Skip to main content
Log in

Skills, preferences and rights: evolutionary complementarities in labor organization

  • regular article
  • Published:
Journal of Evolutionary Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

In this paper, we model the interaction between types of workers and organizations through evolutionary game theory. In particular, we compare two paradigms of work organization: in the “hierarchical” regime, it is the organization itself that makes all relevant decisions, leaving little autonomy to its employees. Conversely, modern “networks” empower their workforce with the right to take initiatives, modulate routines and use their general knowledge in an instrumental way. In our framework, the choice to decentralize decisions is driven by the interplay between three elements: the complexity of production, the employees’ work preferences and skills and the labor-discipline implications of different organizational modes. By analyzing a series of match-specific effects, we derive parametrizations for which centralization dominates delegation and vice-versa. Explicit conditions under which the system remains stuck in Pareto-inferior situations are also obtained. Finally, we interpret our results to draw comments on the current contraction of job-discretion in OECD countries.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Braverman (1974) summarizes the philosophy of Taylorsim as follows: (i) dissociation of the labor process from the skills of the workers; (ii) separation of conception from execution, (iii) exploitation of this cognitive monopoly to control the mode of execution.

  2. For a paper analyzing the shirking-problem under centralization and delegation respectively, see Godlücke and Kranz (2012). For a classic treatment of the shirking-problem, see Shapiro and Stiglitz (1984) or Bowles (1985).

  3. In a neighboring stream of research that investigates the evolution of work pressure in Europe Green/McIntosh, 2001; Gallie 2005; Green 2004), the introduction of high involvement practices have been sometimes found responsible for the reduction of working dead-times and for the increase in the physical and psychological pressure to which employees are exposed. In this view, workplace autonomy «is perceived as a strategy for co-opting workers into a managerial perspective in order to preserve hierarchical authority without bureaucratic control» (Antonioli et al. 2009) and it is invoked as the primary cause of work intensification in Europe. In this literature, however, these new work practices have been conceptualized as Neo-Taylorist, so that they are better understood as an extension of the classical hierarchical mode of coordinating employees rather than as an alternative to it. Hence, the “challenge effect” discussed in this paper should not be confused with the “intensification effect” highlighted in this literature.

  4. Personnel and industrial psychologists have also analyzed the correlation between autonomy in teams and job-satisfaction. For a review, see Van Mierlo et al. (2006).

  5. See Acemoglu et al. (2007) and Christie et al. (2003) for empirical support.

  6. In formal terms, this occurs because \( \frac{g+s\left(1-{p}^H\right)}{g+s{p}^H}>1 \) when pH < 1/2, and since r < 1 by assumption, \( r<{\frac{g+s\left(1-{p}^H\right)}{g+s{p}^H}}_{\mid {p}^H<1/2} \) always.

  7. Meaning that all trajectories starting from an initial pair \( \left({x}_0,{y}_0\right)=\left(1,\hat{y}\right) \), \( \left({x}_0,{y}_0\right)=\left(0,\hat{y}\right) \), \( \left({x}_0,{y}_0\right)=\left(\hat{x},0\right) \) and \( \left({x}_0,{y}_0\right)=\left(\hat{x},1\right) \) will lie on the side with x = 1, x = 0, y = 0 and y = 1 respectively, where \( 0\le \hat{x}\le 1 \) and \( 0\le \hat{y}\le 1 \).

  8. In particular, Fig. 1a visualizes the third of the cases listed in point (i) of Proposition 1, that is, when condition (5) is satisfied but conditions (4) and (8) are not.

  9. Fig. 1b visualizes the case where condition (4) is not satisfied either, as can be seen from the fact that (1, 0) is a saddle.

  10. Observe that we have calculated \( {\varPi}_{\left({x}^{\ast },{y}^{\ast}\right)}^W \) from the second row of matrix (1). By construction however, the expected payoffs to the K and P strategies are equal in the (x, y) equilibrium, so we may have interchangeably calculated \( {\varPi}_{\left({x}^{\ast },{y}^{\ast}\right)}^W \) from the first row of matrix (1).

  11. As above, we have calculated \( {\varPi}_{\left({x}^{\ast },{y}^{\ast}\right)}^O \) from the second row of matrix (6). By construction, the expected payoffs to the N and H strategies are equal in the (x, y) equilibrium, so we may have interchangeably calculated \( {\varPi}_{\left({x}^{\ast },{y}^{\ast}\right)}^O \) from the first row of matrix (6).

  12. The possible Pareto-rankings of the relevant equilibria are multiple. However, the only cases that are Pareto-efficient for both populations are those reported in Proposition 2. The complete list of Pareto-rankings, along with the associated parametrisations, are given in the Appendix, which is available from the author upon request.

References

  • Acemoglu D, Aghion P, Lelarge C, Reenen JV, Zilibotti F (2007) Technology, information, and the decentralization of the firm. Q J Econ 122(4):1759–1799

    Google Scholar 

  • Aghion P, Tirole J (1997) Formal and real authority in organizations. J Polit Econ 105(1):1–29

    Google Scholar 

  • Aghion P, Bloom N, Luckling B, Sadun R, Van Reenen J (2016) Turbulence, firm decentralization and growth in bad times. NBER working paper 23354.

  • Alonso R, Dessein W, Matouschek N (2008) When does coordination require centralization? Am Econ Rev 98(1):145–179

    Google Scholar 

  • Antoci A, Sacco PL, Vanin P (2007) Social capital accumulation and the evolution of social participation. J Socio-Econ 36(1):128–143

    Google Scholar 

  • Antonioli D, Massimiliano M, Pini P (2009) Innovation, industrial relations and employee outcomes: evidence from Italy. J Econ Stud 38(1):66–90

    Google Scholar 

  • Aoki M (1986) Horizontal vs. vertical information structure of the firm. Am Econ Rev 76(5):971–983

    Google Scholar 

  • Aoki M (1995) An evolving diversity of organizational mode and its implication for transitional economies. J Jpn Int Econ 9:330–353

    Google Scholar 

  • Arundel AE, Lorenz BA, Lundvall and A. Valeyre (2007), How Europe’s economies learn: a comparison of work organization and innovation mode for the EU-15. Ind Corp Chang 16(6): 1175–1210

  • Askenazy P, Caroli E (2006) Innovative work practices, information technologies and working conditions: evidence for France. Discussion paper no. 2321, IZA, Bonn.

  • Bénabou R, Tirole J (2003) Intrinsic and extrinsic motivation. Rev Econ Stud 70(3):489–520

    Google Scholar 

  • Boltanski L, Chiappello E (2005) The new spirit of capitalism. Verso, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Bolton P, Dewatripont M (1994) The firm as a communication network. Q J Econ 109(4):809–839

    Google Scholar 

  • Bowles S (1985) The production process in a competitive economy: Walrasian, neo-Hobbesian, and Marxian models. Am Econ Rev 75(1):16–36

    Google Scholar 

  • Braverman H (1974) Labor and monopoly capital. Monthly Review Press, The degradation of work in the twentieth century. New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Brenner M, Fairris D, Ruser J (2004) Flexible work practices and occupational safety and health: exploring the relationship between cumulative trauma disorders and workplace transformation. Ind Relat (43)1: 242-66.

  • Bryson A, Forth J, Stokes L (2017) Does employees’ subjective well-being affect workplace performance? Hum Relat 70(2):1–38

    Google Scholar 

  • Calapez T, Lagoa L, Lopes H (2014) Work autonomy, work pressure, and job satisfaction: an analyzis of European Union countries. Econ Labor Relat Rev 25(2):306–326

    Google Scholar 

  • Caroli E, Greenan N, Guellec D (2001) Organizational change and skill accumulation. Ind Corp Chang 10(2):481–506

    Google Scholar 

  • Carrera JS (2018) Evolutionary dynamics of poverty traps. J Evol Econ:1–20

  • Chang J, Lai C (1999) Carrots or sticks? A social custom viewpoint on worker effort. Eu J Polit Econ 15:297–310

    Google Scholar 

  • Christie AA, Joye LP, Watts RL (2003) Decentralization of the firm: theory and evidence. J Corp Finan 9(1):3–36

    Google Scholar 

  • Cortes GM (2017) Disappearing routine jobs: who, how, and why? J Monet Econ 91:69–87

    Google Scholar 

  • Dankbaar B, Den Hertog JF, De Sitter LU (1997) From complex organizations with simple jobs to simple organizations with complex jobs. Hum Relat 50(5):497–536

    Google Scholar 

  • Deming DJ (2017) The growing importance of social skills in the labor market. Q J Econ 132(4):1593–1640

    Google Scholar 

  • DeNeve E, Krekel C, Ward G (2019) Employee Wellbeing, Productivity and Firm Performance. CEP Discussion Papers 1605, Centre for economic performance, LSE

  • Dessein W, Santos T (2006) Adaptive organizations. J Polit Econ 114(5):956–995

    Google Scholar 

  • Dewatripont M (2006) Costly communication and incentives. J Eu Econ Assoc 4(2–3):253–268

    Google Scholar 

  • Doeringer PB, Lorenz E, Terkla DG (2003) The adoption and diffusion of high-performance management: lessons from Japanese multinationals in the west. Camb J Econ 2:265–286

    Google Scholar 

  • Eurofound (2011) Cox A, Higgins T, Speckesser S. Management practices and sustainable organizational performance: An analyzis of the European Company Survey of 2009. Eurofound, Dublin

  • European Commission (2009) Commission working document. Consultation on the future EU 2020 strategy, 647/3. European Commission, Brussels

    Google Scholar 

  • Felstead A, Gallie D, Green F, Inanc H (2015) Fits, misfits and interactions: learning at work, job satisfaction and job-related well-being. Hum Resour Manag J 25(3):294–310

    Google Scholar 

  • Gallie D (2005) Work pressure in. Europe 1996–2001: trends and determinants Brit J Ind Relat 43(3):351–375

    Google Scholar 

  • Godlücke S, Kranz S (2012) Delegation, monitoring and relational contracts. Econ Lett 117:405–407

    Google Scholar 

  • Green F (2004) Why has work effort become more intense? Ind Relat 43(4):709–741

    Google Scholar 

  • Green F (2012) Employee involvement, technology and evolution in job skills: a task-based analyzis. Industrial & Labor Relations Review 65(1):35–66

    Google Scholar 

  • Green F, Felstead A, Gallie D, Henseke G (2016) Skills and work organization in Britain: a quarter century of change. J Labor Market Res 49:121–132

    Google Scholar 

  • Greenan N, Kalugia E, Walkowiak E (2013) Has the quality of working life improved in the EU-15 between 1995 and 2005? J Ind Corp Change 23(2):399–428

    Google Scholar 

  • Handel M, Levine D (2004) Editors’ introduction: the effects of new work practices on workers. Ind Relat 43(1):1–43

    Google Scholar 

  • Holm RJ, Lorenz E (2015) Has “discretionary learning” declined during the Lisbon agenda? A cross-sectional and longitudinal study of work organization in European nations. Ind Corp Chang 24(6):1179–1214

    Google Scholar 

  • Holman D, Rafferty A (2018) The convergence and divergence of job discretion between occupations and institutional regimes in Europe from 1995 to 2010. J Manag Stud 55(4):619–647

    Google Scholar 

  • Jonker LB, Taylor PD (1978) Evolutionarily stable strategies and game dynamics. Math Biosci 40:145–156

    Google Scholar 

  • Kozlowski SWJ, Bell BL (2003) Work groups and teams in organizations. In: Borman WC, Ilgen DR, Klimoski RJ (eds) Handbook of psychology: industrial and organizational psychology, vol 12. John Wiley & Sons, Hoboken, NJ, pp 333–375

    Google Scholar 

  • Kristof-Brown AL, Zimmerman RD, Johnson EC (2005) Consequences of individuals’ fit at work: a meta-analyzis of person–job, person–organization, person–group, and person–supervisor fit. Pers Psychol 58(2):281–342

    Google Scholar 

  • Lindbeck A, Snower DJ (2000) Multitask learning and the reorganization of work: from Tayloristic to holistic organization. J Labor Econ 18(3):353–376

    Google Scholar 

  • Marton F, Säljö R (1976) On qualitative differences in learning: 1 – outcome and process. The British Journal of Educational Psychology 46(1):4–11

    Google Scholar 

  • McElheran K (2014) Delegation in multi-establishment firms: evidence from I.T. purchasing. J Econ Manag Strateg 23(2):225–258

    Google Scholar 

  • Mookherjee D (2006) Decentralization, hierarchies, and incentives: a mechanism design perspective. J Econ Lit 44(2):2006

    Google Scholar 

  • Morita H (2005) Multi-skilling, delegation and continuous process improvement: a comparative analyzis of us-Japanese work organizations. Economica 72(285):69–93

    Google Scholar 

  • Nelson R, Winter S (1982) An evolutionary theory of economic change. Belknap Press, Harvard

    Google Scholar 

  • O.E.C.D. (1972) The emerging attitudes and motivations of workers, report of a management experts' meeting. Manpower and Social Affairs Directorate, Paris

    Google Scholar 

  • Rantakari H (2008) Governing adaptation. Rev Econ Stud 75(4):1257–1285

    Google Scholar 

  • Reijnders L (2018) Technology, offshoring and the rise of non-routine jobs. J Dev Econ 135:412–432

    Google Scholar 

  • Schelling TC (1978) The micromotives of macrobehavior. Norton, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Shapiro C, Stiglitz JE (1984) Equilibrium unemployment as a worker discipline device. Am Econ Rev 74(3):433–444

    Google Scholar 

  • Strauss G (1968) Human relation—1968 style. Ind Relat 7:262–276

    Google Scholar 

  • Taylor FW (1911) The principles of scientific management. Harper & Brothers, New York and London

    Google Scholar 

  • Van Mierlo H, Rutte CG, Vermunt JK (2006) Individual autonomy in work teams: the role of team autonomy, self-efficacy, and social support. Eu J Work Organ Psy 30(2):211–235

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgments

The author would like to thank Angelo Antoci, Fabio Berton, Francesco Devicienti, Thomas Kochan, Alain Marciano, Ugo Pagano, Fabrizio Pompei, Michele Rosenberg, Massimiliano Vatiero, all the participants to the 2017 WINIR conference on “Institutions and open societies”, all the participants to the 2017 Trento Summer School “New thinking on the firm” and two anonymous referees for their very useful comments on earlier versions of the paper. The usual caveats apply.

Funding

Università degli Studi di Torino. Ph.D. grant, Ph.D. program “Institutions, Economics and Law”; XXI cycle.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Stefano Dughera.

Ethics declarations

Conflict of interest

none.

Additional information

Publisher’s note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Dughera, S. Skills, preferences and rights: evolutionary complementarities in labor organization. J Evol Econ 30, 843–866 (2020). https://doi.org/10.1007/s00191-020-00675-7

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s00191-020-00675-7

Keywords

JEL classifications

Navigation