1 Introduction

Corporate social responsibility (CSR) refers to all social and environmentally friendly activities of a firm beyond its legal requirements (Kitzmueller and Shimshack 2012). In the past decades, CSR has increasingly become a concern for many firms, particularly large- and mid-cap companies (Benn and Bolton 2011; KPMG 2017). Among the various motives for CSR, its strategic use in markets with imperfect competition plays an important role (Garriga and Melé 2004; Bénabou and Tirole 2010). The basic idea is that even pure profit-maximizing firms engage in CSR because it may serve as a commitment device for their strategy choices.

Although overall empirical evidence on the relation between firms’ CSR activities and their financial performance is mixed, meta-analyses such as Aguinis and Glavas (2012) confirm a small positive relation. Indeed, many recent studies find a positive correlation (Jo and Harjoto 2011; Eccles et al. 2014; Flammer 2015). This raises the question about causality: does CSR boost profits or can more profitable firms afford more CSR?

We address this question within a simple model of Cournot competition between two firms that differ in their marginal costs of production. The level of CSR determines the weight a firm puts on consumer surplus in its objective function before it decides upon supply. We find a mutual causality: the more efficient firm chooses a higher CSR level, reinforcing its dominant position. If there are sufficiently large fixed costs of CSR, an equilibrium will arise in which only the more efficient firm chooses a positive level of CSR.

2 The Model

We consider Cournot competition between two profit-maximizing firms on the market for some homogeneous good with (normalized) linear inverse demandFootnote 1p = 1 − (q1 + q2), where p denotes the price of the good and qi denotes the output of firm i ∈{1,2}. Marginal costs of production are assumed to be constant with c1 = 0 (normalization) and c2 = c, where 0 ≤ c ≤ 1, i.e., firm 1 is (possibly) more efficient than firm 2.

Competition between firms is modeled as a two-stage game. In the first stage of the game, the firms simultaneously choose their level of CSR. The CSR level of firm i ∈{1,2} is understood as the weight 𝜃i ≥ 0 on consumer surplus CS in addition to profits πi in its objective function:Footnote 2

$$ V_{i} = \pi_{i} + \theta_{i} \cdot CS = (1-q_{i}-q_{j}-c_{i})q_{i} - K_{i} + \frac{1}{2}\theta_{i}(q_{i}+q_{j})^{2}, $$

where Ki represents a quasi-fixed cost of CSR, i.e., Ki = 0 if 𝜃i = 0 and Ki = Z ≥ 0 if 𝜃i > 0.Footnote 3 Such a commitment to an objective function can be thought of as signing an appropriate corporate charter or hiring a manager known to have appropriate preferences. Our framework may thus also be interpreted as a model of strategic delegation (Vickers 1985; Fershtman and Judd 1987; Sklivas 1987).

In the second stage of the game, firms decide simultaneously on their output levels qi ≥ 0 in order to maximize their objective functions Vi.

3 Analysis

In this section, we abstract from costs of CSR (Z = 0) and solve the game by backward induction for its subgame perfect equilibria (SPE). We focus on potential SPE in which 𝜃i ∈ [0,1] for i ∈{1,2}, i.e., no firm puts more weight on consumer surplus than on profits.

At the second stage of the game, the first-order conditions Vi/qi = 0 imply the reaction functions

$$ \begin{array}{@{}rcl@{}} q_{1}(q_{2})&=& \frac{1-(1-\theta_{1})q_{2}}{2-\theta_{1}},\\ q_{2}(q_{1})&=& \frac{1-c-(1-\theta_{2})q_{1}}{2-\theta_{2}}, \end{array} $$

and thus, the second stage quantity choices as functions of the CSR levels:

$$ \begin{array}{@{}rcl@{}} q_{1}&=& \frac{1-\theta_{2}+\theta_{1}+c(1-\theta_{1})}{3-\theta_{1}-\theta_{2}}, \end{array} $$
(1)
$$ \begin{array}{@{}rcl@{}} q_{2}&=& \frac{1-\theta_{1}+\theta_{2}-c(2-\theta_{1})}{3-\theta_{1}-\theta_{2}}. \end{array} $$
(2)

At the first stage, the firms anticipate these choices and maximize their respective profits

$$ \begin{array}{@{}rcl@{}} \pi_{1}&=& \frac{(1-\theta_{2}+c-\theta_{1})(1-\theta_{2}+c+(1-c)\theta_{1})}{(3-\theta_{1}-\theta_{2})^{2}}, \end{array} $$
(3)
$$ \begin{array}{@{}rcl@{}} \pi_{2}&=& \frac{(1-2c-(1-c)\theta_{1}-(1-c)\theta_{2})(1-2c-(1-c)\theta_{1}+\theta_{2})}{(3-\theta_{1}-\theta_{2})^{2}}, \end{array} $$
(4)

by the choice of their CSR levels. The first-order conditions πi/𝜃i = 0 imply

$$ \begin{array}{@{}rcl@{}} \theta_{1}(\theta_{2})&=& \frac{(1-\theta_{2})^{2}+(1-\theta_{2})c}{3-\theta_{2}-c}, \end{array} $$
(5)
$$ \begin{array}{@{}rcl@{}} \theta_{2}(\theta_{1})&=& \frac{(1-\theta_{1})^{2}-(1-\theta_{1})(2-\theta_{1})c}{3-\theta_{1}-(2-\theta_{1})c}. \end{array} $$
(6)

It is straightforward to show that 0 ≤ 𝜃1(𝜃2) < 1 for all 0 < c < 1 and all 𝜃2 ∈ [0,1] as well as 𝜃2(𝜃1) < 1 for all 0 < c < 1 and all 𝜃1 ∈ [0,1]. Moreover, 0 < 𝜃2(𝜃1) for 0 < c < 1 and 𝜃1 ∈ [0,1] if and only if

$$ \theta_{1} < \frac{1-2c}{1-c}. $$
(7)

Consequently, for all 0 < c < 1 and 𝜃1,𝜃2 ∈ [0,1], the first stage best responses of the firms are given by the reaction functions r1(𝜃2) := 𝜃1(𝜃2) and \(r_{2}(\theta _{1}):=\max \limits \{\theta _{2}(\theta _{1}),0\}\), where 𝜃1(𝜃2) and 𝜃2(𝜃1) are defined by Eqs. 5 and 6, respectively.

Figure 1 illustrates the equilibrium CSR levels depicting the reaction functions r1 and r2 for the cost differentials c = 0, c = 1/4, and c = 1/3, respectively. Lemma 1 in the Appendix provides the comparative statics properties of the reaction functions. In particular, it shows that an increase in c increases r1 and decreases r2 wherever positive. For c = 1/3, we have r1(0) = 𝜃1(0) = 1/2 and r2(1/2) = 𝜃2(1/2) = 0 according to Eqs. 5 and 6, and thus, r1 and r2 intersect at (𝜃1,𝜃2) = (1/2,0). Lemma 1 then implies that, for any c ≥ 1/3, we always have 𝜃2 = 0 where r1 and r2 intersect. If 𝜃2 = 0, however, Eq. 5 implies the best response 𝜃1 = (1 + c)/(3 − c), and thus, q2 < 0 for all c > 1/3 by Eq. 2, i.e., the non-negativity constraint on the quantity of firm 2 will be violated. This proves

Fig. 1
figure 1

CSR levels in the SPE with asymmetric marginal costs

Proposition 1

If c ≥ 1/3, the less efficient firm will leave the market.

Notice that, without the strategic use of CSR (𝜃1 = 𝜃2 = 0), the threshold marginal cost above which the less efficient firm leaves the market is larger (c = 1/2). Strategic CSR may thus increase the market power of more efficient firms and foster market consolidation as well as the adaption of new technologies.

For smaller marginal costs, the intersection of the reaction functions r1 and r2 constitutes a SPE. We asterisk the corresponding equilibrium values.

Proposition 2

For all c ∈ (0,1/3), the two-stage game with strategic CSR and Cournot competition between two asymmetric firms has a SPE in which

  1. (a)

    The firm with the lower marginal costs chooses a higher CSR level, produces more output, and earns higher profits, i.e., \(\theta ^{*}_{1} > \theta ^{*}_{2} > 0\), \(q^{*}_{1}>q^{*}_{2} > 0\), and \(\pi ^{*}_{1}>\pi ^{*}_{2} > 0\) for all 0 < c < 1/3.

  2. (b)

    An increase in the cost differential increases the CSR level of the advantaged firm and decreases the CSR level of the disadvantaged firm, i.e., \(d\theta ^{*}_{1}/dc > 0\) and \(d\theta ^{*}_{2}/dc < 0\) for all c ∈ (0,1/3).

The proof can be found in the Appendix. For the intuition behind these results, note that in this model a higher CSR level (i.e., more weight on consumer surplus) represents a strategic commitment to a higher output. Since the more efficient firm faces lower costs of production, increasing its output is less costly for this firm. Therefore, it has stronger incentives to use this commitment device.Footnote 4 The model thus applies particularly well to environments in which CSR measures aim at a high market coverage, e.g., in the provision of pharmaceuticals in developing countries.

Proposition 2 is in line with several findings in the recent literature on strategic delegation. Straume (2006) and Fanti and Meccheri (2017) also find that the more efficient firm chooses a higher weight on the additional objective if managers maximize a weighted combination of profits and sales. For revenues as additional objective, Delbono et al. (2016) show that the more efficient firm earns higher equilibrium profits.Footnote 5 Moreover, Colombo (2019) finds that for sufficiently high cost differences the more efficient firm may even earn higher profits in the delegation equilibrium than if both firms abstained from delegation.

4 Inclusion of Fixed Costs for CSR

Fixed costs for CSR may induce firms to shy away from its strategic use. Based on numerical computations, we demonstrate that, depending on the level of fixed costs Z, different types of equilibria may exist: as Fig. 2 illustrates (for c = 0.02), we may find not only interior solutions, I, in which both firms choose positive CSR levels, but also right (left) corner solutions, R (L), in which only the more (less) efficient firm chooses a positive CSR level, or an equilibrium, O, in which neither firm engages in CSR.

Fig. 2
figure 2

Best responses and equilibria at different levels of Z (c = 0.02)

Figure 3 depicts which equilibria may occur for different combinations of asymmetric marginal costs of production, c, and symmetric quasi-fixed costs of CSR, Z. Using Eqs. 3 through 6, we compute the threshold values for Z for each given c in the following way:

$$ \begin{array}{@{}rcl@{}} Z_{0}&=&\pi_{2}(\theta_{1}(0),\theta_{2}(\theta_{1}(0)))-\pi_{2}(\theta_{1}(0),0), \\ Z_{1}&=&\pi_{2}(\theta_{1}^{*},\theta_{2}^{*})-\pi_{2}(\theta_{1}^{*},0), \\ Z_{2}&=&\pi_{1}(\theta_{1}(\theta_{2}(0)),\theta_{2}(0))-\pi_{1}(0,\theta_{2}(0)), \\ Z_{3}&=&\pi_{2}(0,\theta_{2}(0))-\pi_{2}(0,0), \\ Z_{4}&=&\pi_{1}(\theta_{1}(0),0)-\pi_{1}(0,0). \end{array} $$

Intuitively, if the costs of CSR are sufficiently small (below Z1), it may pay off for both firms to choose positive CSR levels resulting in an interior solution (I). By contrast, if the costs of CSR are prohibitively large (above Z4), both firms will abandon CSR in equilibrium (O). In the range of intermediate costs of CSR (above Z0 and below Z4), corner solutions may arise: investing these costs and choosing a sufficiently high level of CSR, one firm can “take the lead” and commit to a quantity that makes such a costly commitment unprofitable for the other firm. Since a commitment to a larger quantity is less attractive for the less efficient firm (and the less so the higher its production costs c), the range of parameters for a left corner solution (L), where only the less efficient firm engages in CSR, is restricted to the area above Z2 and below Z3. By contrast, in the whole area between Z0 and Z4, there always exists a right corner solution (R), where only the more efficient firm engages in CSR.

Fig. 3
figure 3

Occurrence of equilibria depending on c and Z

Including fixed costs for CSR, our model thus provides an explanation why firms with and without CSR engagement may coexist.

5 Conclusion

We have examined the strategic use of corporate social responsibility (CSR) in Cournot competition between two firms that differ in their marginal costs of production. The level of CSR determines the weight a firm puts on consumer surplus in its objective function before it decides upon supply. The results demonstrate that the strategic use of CSR complements cost advantages and reinforces differences in market power. Moreover, (symmetric) fixed costs of CSR provide an explanation for the coexistence of (highly profitable) firms that engage in CSR and (less profitable) firms that abstain from CSR. In the long-run, strategic CSR may thus foster market consolidation and accelerate the adoption of superior technologies.

The lessons for policymakers are twofold: First, the observation of differing CSR levels may convey information on differing costs of production. On markets with imperfect competition, a firm’s CSR level may also be an indicator of market power. Thus, such information may be useful for regulatory purposes. Second, if politics can control the fixed costs of CSR, e.g., by establishing an official CSR label, it may be able to influence the (type of) market equilibrium and outcome. We find both cases in which the government can increase consumer surplus by reducing the fixed costs of CSR and cases in which it can do so by raising them.Footnote 6

A comprehensive welfare analysis is, however, beyond the scope of this short paper.