation strategies were adopted and professional administrators were hired to implement productive regulations. As Putnam et al., (1994 :126) point out, “[p]ublic administration in the communal republics was professionalized. A corp of experts in municipal government developed remarkably advanced systems of public finance (including a market in negotiable public securities), land reclamation, commercial law, accounting, zoning, public hygiene, economic development, public education [...]”. These historically unprecedented forms of participation and, in particular, the limits to the exercise of authority were, however, often short-lived, eventually giving way to lordships (“signorie”). That said, the use of professional administrators (often hired from other polities) was frequently maintained.

The existence of extensive rents and the need to keep the ruled populace under control was, in contrast, associated to a more “familistic-oligarchic” and highly hierarchical administration of power in the maritime republics (see also De Lara et al., 2008; Puga & Trefler 2014). “Unlike all the other [republics], which perforce drew their podestà and their judges from other places [...], [Venice] not only called on its own native population, but upon that same nobility which staffed all other departments of the state” (Finer, 1999: 1008). Similarly, in Genoa “the representatives on the council of anziani were mostly former officeholders, and even when the wards selected the members of an advisory body, the familiar names usually predominated” (Epstein, 1996: 135). No systematic evidence exists, however, on the possible role of trained administrators and term limits in the persistence of productive social contracts.

Enduring inclusive configurations require persistence in policies and attitudes. In line with our conceptual framework, evidence suggests that inclusive policies were often not discontinued with the advent of lordships. For instance, in 1459 Duke Francesco Sforza granted certain privileges to silk workers who established residency in Milan, including citizenship, exemption from taxes and tolls for a period of ten years, and the right to employ non-Milanese workers in their shops (Fennel Mazzaoui, 1984: 527). Battilani (2001) offers suggestive evidence of the persistence of medieval multiple social contracts through an analysis of municipalities’ balance sheets at the moment of Italian unification in 1863. She documents enduring differences in the administration of local public finance that were arguably due to pre-existing differences in historical local regulation and were only partially attenuated in the forty years after unification.

3 Data and empirical patterns

The historical evidence discussed in Sect. 2 broadly aligns with our structural narrative. Here, we aim to systematically measure the evolution of local political institutions and empirically investigate their potentially persistent impact on public policies and attitudes, that is on local social contracts, – today. Broadly, we present the construction of the main variables of interest. Section 3.1 focuses on data tracking the spatio-temporal evolution of the intensity and stability of exposure to the rule of the medieval republics and provides descriptive evidence. Section 3.2 describes the construction of the outcome variables for the regression analysis and their spatial distribution.

3.1 The medieval republics

Data and measurement As no existing, ready-to-use measurement of the evolution of the territorial rule of the medieval republics is available, we collect and geo-localize information on the emergence, evolution, and disappearance of the sovereign polities ruling over Italian locations during the period 1000-1800 AD. Specifically, we assemble a yearly panel database with disaggregated data that relies on 0.0833x0.0833 degree (roughly 10x10 square kilometers at the equator, or 66 square kilometers in Italy) grid cells as units of observation. We digitize and geo-reference maps on the changing borders of each independent sovereign polity. That is, polities at the highest level of sovereignty, ruling over the territory of the Italian peninsula at yearly frequency, using the Centennia Historical Atlas of Europe (Reed, 2014) as a baseline source of information. Details on our data construction procedure, sources, description of polities, sample selection, and descriptive statistics are reported in the Supplementary Appendix 1.

Fig. 1
figure 1

Political Geography of Italy—Examples for Selected Years (Centennia Historical Atlas)

We construct several variables on the political history of each location. In particular, for each location / grid-cell, we track the territorial evolution of each polity and the turnover of rulers, giving us a measure of local “political instability.” Information on the appearance of new polities and historical sources are used to identify the emergence of each of the medieval republics. Grid-cell level information is then mapped at the level of today’s roughly 8000, Italian municipalities (at the centroid) (Fig. 1). As baseline in the regression analysis, we focus on the approximately 5000 municipalities whose territory was exposed to the rule of any medieval republic for at least one year during the observation period. Figure 2 illustrates some of the data by depicting in panel (a) a summary of the geographic distribution of the number of years a municipality was ruled by republics (in centuries, cumulating any republican experience) and in panel (b) the number of changes of ruler (including non-republics as well). On average, a given municipality was ruled by a republic for about 3 centuries and experienced 20 changes of ruler. Both variables display, however, large variation even across neighboring municipalities, ranging from only 1 year to over a millennium of republican rule, and 3 to 71 changes of ruler.

Fig. 2
figure 2

Intensity of Exposure to Republican Rule and Historical Political Instability. Time ruled by any republic and number of ruler changes in the period 1000–1800 AD (municipality level)

We also track the time-varying centrality of each location in the historical network of republics. To this end, we collected data on the set of centers of power in each year, and for each location we computed the distance to each republican capital. This information is used to build measures of the predicted, rather than actual, annexation to the rule of the different types of republics in the IV analysis.

Patterns of territorial control The database allows us to explore the predictions of the conceptual framework relative to the different strategies of territorial control in the communal and maritime republics. We distinguish between the territory ruled by each republic at the moment of its emergence, the seeds of the republic, and the locations that were subsequently annexed to the latter. To this regard, Fig. 3a depicts the locations that were ever part of the seeds of any communal republic and the territories that were annexed under the rule of any of these polities for at least a year during the observation period. Figure 3b shows the same information for the maritime republics. The seeds of communal and maritime republics are (geographically) disjointed subsets, while some locations have been annexed over the years by both communal and maritime republics.Footnote 10 In the baseline regression analysis, we exploit information on the overall duration of exposure (in centuries) as seed and as annexed territory of any communal or maritime republic. We also track the locations that had been both a seed of a communal republic and an annexed territory under the rule of a maritime republic (and viceversa), as well as locations that had been annexed to both types of republics but were never seeds.

Fig. 3
figure 3

Seeds and Annexed Locations: Communal vs Maritime Republics. Locations that formed part of a republic at its emergence are labeled Seeds. Locations that were ruled by a republic after its emergence (for at least a year) are labelled Annexed. Time period of 1000–1800 AD

The conceptual framework emphasizes the role of the territorial size of polities in the emergence of productive and extractive social contracts and the differing strategies of territorial control implemented by communal and maritime elites. In spite of the historical narratives discussed above, no formal study has thus far tracked the patterns of territorial control. Figure 4 provides supporting evidence by depicting the average size of communal and maritime republics as well as the evolution of seeds and annexed territories over the 800 years of the observation period. The data illustrates the smaller and roughly stable average size of communal republics and the larger, and increasing, territorial rule of the maritime republics.

Fig. 4
figure 4

Size of the Medieval Republics. Number of locations being ruled by a communal or maritime republic at \(5\times 5\) arcminute grid cells covering the Italian territory. Yearly data for the period of 1000–1800 AD.

Figure 5 documents the different strategies of territorial control and annexation. We see that the size of the seeds of the communal republics remains roughly stable until the mid-fifteenth century and is comparable to the size of the annexed territories (given by the difference between total territory in any year and the territory of the seeds in the same year). The opposite is true of the maritime republics, where the size of the annexed territories is substantially larger than the size of the seeds. As illustrated in the Supplementary Appendix, the number of communal republics is hump-shaped, peaking in the twelfth century and displaying a sharp reduction starting in the early fifteenth century, while the number of maritime republics is more stable. The total territory controlled by the communal and maritime republics follows similar patterns (see Fig. A.1 in the Supplementary Appendix).

Fig. 5
figure 5

Strategies of Territorial Control in the Medieval Republics. Number of locations being ruled by any communal or maritime republic (seeds and total) for \(5\times 5\) arcminute cells. Yearly data for the period of 1000–1800 AD

3.2 Socio-economic outcomes today

In this section, we turn to the outcome variables of main interest for the regression analysis.

Fiscal compliance and productive governance Measuring attitudes on fiscal compliance in the population necessarily requires dealing with “evidence of the invisible” (Slemrod & Weber, 2012). As no data on fiscal compliance exists at a disaggregated, municipal, level, we build our own measure of local fiscal compliance. Specifically, we collected information from the Italian national public broadcasting company (RAI - Radiotelevisione Italiana) on the number of households paying the television-radio license fee at the municipality level (average for the period 2004-2010). This is, for several reasons, the best available information for assessing attitudes towards fiscal compliance at a disaggregated level. First, the fee is due by all households for the mere possession of a television or radio set and therefore essentially applies to the universe of the population. Second, the annual fee is flat and comparatively small (ranging from 99.60 euros in 2004 to 109 euros in 2010), is levied at the level of households independently of the number of family members, and is paid in a single installment. The small amount implies that tax avoidance is mostly related to attitudes towards fiscal compliance rather than to the existence of sizable (and heterogenous across households) economic gains. Third, the data refers to a public good that is not provided locally and is therefore, by construction, unrelated to the efficiency of local institutions.Footnote 11 In practice, households received a letter once a year reminding them of the deadline and the amount to be paid but, given the difficulty and comparative costs of implementing controls, there was little or no enforcement and threats of checks were not credible. Evading the fee was thus very easy. Importantly, even the limited enforcement was centralized and not managed by the municipality, implying that the measure is conceptually unrelated to the effectiveness of local institutions in enforcing fiscal compliance. Fourth, information on the (lack of) payment was fully private, such that compliance can be interpreted as driven more by attitudes than by social sanctions. Fifth, data on the share of households paying the fee is available at the municipality level. Finally, the measure correlates with traditional measures of tax evasion that are, however, available only at more aggregate spatial levels.Footnote 12 We therefore have a precise and reliable measure of individual attitudes towards fiscal compliance at the municipality level for the universe of households in Italy. Average compliance with payment of the fee is 66%, though with large variability in the sample even across neighboring locations, ranging from around 13 percent to 100 percent (standard deviation around 9).

We measure local public governance using Italian National Institute of Statitstics (ISTAT) data on the provision of local public goods and services. As baseline we focus on expenditures for the provision of preschool directly supplied and managed by the municipality. Specifically, we employ information on the (logarithm of) the average expenditures during the period 2013–2018 in each municipality divided by the population (in the range 0–4.7). This variable is labeled productive governance.

Population diversity and social closure Information on the distribution of surnames across the entire population of each municipality sheds light on long-term patterns of migration across locations. Following Buonanno and Vanin (2017), we build measures that capture the differential patterns of in-migration and the latent attractiveness of historical politico-economic conditions. A higher intensity of historical in-migration in a given location manifests, all else equal, in higher levels of surname entropy today. This variable is labeled population diversity.Footnote 13 We also look at the distribution of the five most frequent surnames, which provides a more directly informative measure of the closeness of the population; we label this variable social closure.

Figure 6 depicts the spatial distribution of the main variables of interest.

Fig. 6
figure 6

Local Social Contracts and Population Diversity Today. Spatial distribution of the main outcome variables for the sample of municipalities ever ruled by medieval republics. a share of households paying the television-radio fee; b (log of) the municipality expenditures per capita for directly managed municipal preschools; c entropy (index) of the universe of surnames in the municipality; d distribution of most frequent (top) surnames

4 Empirical analysis

4.1 Econometric specification

Our baseline empirical analysis involves isolating the impact of political history on modern outcomes in specifications like,

$$\begin{aligned} Y_{i}=\gamma _{0}+\gamma _{1}Com_{i}+\gamma _{2}Mar_{i}+\gamma _{3}Inst_{i}+\delta \mathbf {X_{i}}+\epsilon _{i} \end{aligned}$$
(1)

where, for each municipality i, Y denotes an outcome variable of interest. The variables Com and Mar denote the centuries of exposure to communal and maritime republican rule, respectively, while Inst denotes historical political instability in terms of number of changes of ruler. The vector of covariates is denoted by \({\mathbf {X}}\) while \(\epsilon\) is the error term. When we distinguish the republican experience in terms of exposure as either seed or annexed location, we estimate specifications like,

$$\begin{aligned} Y_{i}=\beta _{0}+\beta _{1}SeedCom_{i}+\beta _{2}AnnCom_{i}+\beta _{3}SeedMar_{i}+\beta _{4}AnnMar_{i}+\beta _{5}Inst_{i}+\delta \mathbf {X_{i}}+\epsilon _{i}. \end{aligned}$$
(2)

where SeedCom and SeedMar denote time of exposure to communal and maritime republics as seeds while AnnCom and AnnMar denote the time of exposure to the different republics as annexed locations.

The baseline specification accounts for spatial correlation in two ways. First, standard errors are double-clustered along the two main treatment dimensions i.e., municipalities experiencing the same sequence of rulers over the period of 1000-1800 AD, and the length of republican experience (see Cameron et al., 2011). Second, we compute standard errors estimated with a spatial correction accounting for cross-sectional spatial correlation, as in Conley (1999) (reported in the Tables in squared brackets). As baseline we retain a radius of 70 Km, meaning that we can account for spatial autocorrelation with the neighboring 473 municipalities (Italian municipalities are rather small, having an average surface of 32.53 squared kilometers), and allow a Bartlett distance linear decay in the correlation structure so as to account for spatial decays even across observations within the same cluster.

4.2 Preliminary analysis: correlates of republican experiences

Before presenting our empirical investigation of current outcomes, we first explore the geographical and historical correlates of local political history. This preliminary analysis elucidates the features that may have affected the likelihood a given territory was ever part of a communal or maritime republic (as either seed or as annexed location) and the probability of being subject to more ruler changes, relevant potential confounders of modern institutional and socio-economic outcomes.

In light of our conceptual framework and the historical narratives, we control for three important baseline sets of variables: geography, historical population and routes, and historical political experiences. First, easy access to sea trade should impact the likelihood that a location is part of the (seeds of) maritime republics, while the opposite might be true for seeds of communal republics. We thus control for whether a municipality is located on or close to the coast and for distance to the sea. Altitude and ruggedness might also affect the emergence of seeds or the likelihood of being annexed. This could be either indirectly, through their impact on historical development, or directly, by making certain locations more or less easy to conquer. We also control for agricultural suitability (pre-1500 AD i.e., before the Columbus exchange) and distance from main rivers. Second, according to the conceptual framework, differences in historical levels of development, proxied in a Malthusian perspective by historical population in the year 1000 AD, can affect the likelihood that locations were republican seeds. Similarly, access to inland trade, in terms of the distance from the main trade and transportation networks given by the Roman roads (see Dalgaard et al., 2018), can have a direct impact on the emergence, in particular, of communal seeds. Third, we control for historical experiences that, in view of the literature, might interact with the emergence of the self-governed republics. To account for the role of historical centers of economic and religious power, we control for the distance from cities hosting bishops that existed in the year 1000 AD (see Belloc et al., 2016). Finally, we also control for free cities and cities fighting against the Emperor, assessed in terms of participation in the Lombard League.Footnote 14

The empirical results, reported in Table 1, show that most of these covariates impact the likelihood of different republican experiences, in line with priors (columns 1–6). In particular, proxies of easier access to sea trade increase the likelihood of being a seed of a maritime republic and decrease that of being a seed of a communal republic. Meanwhile, access to inland trade routes raises the probability of being a seed of a communal republic. Other geographic features display less systematic patterns, while historical development (measured in terms of population) increases the likelihood of being a seed of either type of republic. Notably, conditional on geography, population, and location in terms of access to inland and sea trade, no systematic significant patterns can be detected for the experiences of free cities and participation in the Lombard League.Footnote 15

Table 1 Exposure to Republics and Instability: Geographic and Historical Correlates

Results in column (7) indicate that locations on the coast, close to rivers, and near bishop cities, which presumably were historically more economically attractive in terms of territorial control and competition, are significantly associated to higher historical political instability. Meanwhile, we detect no significant patterns for other geographic and historical correlates when accounting for spatial autocorrelation.Footnote 16

4.3 Political history and local social contracts today

The conceptual framework and historical evidence support the prediction that a more intense exposure to the rule of communal republics should favor the emergence and persistence of inclusive social contracts in terms of fiscal compliance and productive governance, while the opposite is expected for the intensity of historical exposure to the rule of maritime republics, particularly as annexed locations. Historical political instability is expected to deter persistence, and therefore the likelihood of observing, inclusive social contracts. Preliminary unconditional correlations align well with these predictions (see Fig. A.5 in the Supplementary Appendix). In this Section, we report the results of a regression analysis that systematically investigates the effect of the intensity and stability of exposure to the rule of the republics on the main outcomes of interest and present a brief assessment of their quantitative impact. Further analysis documenting the validity of the main findings and additional results are discussed in Sect. 5.

Fiscal compliance and productive governance Table 2 reports the results using fiscal compliance (in columns 1–4) and productive governance (in columns 5–8) as outcome variables. We estimate the effect of the time of exposure to republican rule also distinguishing between seeds and annexed locations, to explore the predicted mechanism related to the existence of different, inclusive or exploitative, historical territorial strategies. The results provide broad support for the predicted role of political history on today’s social contracts. Being exposed to communal republics significantly increases fiscal compliance, while exposure to maritime republics has the opposite effect. Notably, the positive effect of the exposure to communal republics is mainly driven by the seeds, while the negative effect of the exposure to maritime republics is mostly driven by the annexed territories. Looking at the extremes, an increase in the time ruled as either seed of a communal republic or as annexed of a maritime republic, is respectively associated to a 11% increase and 7% reduction in the standard deviation of fiscal compliance.Footnote 17 The results for productive governance document that municipalities ruled longer by communal republics display a higher provision of public services, with an effect that is very similar in both seeds and annexed locations (although estimates for the former are more precise). The opposite is true for municipalities ruled longer by maritime republics, where the effect is largely driven by annexed locations. In line with the prior of the harmful effect of historical changes of ruler, historical political instability has a robust negative effect on both fiscal compliance and productive governance across specifications.

Table 2 The Legacy of Political History on Local Social Contracts

Population diversity and social closure The conceptual framework and historical evidence furthermore emphasize the role of inclusive institutions as instrumental in attracting in-migration. This view implies the testable prediction that a longer exposure to inclusive social contracts, proxied by the exposure to communal rule, should increase the level of population diversity. In Table 3, we report the results for population diversity, measured in terms of entropy in the population (in columns 1–4), and for social closure, measured in terms of the highest concentration of surnames (in columns 5–8). Our findings show that the intensity of exposure to communal rule increases population diversity while no significant effects are detected for the maritime republics. Locations ruled by the maritime republics, particularly as annexations, display a higher degree of social closure. Consistently, historical political instability strongly and robustly reduces population diversity (and increases social closure); plausibly explained by the lower level of attractiveness of these locations for in-migration. These patterns offer evidence that aligns with the historical narratives, namely that communal republics implemented more attractive legal regulations and offered a more permeable economic environment, which also favored the arrival of migrants (see also Sect. 5.2 below).

Table 3 The Legacy of Political History on Population Diversity

Discussion Before presenting the robustness checks and further results, we perform a quantitative assessment of the importance of the intensity and stability of historical exposure to the different types of medieval republican institutions relative to other covariates. To this end, we exploit two methodologies. First, following Ashraf et al. (2021) we compute the added explanatory power associated to each group of explanatory variables in terms of partial \(\hbox {R}^{2}\) statistics. Second, we perform a Shapley decomposition (Shorrocks, 2013) to evaluate the weight of each group of regressors in the overall estimated \(\hbox {R}^{2}\).Footnote 18

Table 4 Quantitative Assessment: Geography and History

The results of the two methodologies, reported in Table 4, deliver complementary insights. Geographical characteristics have the largest explanatory power and account, for instance, for 14 percent of the total residual variation in fiscal compliance; in the Shapley decomposition, these account for 64 percent of the overall \(\hbox {R}^{2}\). For the same variable of interest, the measures of exposure to republican rule have the second highest overall explanatory power (followed by political instability), explaining about 4% of the total residual variation and 17 percent of the overall \(\hbox {R}^{2}\) (i.e., about a third compared to geography). Interestingly, the variables tracking political history have comparatively larger explanatory power for productive governance, while geography is by far the stronger predictor of population diversity and social closure. This aligns with the insights of the conceptual framework, which interprets the effect of social contracts on population diversity to be only indirect and related to their impact on differential migration in the long run.Footnote 19 Interestingly, however, the explanatory power of geographical features is differentially reduced by the inclusion of historical covariates. This reduction tends to be small for the case of fiscal compliance and productive governance (about 1 percentage point if we compare the most parsimonious specification with the full specification) but is larger for population diversity and social closure (the reduction being 4 and 7 percentage points, respectively). Taken together, these results suggest that geography is a relatively more important driver of population diversity, but also that part of the “first nature” effects of geography for these variables runs through historical,“second nature,” mechanisms.

5 Robustness and further results

In this section, we discuss several checks performed to assess the validity of the empirical evidence, as well as present further results and additional evidence on the mechanisms at play.

5.1 Robustness

Given the use of disaggragated data, the main conceptual concerns regard the potential role of omitted location-specific characteristics and the correct handling of spatial autocorrelation. Our baseline analysis accordingly employs the empirical strategies typically implemented in the literature to deal with these issues. All results are robust to conditioning on a large set of covariates in terms of geographic and historical socio-economic and political characteristics. Given the findings of heterogenous effects, it is challenging to discern the type of omitted variables or process of selection into treatments that could drive purely statistical biases, inducing estimates with systematic opposite signs. Such omitted factors should consistently bias the estimated effects of time ruled by (annexed to) the republics in opposite directions for all the different variables of interest. Nonetheless, in this section we discuss the results of robustness checks that further explore the possible role of omitted variables and patterns of spatial clustering using an identification-by-committee approach. The findings are reported in the Supplementary Appendix.

Seemingly unrelated regressions The dimensions of the social contracts in terms of attitudes, policies, and population diversity are, in theory, co-determined in equilibrium. This implies that even if the variables explaining these outcomes are assumed to be exogenous, the error terms are not independent of one another as, for instance, a random shock to fiscal compliance in the population could impact productive governance and the attractiveness of the social contracts. The Breusch-Pagan test of independence of the error terms indeed suggests that the error terms of the four regressions are not independent of one another. To explore the potential impact of this correlation on the results, we run seemingly unrelated regressions (SUR) with double clustered standard errors. The findings reassuringly show that the results hold also when explicitly accounting for the interdependence of the outcomes of interest (see Table A.8).

Spatial autocorrelation: further checks The use of highly disaggregated data raises the question as to how to correctly implement statistical inference accounting for the role of spatial autocorrelation.Footnote 20 In the baseline analysis, we double-cluster standard-errors and use Conley standard errors with a 70 km radius. Following Colella et al. (2019), we further show that the baseline results are robust using Conley standards errors for radii ranging from 10 to 100 Km (see Appendix 3.2).Footnote 21

Geographic fixed effects and sample We further push our strategy of accounting for pre-determined confounders of the republican experiences by exploring the role of populations and polities before the advent of the republics. Specifically, we include fixed effects for Roman regions (in 117 AD, from Talbert 2000) and account for different sovereign polities ruling the Italian peninsula in the year 1000 AD (from the Centennia Historical Atlas). We assess the impact of sample composition by restricting to the territory in the North of the country (thereby also including municipalities that were never ruled by the medieval republics but were located nearby these polities). With the relevant caveat that the borders of Roman regions and early polities are uncertain and therefore likely subject to large measurement error, the results confirm the baseline findings (see Fig. A.8).

Fixed effects for random territorial units Studies using highly disaggregated data often condition on fixed effects for modern administrative units like provinces or regions. In our application, this strategy is problematic since the exposure to the republics endogenously shaped modern administrative borders. Similarly, modern covariates such as level of income or population are potentially endogenous to local political history and thus may be bad controls. To further explore unobserved local characteristics, we include simulated, rather than actual, territorial fixed effects, thereby exploiting variation within random territorial units of about the size of actual administrative provinces. We replicate the analysis a thousand times and report the distribution of point estimates obtained using the residual variation within these artificial provinces. Each random iteration also effectively implies allowing for different, and random, perturbations of the spatial autocorrelation across neighbouring locations. The results confirm the baseline finding of the opposite effects of political history in communal and maritime republics (see Fig. A.9).

Isolated locations and municipalities on historical borders Isolated municipalities, in particular those found on the island of Sardinia, display a lower degree of variability in all the variables of interest (see Figs. 2 and 6). Excluding municipalities in Sardinia confirms the observed patterns and even renders the findings slightly stronger in magnitude (see Table A.9). We also explore, following Kitamura and Lagerlöf (2020), the role of historical borders. The baseline results are robust to controlling for having been split by a border or controlling for the length of time a municipality has spent on historical borders (see Table A.10).

Predicting patterns of annexation: IV estimates Finally, we devise an IV strategy based on the conceptual framework and the historical narratives, where measures of the latent ability of rulers to annex a location is used as instrument for actual annexation. We exclude locations exposed to the republics only as seeds. This limits by construction endogeneity related to the origin of each polity. We build three instruments that are informative on the predicted annexation based on the fact that the state capacity of pre-industrial polities was declining in the distance from centers of power (see Sect. 2), and on the different strategies of territorial control and competition pursued by elites of communal and maritime republics (see Sects. 2 and 3). First, decay in the territorial grip of maritime republics is measured by the (log) distance from their capitals ruling over a location in a given moment in time, or the distance to the closest maritime capital (for the locations ruled by communal republics in a given year). Second, we build a similar variable for the distance to the capital of communal republics although, in view also of their smaller territorial size, this measure is less informative. Finally, following the idea that territories that are more centrally located in the network of communal capitals face more intensive competition and have a higher probability of be annexed, we track their centrality within the changing network of communal republics. Higher average centrality in the network of communal republics and distance to maritime capitals increase the exposure to communal republics, the distance from own (or closer) maritime capital is a strong predictor of the time spent as an annexed territory to these polities, while centrality in the network of communal republics reduces it.Footnote 22 The OLS estimates in the restricted sample of ever annexed locations are similar to the baseline. The validity of the exclusion restriction, while impossible to test, must hold conditional on the extensive set of covariates.

The IV results confirm the findings and their magnitude is two to four times larger than the OLS estimates. While generally moderate, the difference in magnitudes may be due to attenuation bias induced by measurement error and by the role of historical contingencies that are orthogonal to the instruments and lead to lower estimates of the ATE for given LATE. Specifically, while representing good predictors of the likelihood of being ruled by the different polities, the distance to communal and maritime capitals and the centrality in the communal network at a given point in time are not the only determinants of annexations by communal and maritime republics. Historical contingencies, such as conflicts or random events that impact the ability of a location to facilitate or resist annexation attempts, also likely mattered. Conceptually, the presence of such “defiers” would attenuate the estimate of the ATE relative to the estimated LATE. Reduced form, intention-to-treat, estimates are reported in Table A.11 while first stage, OLS, and IV results are reported in Table A.11.

5.2 Further results

We conclude the empirical analysis by looking at the effects of the historical republican experience on other outcomes that help shed light on the mechanisms at play. We furthermore explore additional predictions of the conceptual framework.

5.2.1 Institutions, social capital and cooperation

An assessment of the impact of political history on other relevant outcomes offers complementary evidence and insights on the mechanisms at work. The results, reported in Table 5, provide suggestive evidence that municipalities that were ruled by a communal republic also display more efficient local fiscal institutions, as measured by their effectiveness in fighting tax evasion.Footnote 23 Given the existing literature, we also look at measures of civic attitudes, social capital, and cooperation. Though the conceptual framework is, strictly speaking, silent on the predicted effect of historical social contracts on these dimensions, the results deliver several interesting patterns worth mentioning. A more intensive rule by communal republics reduces the presence of mutual aid association, while higher political instability robustly increases it.Footnote 24 A tentative interpretation of these findings is that a more effective public provision of social services reduces the need for forms of private mutual insurance, while historical political instability has the opposite effect. In line with this reasoning, we also find no crowding out effects for other measures of cooperation relating to services that cannot be offered by local government (e.g., individual organ donations) or for measures typically associated to social capital and generalized morality (e.g., electoral turnout).Footnote 25 We consistently find effects similar to those for fiscal compliance attitudes, namely a positive effect of exposure to communal republics and a negative effect of exposure to maritime republics and political instability.

5.2.2 Interaction between different “Republican Treatments”

An interesting element of local political history, tracked by our measures of political geography, is that the territory of some municipalities was exposed to the rule of both communal and maritime republics. This implies, for instance, that some locations that started out as a seed of either a communal or maritime republic were later annexed as a territory of the other type, and sometimes even reverted back to being a territory ruled by the original type. Some locations shifted back and forth as annexed territories of the two types of republics without belonging to a seed territory. A consideration of the interactions between the different republican treatments as seed and annexed locations allows to further explore the implications of exposure to different historical social contracts.Footnote 26 The findings, reported in Table A.13, show that adding information on the interactions between treatments confirms the baseline patterns on the opposite role of the intensity of exposure to each type. The estimated impact of intensity of exposure as communal seeds is slightly stronger in magnitude, while the estimated impact of annexation to a maritime republic is weaker. Interestingly, and in line with priors, locations that were originally part of communal seeds but later annexed to maritime republics display lower levels of fiscal compliance, while the opposite is true for locations that were maritime seeds but then annexed by communal polities. The same patterns can also be detected for population diversity. Finally, we do not discern any further impact for locations that were not seeds but shifted between being annexations of communal and maritime republics.

Table 5 Further Results: Institutions, Social Capital, and Cooperation

5.2.3 Historical selected migration

The historical evidence discussed in Sect. 2 and the conceptual framework (see also the discussion in the Appendix) suggest the presence of historical selected migration, driven by the differential attractiveness of the historical social contracts. We use information on surnames building on Crow’s (1983:383) observation that “surnames provide a quick, easy, cheap, and crude way to study human inbreeding and migration. Isonymy is the poor man’s population genetics.” Specifically, we exploit the fact that many Italian (and generally European) surnames originated from individual nicknames of toponym nature that mean “from...” These largely emerged in the Middle Ages and were also given to migrants from other locations. Using a simple supervised text analysis, we track the frequency of toponym surnames in each of the medieval republics, distinguishing between the communal and the maritime (e.g., “Bolognesi” or “Fiorentini” versus “Pisani” or “Veneziani”).Footnote 27 The shares of communal and maritime surnames are indirectly informative on the latent process of in-migration from the communal and maritime republics, respectively. The results, reported in Table A.14, document that locations ruled by communal republics positively attracted individuals from other republics (although significantly so only from the other communal polities), while no evidence of this latent differential migration is detected for the maritime republics.

5.2.4 Chief administrators of the medieval republics

The conceptual framework delivers further untested insights on the role of constraints on the executive as coordination devices and for the persistence of inclusive social contracts (see also the Appendix). The historical evidence discussed in Sect. 2 supports the predictions by offering extensive descriptions of the differential permeability of access to political power. In the maritime republics, this was limited to the ruling families and precluded to foreigners, while the communal republics saw the introduction of terms limits and use of professional administrators. No ready to use data is, however, available that allows to empirically explore these predictions. Here we briefly discuss suggestive evidence obtained by collecting data on the full sequence of chief administrators of each republic. This consists specifically of the name and period in office of each “podestà” or “doge” ruling over the republics during their period of existence. The information is gathered from primary archival sources, together with secondary sources used to homogenize information across languages (surnames are sometimes reported in Latin and sometimes in ancient Italian or local dialects) and across multiple spellings (the same person is often referred to slightly differently across sources). The data confirm the historical narratives and document that different communal republics often sequentially hired the same expert (e.g., a lawyer) to implement economic and legal reforms. The raw data is then used to build measures of ruler turnover. The empirical patterns display a systematically higher turnover of government administrators in the communal republics, aligning with the introduction of stricter term limits described by historians. Furthermore, in line with a latent role of early constraints on the executive as coordination devices, we observe that the communal republics that implemented a higher turnover of professional administrators in the period of their emergence lasted longer (see Fig. A.14). Finally, in Table A.15, we show that the baseline results are robust to weighted meaures of exposure to different republican experiences based on data on administrator turnover.

6 Concluding remarks

We comparatively study the political economy within the territories historically ruled by the medieval republics in northern Italy. We link the emergence of institutions and policies in the republics to the needs of local rulers to build state, fiscal, and military capacity in these newborn independent sovereign polities. We argue that existing historical evidence and narratives support the perspective that the ability of local rulers to extract rents and control large territories represented a main driver of the emergence of more inclusive or extractive socio-economic policies. Our proposed conceptual framework, which interprets multiple equilibria as social contracts, delivers a set of novel insights on the role of geography and historical contingencies in the emergence of patterns of public governance, social inclusion, and individual attitudes that mutually support each other and persist over time.

To explore the empirical validity of our predictions, we produced a novel geo-referenced database that tracks the origin, territorial evolution, and disappearance of all the sovereign polities that ruled over the Italian peninsula in the period of 1000-1800 AD and the changing locations of their centers of power. Using municipality level data, we document that the intensity and stability of historical exposure to the rule of different republics continues to shape local public policies and attitudes, and has left a tangible imprint on today’s population diversity. The evidence suggests that the degree of historical political instability, measured in terms of the number of polities ruling over each territory, and the related process of self-selected migration has impacted the persistence of productive social contracts. Our empirical results, which are robust to extensive checks, provide a first systematic evidence on the role of historical political geography as a main driver of social configurations and population diversity still today. The findings furthermore highlight the need for additional research, able to offer a deeper understanding of the role of local political history in shaping today’s political preferences and individual attitudes towards diversity and social inclusion.