Skip to main content
Log in

The impacts of firms’ mobility on the environmental policy

  • Research Article
  • Published:
Environmental Economics and Policy Studies Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This paper investigates the impacts of firms’ mobility on the environmental policy. We focus on two issues. The first one is the relationship between the stringency of environmental regulation and the distribution of environmental rents; the second one is how the interjurisdictional competition shapes the selection of instruments. We find that, in the absence of firms’ mobility, an instrument that allocates more rents to firms will give rise to a lower pollution tax rate, but, in the presence of mobile firms, this result may be reversed. Another finding is that the interjurisdictional competition for mobile firms can lead the governments to adopt non-revenue-raising instruments. This provides an explanation for the prevalence of such instruments without relying on political reasoning. We also find that a larger number of jurisdictions may tighten the regulation, which differs from the conventional results.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Goulder et al. (1997) have indicated that the distinction between the revenue-recycling effect and revenue-raising is important. Revenue-recycling refers to the use of environmental tax revenues to reduce other distortionary taxes or to provide public goods, rather than distributing the tax revenues in a lump-sum manner. In this paper, the revenue-raising instruments refer to the instruments that can generate the revenue-recycling effect.

  2. We ignore the agglomeration effect, which implies that \(R'>0\). We will briefly discuss what happens when \(R' > 0\) in Sect. 6.

  3. Alternatively, we can assume that the firms recognize that their emission decision can affect r. If so, then any positive r will reduce the effective pollution tax rate. Consider an extreme case where all the pollution tax revenues are returned to the polluting firms, in which case the effective pollution tax rate is equal to zero, and the imposition of the tax does not curb any pollution. This result conflicts with the real situation such as the tax on the emissions of \({\mathrm{NO}}_{{x}}\) in Sweden.

  4. Alternatively, we can interpret the pollution tax revenues as being used to cut other distortionary taxes, and the tax recycling generates a constant marginal benefit.

  5. In our framework, the two schemes are equivalent.

  6. We acknowledge that the empirical evidence about this elasticity is mixed. Assuming that \(\varepsilon < 1\) seems more reasonable, because the demand for energy is generally insensitive to changes in price (Cooper 2003).

  7. Subtracting \(D'\) from (5) gives \(t^c - D' = [(1-\varepsilon )(\theta - 1)(1-\lambda )]/ [1 - (1 - \varepsilon _j)[\lambda _j + \theta (1-\lambda _j) ] ] \ge 0\,.\)

  8. In (7), the tax rate is not treated as given; t is a function of \(\lambda \), as shown by the following (5):

  9. The derivation can be found in Appendix (1).

  10. Given \(n_j\), an increase in \(\lambda _j\) enlarges the firm’s rebated tax revenues by the amount \(\,t_j e_j\).

  11. The welfare function is not necessarily concave with respect to t, because the profit function of the firm as a function of tax rate might be convex. I am grateful to the editor for pointing this out. The second-order condition is satisfied, provided that, e.g., \(B''\) is negative and significantly large. This can be seen by differentiating the first term in the square brackets in (12) with respect to t, which gives: \(-(1-m) B'' \partial n/\partial t\). When \(B'' < 0\), \(-(1-m) B'' \partial n/\partial t\) is less than zero. If the product of these terms is sufficiently large (in absolute term), the differentiation of (12) with respect to t is less than zero, and the second-order condition is satisfied.

  12. The selection of the value of \(\lambda \) is not confined to the optimal \(\lambda \); any \(\lambda \) that is between 0 and 1 works.

  13. Some papers have discussed the effects of the distribution of the environmental rents (or the pollution tax revenues) on the stringency of pollution controls [see Fullerton and Metcalf (2001), and Bento and Jacobsen (2007)]. However, these papers consider such a distribution in a discrete style, and a feature of this present paper is to specify the distribution of the environmental rents as a continuous variable. Because of this feature, we can investigate how a change in \(\lambda \) affects the pollution tax rate.

  14. Both France and Sweden have imposed taxes on NO\(_x\). The tax revenues are used to cut other taxes in France, while the Swedish government returns all the tax revenues to the polluting firms. The tax rate in Sweden is much higher than that in France (Sterner 2003, chap. 24).

  15. The derivation of (20) can be found in Appendix (2).

  16. With the marginal pollution damage being constant, differentiating (20) with respect to \(\lambda \) gives \(\mathrm{d}^2 W^o/\mathrm{d}\lambda ^2 = -[e n \varepsilon \theta /( 1 - \lambda ( 1 - \varepsilon ) )] \cdot \mathrm{d}t/\mathrm{d}\lambda \). The second-order condition for the maximization of the social welfare, which requires \(\mathrm{d}^2W^o/\mathrm{d}\lambda ^2 < 0\), implies that \(\mathrm{d}t/\mathrm{d}\lambda \) should be positive.

References

  • Aidt TS (2010) Green taxes: refunding rules and lobbying. J Environ Econ Manag 60:31–43

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bento AM, Jacobsen M (2007) Ricardian rents, environmental policy and the ‘double-dividend’ hypothesis. J Environ Econ Manag 53:17–31

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bovenberg L, de Mooij R (1994) Environmental levies and distortionary taxation. Am Econ Rev 84:1085–1089

    Google Scholar 

  • Bovenberg L, van der Ploeg F (1994) Environmental policy, public finance and the labour market in a second-best world. J Public Econ 55:349–390

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Buchanan JM, Tullock G (1975) Polluters’ profits and political response: direct controls versus taxes. Am Econ Rev 65:139–147

    Google Scholar 

  • Cooper JC (2003) Price elasticity of demand for crude oil: estimates for 23 countries. OPEC Rev 27:1–8

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dewees D (1983) Instrument choice in environmental policy. Econ Inq 21:53–71

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fredriksson PG, Sterner T (2005) The political economy of refunded emissions payment programs. Econ Lett 87:113–119

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fullerton D (1997) Environmental levies and distortionary taxation: comment. Am Econ Rev 87:245–251

    Google Scholar 

  • Fullerton D, Metcalf G (2001) Environmental controls, scarcity rents, and pre-existing distortions. J Public Econ 80:249–267

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Glazer A (1999) Local regulation may be excessively stringent. Reg Sci Urban Econ 29:553–558

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Goulder LH, Parry IWH, Burtraw D (1997) Revenue-raising versus other approaches to environmental protection: the critical significance of preexisting tax distortions. RAND J Econ 28:708–731

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hahn RW (1990) The political economy of environmental regulation: towards a more unifying framework. Public Choice 65:21–47

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hoel M (1997) Environmental policy with endogenous plant locations. Scand J Econ 99:241–259

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kim J, Wilson JD (1997) Capital mobility and environmental standards: racing to the bottom with multiple tax instruments. Jpn World Economy 9:537–551

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kunce M, Shogren JF (2002) On environmental federalism and direct emission control. J Urban Econ 51:238–245

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kunce M, Shogren JF (2005a) On efficiency of decentralized environmental regulation. J Regul Econ 28:129–140

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kunce M, Shogren JF (2005b) On interjurisdictional competition and environmental federalism. J Environ Econ Manag 50:212–224

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lee DR, Misiolek WS (1986) Substituting pollution taxation for general taxation: some implications for efficiency in pollution taxation. J Environ Econ Manag 13:338–347

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • MacKenzie IA, Ohndorf M (2012) Cap-and-trade, taxes, and distributional conflict. J Environ Econ Manag 63:51–65

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Markusen JR, Morey ER, Olewiler N (1995) Competition in regional environmental policies when plant locations are endogenous. J Public Econ 56:55–77

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Oates WE (2001) A reconsideration of environmental federalism. Resources for the future. Olson, Washington, DC

    Google Scholar 

  • Oates WE, Schwab RM (1988) Economic competition among jurisdictions: efficiency enhancing or distortion inducing? J Public Econ 35:333–354

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ogawa H, Wildasin DE (2009) Think locally, act locally: spillovers, spillbacks, and efficient decentralized policymaking. Am Econ Rev 99:1206–1217

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pezzey J (1992) The symmetry between controlling pollution by price and controlling it by quantity. Can J Econ 25:983–991

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pfluger M (2001) Ecological dumping under monopolistic competition. Scand J Econ 103:689–706

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rauscher M (1995) Environmental regulation and the location of polluting industries. Int Tax Public Finance 2:229–244

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sterner T (2003) Policy instruments for environmental and natural resource management. Resources for the future. Olson, Washington, DC

    Google Scholar 

  • Wellisch D (1995) Locational choices of firms and decentralized environmental policy with various instruments. J Urban Econ 37:290–310

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wilson JD (1996) Capital mobility and environmental standards: is there a theoretical basis for a race to the bottom? In: Bhagwati J, Hudec R (eds) Harmonization and fair trade, vol 1. MIT Press, Cambridge, pp 395–427

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

The author is grateful to two anonymous referees and the editor Ken-Ichi Akao for their valuable comments and suggestions. The remaining errors are the author’s sole responsibility. Financial support from the Ministry of Science and Technology [106-2410-H-004 -003-] is gratefully acknowledged.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Yu-Bong Lai.

Appendix

Appendix

  1. 1.

    The derivation of (9):

    Differentiating (8) with respect to \(t_j\) gives the following:

    $$\begin{aligned} R'_j \frac{\partial n_j}{\partial t_j} - e_j [1 - \lambda (1 - \varepsilon _j)] = R'_i \frac{\partial n_i}{\partial t_j}\,. \end{aligned}$$
    (23)

    Then, differentiating \(\sum _i n_i = N\) with respect to \(t_j\) gives:

    $$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial n_i}{\partial t_j}= \frac{-1}{J - 1} \frac{\partial n_j}{\partial t_j}\,. \end{aligned}$$
    (24)

    Inserting (24) into (23), and, after some manipulations, leads to (9).

  2. 2.

    The derivation of (20):

    From (12), we have:

    $$\begin{aligned} \beta = \frac{\theta n (1 -\lambda ) (1 - \varepsilon ) R'}{1- \lambda (1-\varepsilon )} + \frac{D' n \varepsilon R'}{t [1 - \lambda (1 -\varepsilon )]}\, , \end{aligned}$$
    (25)

    where

    $$\begin{aligned} \beta = - B'(1-m) + \bar{n} m R' - \theta (1-\lambda )(1 - m)t e + D' e (1 - m)\,. \end{aligned}$$

    With the help of \(\beta \), (18) can be rewritten as follows:

    $$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial W^o}{\partial \lambda } = -\frac{t e}{R'}\left[ -\beta + \theta n R' \right] . \end{aligned}$$
    (26)

    By inserting (25) into the above equation, and after some manipulations, we obtain (20).

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Lai, YB. The impacts of firms’ mobility on the environmental policy. Environ Econ Policy Stud 21, 349–369 (2019). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10018-018-0233-x

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10018-018-0233-x

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation