1 Introduction

The last decade saw a steady growth of the British outward FDI (OFDI) stocks into the member countries of the European Union (EU) and the European Free Trade Association (EFTA). Between 2009 and 2019, total British OFDI in Europe grew by nearly 12%, half of which was concentrated in the EU and the EFTA membersFootnote 1 (Office for National Statistics 2020). On the other hand, the British multinational firms (MNEs) faced various operational challenges, e.g., the Eurozone crisis, trade disputes, and Brexit,Footnote 2 and were often forced to adapt, and in some cases, establish new subsidiaries abroad (Bloom et al. 2019). While the trade implications of Brexit have been studied to a great degree (Dhingra et al. 2017; Dhingra and Sampson 2019; Oyamada 2020), the FDI dimension has seen little to no empirical work, with only the exception of Breinlich et al. (2020), who document a substantial increase in the number of British OFDI transactions to the EU members just after the Brexit referendum.

To date, the existing literature on British OFDI has investigated a number of topics, e.g. Kneller and Manderson (2012) evaluated the effect of environmental regulations on the pattern of British MNEs activities. Simpson (2012) examined the relationship between the structure of firms’ overseas FDI, and its performance in both manufacturing and business services using firm-level OFDI data across 1998–2004. Their findings indicate that the most productive firms are generally sorted into multinational status, and use FDI. Further, they discuss evidence that UK firms invest in low-wage economies, engage in offshoring, and display vertical integration. Following, Maza et al. (2020) studied the determinants of British MNEs in Spain and discovered that the level of wages and infrastructure development to be the main factors of the location choice of British firms. Most recently, Gurshev and Hamza (2021) scrutinized the impact of bilateral investment treaties (BITs) between the UK and its FDI partners and highlighted the dominance of horizontal motive of British OFDI, and the negative effects of participation in BITs. Not surprisingly, besides Maza et al. (2020) and Gurshev and Hamza (2021), the earlier studies made no attempts to analyze the core determinants of British OFDI, and especially, did not provide any detailed treatment of OFDI going in the EU and the EFTA. With the exception of the latter study, there has been little work on disentangling the potential puzzle between British OFDI and the ongoing profit shifting of MNEs vis-à-vis the FDI channel, especially given the economic backdrop of the last decade. Henceforth, we argue that a thorough investigation is in order as understanding the core determinants of British OFDI in the EU and the EFTA economies remains a relevant research topic.

As of 2019, the bulk of British OFDI was located in the Benelux and other parts of Western Europe, including the Netherlands (US$ 198.84 billion), Luxembourg (US$ 122.44 billion), Spain (US$ 96.06 billion), France (US$ 96.01 billion), and Ireland (US$ 70.27 billion). Figure 6 (Appendix) illustrates the partner distribution of British OFDI between 2009 and 2019. The majority of stocks were located in sectors such as financial services (US$ 275.47 billion), information and communication (US$ 110.44 billion), petroleum and chemicals (US$ 91.430 billion), retail and wholesale (US$ 54.30 billion), food and tobacco (US$ 47.67 billion). Figure 7 (Appendix) shows the sectoral distribution of the British OFDI across 2016–2019.Footnote 3 Given the existing financial links of the UK with some of the EU economies (Ireland, Luxembourg, and alike), the analysis undertaken in this paper assumes that the mass of outgoing FDI to the aforementioned locations represents transit of financial transactions due to corporate tax avoidance and profit shiftingFootnote 4 rather than real-world investments and physical operations of MNEs. This is because the existing literature documents significant amounts of quantitative evidence in regards to the profit-shifting activities of MNEs associated with the above-mentioned locationsFootnote 5 (Hines and Rice 1994; Davies et al. 2018; Damgaard et al. 2019). In particular, we hypothesize that the existing results of Breinlich et al. (2020) that document an increase in the number of financial transactions between the UK and the EU before the Brexit, at least in part, represent round-tripping via FDI because of pooled estimation with Ireland, the Netherlands, and Luxembourg present in the sample. Further, count data could be subject to bias due to the existence of pass-through transactions that are simply recorded but have nothing to do with the actual operations of MNEs.

The main goal of this paper is to provide back-of-the-envelope empirical calculations of location choice of British MNEs in the EU and the EFTA economies, using a general framework of cross-country distribution of MNEs developed in Bergstrand and Egger (2007) as a point of departure for variable selection and identification of FDI motives. Because of the fact that there could be additional covariates that influence MNEs’ location decision, e.g., tax policies, local institutions, and certain geographic features, we take the Bayesian approach, as it is able to accommodate uncertainty regarding the potential choice of covariates beyond the initial theoretical set of variables. In particular, we use the Bayesian model averaging (BMA) estimation method, which enables us to investigate a diverse set of possible covariates and select the most promising candidates as well as estimate average regression coefficients inside of model space. While the use of BMA is not entirely new to the economic literature (Sala-i-Martin et al. 2004), it has been becoming increasingly popular to empirically study all kinds of FDI data. Notable examples are Blonigen and Piger (2011, 2014), Camarero et al. (2019), and Camarero et al. (2021). Though, to the best of our knowledge, this method has not been used yet to study the determinants of British OFDI. Lastly, because of the potential data issues regarding the actual degree (or volume) of round-tripping, the analysis undertaking in this paper attempts at bridging the gap between real and round-trip FDI with the use of data-matching between the national British OFDI stock data and Damgaard et al. (2019) estimates.

The contribution of this paper to the literature is severalfold. First, in contrast to the previous studies that employ BMA, the featured methodology is built from a general equilibrium theory of cross-country distribution of MNEs, which is then applied to British OFDI data. Further, the paper analyzes the extent and degree of effects surrounding profit shifting via the FDI channel by comparing reported and estimated stocks for the selected pool of round-trip FDI partners. Next, the paper adds to the discussion on the topic of FDI determinants in Europe by examining important drivers of FDI into two subgroups of countries: pre-2000 and post-2000 EU accession members (the East–West structure of inward FDI in the EU). Finally, the paper examines the effects of the Eurozone crisis and Brexit on British OFDI in Europe.

Few facts arise from our investigation: first, we show the importance of host country characteristics such as size, level of urbanization, and the rule of law in driving horizontal FDI in large (pre-2000) EU economies. Such findings are similar to what Blonigen and Piger (2011) obtain for their FDI data, while in comparison with Camarero et al. (2019, 2021), our results support a more pronounced role of GDP-related covariates. Second, the analysis finds shifting of vertical FDI to CEE and the Nordic economies from the core-EU members. This fact extends previously found empirical evidence in Disdier and Mayer (2004), who underline the stark East–West structure of FDI in Europe. Our addition is the finding of a dynamic behavior within this structure not only East to West, but also West to North. Further, we report the negative relationship between the government effectiveness and FDI that can imply the willingness of MNEs to participate in domestic corruption mechanisms in order to obtain local permits or licenses in the host economy. This result supports previously obtained evidence on MNE operations and hosts’ corruption in Egger and Winner (2005). Third, as for post-2000 EU accession members, our findings emphasize the importance of tax revenue (e.g., infrastructure spending and public investment) and enhanced political stability in attracting FDI. The role of public investment and infrastructure has been highlighted in Justesen (2008), while the role of political stability and MNE activity has been emphasized in studies of Resnick (2001), Carmignani (2003) and Busse and Hefeker (2007), and our analysis supports this relationship. Finally, the results document the negative effects of the Eurozone crisis and Brexit anticipation on FDI stock levels in the EU and the EFTA.

The remainder of the paper organizes as follows. Section 2 introduces basic notions behind FDI, our baseline theoretical framework, and research hypotheses. Section 3 describes statistical data and empirical methodology. Section 4 reports and discusses estimation results. Section 5 concludes.

2 Theoretical framework

This section introduces the baseline framework for the identification of FDI motives. The literature on FDI and MNEs distinguishes between two types of motives for FDI: horizontal and vertical. In the horizontal motive of FDI, firms face the trade-off between maximizing proximity of production to customers and export (or trade) costs.Footnote 6 While, in the vertical motive, FDI is related to countries’ differences in relative factor endowments, where MNEs exploit cost variation between production factors in different countries. In sum, the decision of firms to engage in horizontal FDI would be driven by the market characteristics (size, population, trade barriers, etc.) of the host country, whereas vertical FDI would look for cost competitiveness of production factors (capital, labor, natural resources, etc.) among the group of countries.

To distinguish between horizontal and vertical motives, this paper relies on a general equilibrium model of MNEs location choice developed in Bergstrand and Egger (2007)—knowledge-and-physical capital model as it allows for clear differentiation between the horizontal and vertical reasons for FDI using the country-level characteristics, e.g., market size, factor endowments, bilateral barriers to trade, etc.Footnote 7 Its three core assumptions are as follows: first, services of knowledge-based activities such as R&D, patents, and know-how can be geographically separated from physical production and supplied to operating facilities when needed at low costs. Second, the knowledge-based activities are skilled labor intensive relative to production. The first two assumptions imply the vertical fragmentation of MNE operations, where skilled-intensive facilities are located in the advanced (human capital abundant) economies, while more routine manufacturing takes place in low-cost location. Finally, the knowledge-based services have a partial joint-input characteristic, so that they can be used at the same time by many production facilities. This creates firm-level economies of scale and motivates the horizontal investments that serve the domestic market by supplying goods similar to the ones available in the parent country. Thus, the resulting trade and investment interactions between countries in the model are endogenous.

The model assumes two goods (\(X\) and \(Y\)), three countries (\(H\), \(F\), and ROWFootnote 8), and three factors of production: unskilled labor (\(L\)), skilled labor (\(S\)), and physical capitalFootnote 9 (\(K\)). \(L\) and \(S\) are internationally immobile, while \(K\) is mobile in the sense that firms will endogenously choose the optimal allocation of domestic physical capital between \(H\) and \(F\) to maximize profits. The setup of firm headquarters requires the host (or home) to be endowed with skilled labor, while the setup of a plant requires the host (or home) to have physical capital.Footnote 10 Good \(Y\) is unskilled labor intensive and requires physical capital only, and is produced under constant returns to scale in a perfectly competitive industry, while good \(X\) is skilled labor intensive and produced under increasing returns to scale at the plant-level subject to Cournot oligopoly with free market entry and exit. With such market structure, there are several types of firms that can arise in the equilibrium: national firms (N-type firms) that serve domestic market and export abroad, horizontally integrated firms (H-MNEs) with two plants in both \(H\) and \(F\) countries with no international trade, and vertically integrated firms (V-MNEs) that maintain headquarters and plant in different countries with exports from an affiliate to a parent.

The cross-country distribution of these three types of firms is driven by country-pair endowment characteristics. For example, N-type firms arise in the equilibrium if one of the three countries (\(H\), \(F\), or \(ROW\)) is relatively larger and trade costs are low, which encourages domestic production and exports to a smaller country. H-MNEs become important once both \(H\) and \(F\) are similar in size and factor endowments, while bilateral trade costs are high. Firms will find it profitable to locate themselves in country \(F\) and serve local market to avoid transport and trade costs. However, if countries have different factor endowments and trade costs are low, firms prefer to specialize vertically and leverage the variation in skilled and unskilled labor between \(H\) and \(F\). Finally, the model allows all three types of firms to coexist in the equilibrium based on the initial set of calibration parameters on size, endowment, and trade cost characteristics.

While the original model does not feature closed-form solutions, the currently available data offer a number of proxies that are suitable to quantify levels of physical capital, human capital endowments, market size, distance, and bilateral barriers. Hence, the model can be operationalized by estimating a space of linear models that are initially based on the aforementioned country characteristics. However, because the model is unable to account for profit shifting via the FDI channel, this paper relies on data matching between different levels of FDI equity owned by MNEs to produce counterfactual analysis.

When put into the studied context, it is expected that the model should find the presence of both horizontal and vertical motives for FDI because the host economies of the EU and the EFTA are heterogeneous and can be at least split into two groups: large capital-rich economies (France, Germany, Italy, and others), and relatively smaller and capital scarce economies of Central and Eastern Europe (Czech Republic, Poland, Hungary, and others). In this regard, previous research found a very stark East–West structure of inward FDI into Europe. For example, for French investors, agglomeration (market-size related) effects were found to be less strong in CEE countries than core-EU members, but with an emphasis on institutional quality (Disdier and Mayer 2004). Further, because destinations like Ireland, Luxembourg, or the Netherlands feature relatively high endowments of skilled labor (on aggregate level), there is a strong overlap between vertical FDI activity and round-tripping in these destinations. Hence, we suspect that variables that are often used for vertical FDI identification (e.g. skilled labor proxy) could be biased because of the above-mentioned destinations present in the sample.Footnote 11 Lastly, because of the disruptive effects of both the Eurozone crisis and Brexit, the analysis assumes the existence of shocks to coordination between MNEs’ headquarters and affiliates with the overall result being negative for both horizontal and vertical MNEs. All in all, we test the following hypotheses:

  • Hypothesis 1: British MNEs locate horizontal FDI in the core EU economies of Western Europe and place vertical FDI in Eastern and Northern Europe.

  • Hypothesis 2: Presence of round-trip FDI partners’ stock in the global sample leads to a biased estimation of the vertical motive of FDI in relation to cost advantages in factor endowments.

  • Hypothesis 3: Both the Eurozone crisis and Brexit anticipation has had a negative impact on the volume of British OFDI stocks in the EU and the EFTA members.

3 Empirical methodology and data

3.1 Empirical methodology

As we rely on a general theory of cross-country distribution of MNEs, the analysis starts with a typically “narrow” set of covariates that is conventional to knowledge and physical capital model: factor endowments, market size, geographical proximity, and bilateral barriers to trade and investments. However, because of the fact, that there could be additional covariates that influence MNEs’ location decision (e.g. tax collection, domestic institutions, access to major trading routes, etc.), we take the Bayesian approach, as it is able to accommodate uncertainty regarding the potential choice of covariates beyond the initial theoretical set (Blonigen and Piger 2014). Hence, this paper uses BMA as it supports the study of an extraordinary large covariate space, and its output can be interpreted within the existing theory to identify types of FDI activity.

The estimating equation in the generalized form is specified as follows:

$${M}_{\gamma }:y= {X}_{0}\alpha + {X}_{\gamma }{\beta }_{\gamma }+\epsilon , \epsilon \sim \mathrm{\rm N}\left(\mu ,{\sigma }^{2}I\right)$$
(1)

where \(M\) is the model space and contains \({2}^{P}\) competing models, \(\gamma \) is a p-dimensional binary vector \(\gamma =({\gamma }_{1}, \dots ,{\gamma }_{p})\) to identify competing models, \(y\) is the n-dimensional vector of observations for the dependent variable (inward FDI stock for a given host), \({X}_{\gamma }\) is the \(n \times {p}_{\gamma }\) matrix of potential FDI determinants in \(X\), \(\mathrm{and} {\beta }_{\gamma }\) is the vector of linear regressors. The resulting model space consists of 137 billion competing models (~ \({2}^{37}\)).

Alternative model comparison is based on the posterior probability that some \({M}_{\gamma }\) is the true model that generated the data. Formally, the model selection problem is defined by the Bayes theorem:

$$\mathrm{Pr}\left({M}_{\gamma }|y\right)= \frac{{m}_{\gamma }\left(y\right)\mathrm{Pr}({M}_{\gamma })}{{\sum }_{\gamma }{m}_{\gamma }(y)\mathrm{Pr}({M}_{\gamma })}$$
(2)

where \(\mathrm{Pr}({M}_{\gamma })\) is the prior probability that \({M}_{\gamma }\) is the true model and \({m}_{\gamma }\) is the integrated likelihood with respect to the prior \({\pi }_{\gamma }\):

$${m}_{\gamma }\left(y\right)= \int {f}_{\gamma }\left(y|{\beta }_{\gamma }, \alpha , \sigma \right){\pi }_{\gamma }\left({\beta }_{\gamma }, \alpha ,{\sigma }^{2}\right)\mathrm{d}{\beta }_{\gamma } \mathrm{d}\alpha \mathrm{d}{\sigma }^{2}$$
(3)

Posterior inclusion probabilities for each competing variable can be summarized:

$$p\left({x}_{\gamma }|y\right)= \sum_{\{{M}_{I}:{x}_{\gamma }\in {M}_{I}\}}P\left({M}_{I}|y\right), \quad \gamma =\mathrm{1,2},\dots ,p$$
(4)

Following Bayarri et al. (2012), we include the “Robust prior” for the regression parameters:

$${\pi }_{\gamma }^{R}\left(\alpha ,{\beta }_{\gamma },\sigma \right)= {\sigma }^{-1}{N}_{p\gamma }\left({\beta }_{\gamma }|0,g{\Sigma }_{\gamma }\right),$$

where \({\Sigma }_{\gamma }={\sigma }^{2}{\left({V}_{\gamma }^{T}{V}_{\gamma }\right)}^{-1}\), with

$${V}_{\gamma }=({I}_{n}- {{X}_{0}\left({X}_{0}^{T}{X}_{0}\right)}^{-1}{X}_{0}^{T}){X}_{\gamma }$$

and

$$g \sim {p}_{\gamma }^{R}\left(g\right)= \frac{1}{2}\sqrt{\frac{1+n}{\left({p}_{\gamma }+{p}_{0}\right)}}{(g+1)}^{-3/2}, g>\frac{1+n}{\left({p}_{\gamma }+{p}_{0}\right)}-1$$
(5)

where \(g\) is always positive, as it ensures criteria for measurement invariance (chosen units of measurement do not affect Bayesian answers), and that \({p}_{\gamma }^{R}\left(g\right)\) is a proper density. The advantage of the “Robust prior” is its ability to obtain closed-form Bayes posterior inclusion probabilities for the employed covariates in integral (3), and statistical robustness of the obtained parameters.

The prior distribution over the model space is the Scott–Berger prior as it allows controlling for multiplicity with the prior probabilities \(\mathrm{Pr}({M}_{\gamma })\) (Scott and Berger 2006). Its function is to assign a uniform probability to models of the same dimension \(({p}_{\gamma }+{p}_{0})\). The Scott–Berger prior is defined as:

$$\mathrm{Pr}\left({H}_{\gamma }\right)={\left((p+1)\left(\genfrac{}{}{0pt}{}{p}{{p}_{\gamma }}\right)\right)}^{-1}$$
(6)

Additional approximations are done using Gibbs sampling, which is a Markov Chain Monte Carlo (MCMC) algorithm that samples from a resulting model space and yields the reported probability values of the posterior inclusion probabilities of the covariates. We run through 100,000 iterations, the probabilities stabilize at approximately 6000 mark, and the detailed evolution of the inclusion probabilities with the iterations in Gibbs sampling is illustrated in Fig. 9 of Appendix. The proposed econometric approach is implemented in R using statistical package BayesVarSel (Garcia-Donato and Forte 2018). We rely on the function GibbsBvs to obtain reported posterior inclusion probabilities of covariates, and the function BMAcoeff to obtain posterior mean of the model’s coefficients, both of the above-mentioned functions are developed by Garcia-Donato and Martinez-Beneito (2013).

3.2 Data description

Data on British OFDI are collected from the annual reports of the Office for National Statistics (2020). In particular, data are equity stocks owned by the UK-registered firms in the EU and the EFTA member countries across 2009–2019. The choice of stock data is dictated by the argument of Blonigen and Piger (2014, p. 782), that stock data represent “the long-run factors that explain the distribution of FDI.” The reported data contain disinvestments and missing observationsFootnote 12 (0.65% and 3.59% of the total sample, respectively); the number of observations for the complete partner sample is 306. The sample of host countries is illustrated in Table 1.

Table 1 Sample of countries used in the estimation.

Data on market size and relative factor endowments are sourced from the most recent version of the Penn World Table 10.0 (Feenstra et al. 2015). Distance-related costs between the UK and the host country are expressed as geographical proximity, which is measured as a distance between London and the capitals of particular partner countries (in km). The distance data are sourced from the Centre d'Etudes Prospectives et d'Informations Internationales gravity database (CEPII 2021). This baseline dataset is then augmented with additional explanatory variables, which proxy for market access, national taxation, population, industrial development, institutional characteristics, infrastructure, and geographic features (World Bank 2021; Eurostat 2021). In addition, we use a range of dummies and interaction terms that proxy common language, currency area participation, membership in the EU, or EFTA, etc. Table 2 describes the set of used explanatory variables.

Table 2 Description of variables used in the estimation.

4 Empirical results

This section presents and discusses estimation results from the estimation of BMA on British OFDI data in the EU and the EFTA economies. The analysis comes in five parts: first, the results for global sample that features original stock data are discussed (general case). Then, we report results for the case, when we apply and match Damgaard et al. (2019)’s decomposition of stock data to the selected round-trip destinations (decomposed case). Further, the results for restricted sample that completely exclude round-trip FDI are considered (restricted case). Finally, the section ends with two subgroup estimations that consider pre-2000 and post-2000 EU accession members.

The results are structured as follows: the reported posterior inclusion probabilities (PIP) reflect the marginal importance of different covariates of British MNEs location choice. Generally, the BMA literature considers PIP valueFootnote 13 for a regressor from 50 to 75% weak, from 75 to 95% positive, from 95 to 99% strong, and > 99% very strong (Raftery 1995). For the clarity of exposition, we report only those variables that obtain PIP value above the threshold of 90% with their posterior means. The estimated PIP values are shown in Figs. 1, 2, 3, 4, 5. Detailed numerical outputs can be found in Tables 3, 4, 5, 6, 7 (Appendix), while convergence graphs for each case are demonstrated in Fig. 9 (Appendix).

Fig. 1
figure 1

Posterior Inclusion probabilities for each of the potential covariates, complete sample, 2009–2019

Fig. 2
figure 2

Source Own summary

Posterior inclusion probabilities for each of the potential covariates, complete sample with decomposed round-trip FDI stocks, 2009–2019.

Fig. 3
figure 3

Inclusion probabilities for each of the potential covariates, restricted sample, excluding round-trip partners, 2009–2019

Fig. 4
figure 4

Source Own summary

Inclusion probabilities for each of the potential covariates, core subgroup, excluding round-trip partners, 2009–2019.

Fig. 5
figure 5

Source Own summary

Inclusion probabilities for each of the potential covariates, periphery subgroup, excluding round-trip partners, 2009–2019.

Figure 1 reports the general case results, robust PIP valuesFootnote 14 are obtained for the variables representing human capital difference (h_diff: + 4.56), joint market size (gdp_sum: + 6.68), geographical proximity (dist: − 0.94), market size similarity (gdp_sim: + 2.73), total and urban population in the host country (total_pop: − 2.98; urban_pop: + 2.08), landlocked dummy (landlocked: + 0.98), government effectiveness proxy (gov: − 3.92), major seaport dummy (ports: + 1.21), Brexit anticipation dummy (brexit_a: − 0.67), EU-core dummy (core: − 1.69), round-trip FDI partner dummy (phantom: + 1.43), German language proxy (lang_ger: − 1.438), the Eurozone crisis dummy (greek: − 1.51), and market size-physical capital difference interaction term (gdp_diff_k: − 0.18).

In the general case results, the horizontal motive is supported by positive coefficients on the covariates of joint market size, market size similarity, urban population of the host (due to how consumption is driven by urban areas), and seaport dummy (due to higher infrastructure level attracting FDI). Further, negative signs of the total population proxy and distance imply that MNEs favor markets with higher per-capita GDP in closer proximity to the parent economy. Then, in this case, positive signs on both landlocked and round-trip FDI dummies are likely to be driven by stocks located in Luxembourg, and Switzerland. Further, negative sign of government effectiveness can imply the willingness of MNEs to accept paying bribes in order to speed up the bureaucratic processes in the host economy (Lui 1985; Egger and Winner 2005), while negative sign of Brexit anticipation and the Eurozone crisis dummies suggest the impact of economic uncertainty on MNEs’ FDI activity in the region. Lastly, the vertical FDI motive is supported by positive coefficient on the human capital difference variable (FDI seeking low-cost skilled labor) together with negative coefficients on EU-core, German language dummies, and market size-physical capital difference interaction term, which point toward vertical FDI in countries such as Czech Republic, Hungary, and Slovakia.

In comparison with Camarero et al. (2019), who study German OFDI, the results find strong statistical evidence in support for GDP-related measures, while high PIP values of total, and urban population, language proxy, distance as well as EU-core dummy are largely in line with their findings. Additionally, the results are somewhat close to what Blonigen and Piger (2011) obtain in their estimation, though, in our data, we find a much more pronounced role of hosts’ institutional characteristics such as government effectiveness proxy having high PIP value. Finally, compared to the recent study by Camarero et al. (2021) on Japanese OFDI, our results are starkly different in regards of supporting the GDP-related covariates, as their results imply a pretty much nonexistent role of hosts’ GDP covariates in BMA estimation.

We now investigate a different case using the estimates of real FDI stock data from Damgaard et al. (2019), who decompose cross-country FDI positions into real FDI and round-trip FDI using data on Special Purpose Entities (SPEs) and non-SPEs.Footnote 15 Hence, they provide a detailed database, where both outward and inward FDI positions are broken down into two components: FDI by SPEs and non-SPEs. Then, we match data on British OFDI from their database for the selected round-trip partners using non-SPE-owned stocks and obtain the decomposed case results.

Figure 2 reports the results obtained using decomposed phantom stocks. The results indicate robust PIP values for the variables of human capital difference (h_diff: + 4.14), joint market size (gdp_sum: + 5.48), geographical proximity (dist: − 1.06), market size similarity (gdp_sim: + 2.22), urban population in the host country (urban_pop: + 2.15), tax revenues proxy (tax: + 1.25), landlocked dummy (landlocked: + 0.83), government effectiveness proxy (gov: − 3.75), major seaport dummy (ports: + 0.91), the EU-core dummy (core: − 1.63), round-trip FDI partner dummy (phantom: + 1.32), German language proxy (lang_ger: − 1.11), the Eurozone crisis dummy (greek: − 1.46), and market size-physical capital difference interaction term (gdp_diff_k: − 0.16).

In comparison with the general case results, the difference is threefold. First, the total population covariate is by far no longer robust (PIP = 0.47), and second, tax revenue proxy is now robust with positive coefficient, which suggests that there is a positive relationship between the volume of tax revenue relative to GDP of the host and inward FDI stocks. Further, because the tax revenue proxy retains its sign from the general case, it is possible to hypothesize that larger spending on infrastructure, transportations systems, and public investment attracts vertical FDI from British MNEs (Justesen 2008), with host economies of Denmark, Sweden, Norway, and Austria (tax revenue relative to GDP > 25%) driving the positive sign of this parameter. In sum, the decomposed case results offer a more mixed picture of FDI motives because now MNEs are less interested in the total population of the given market, and there is a stronger relationship between inward FDI and tax revenue collection (which is transformed into domestic spending, and investment). Lastly, the significance level of Brexit anticipation is reduced to 0.8 PIP level, yet remains fairly high.

The analysis now considers a restricted case, where round-trip FDI partners are excluded from the studied sample. Figure 3 presents restricted case, the results indicate robust PIP values for the variables of joint market size (gdp_sum; + 6.67), distance (dist: − 1.32), market size similarity (gdp_sim: + 2.77), total urban and employed population (urban_pop; + 2.66; emp_pop: − 2.524), tax revenue proxy (tax: + 1.69), government effectiveness proxy (gov: − 3.80), seaport dummy (ports: + 1.50), the EU-core dummy (core: − 1.99), German language proxy (lang_ger: − 1.15), and the Eurozone crisis dummy (greek: − 1.92).

With round-trip partners removed from the partner pool, the human capital difference proxy is no longer robust (PIP = 0.46), and the total employed population covariate is upgraded to robust with negative coefficient. The former result confirms the H2 as in the previous cases, the presence of round-trip stock was driving the importance of the factor cost advantage in skilled labor, while the latter result suggests that MNEs are trying to take advantage of unemployed workers and labor availability in countries, whose labor cost would be initially low relative to the parent economy (Billington 1999), e.g. CEE countries. Further, previously found PIP values and estimated coefficients on the variables representing market size, total urban population, tax revenue collection, location of major seaport as well as negative signs of distance, government effectiveness, the EU-core dummy, German language proxy, and the Eurozone crisis dummy, hold their values and signs with round-trip partners removed.

Finally, the analysis examines British OFDI in two subgroups (East–West divide): pre-2000 and post-2000 EU accession members. Similar to the previous case, the estimation does not contain any round-trip partners or EFTA members (each subgroup has 121 observations). Figure 4 illustrates the results from the pre-2000 subgroup; robust PIP values are obtained for the variables of market similarity (gdp_sim: + 3.61), rule of law (law: + 4.75), and the Eurozone membership (euro: − 1.83). The obtained results from the pre-2000 largely document the horizontal motive for FDI through market similarity and domestic institutions, while the negative sign on the Eurozone dummy indicates shifting of FDI to non-Euro economies of Denmark and Sweden.Footnote 16

Figure 5 presents results obtained from the post-2000 subgroup; the results picture robust PIP for the variables of market size difference (gdp_diff: − 2.76), joint market size (gdp_sum: + 18.56), tax revenue proxy (tax: + 3.28), political stability of the host (stab: + 1.09), and major seaport proxy (port: − 5.14). The results are mixed, with market size difference indicating vertical FDI, and joint market size suggesting horizontal FDI. Further, positive sign of the tax revenue proxy is driven by Malta, Latvia, Hungary, and Croatia (tax revenue relative to GDP > 20%) suggesting vertical FDI due to public spending and domestic investments. Next, positive sign of the political stability variable supports the existing literature on FDI and domestic political stability that documents the importance of security and peace for MNEs operations in the host economy (Resnick 2001; Carmignani 2003; Busse and Hefeker 2007). In particular, the beneficiaries of the enhanced political stability of the last decade are CEE economies of Czech Republic, Poland, and Slovakia. Lastly, negative sign of the seaport proxy is a result of the fact that with the exception of Poland, the post-2000 accession members do not feature any high-volume sea transportation hubs (e.g. they are landlocked or have relatively smaller volume of sea trade via domestic infrastructure).

5 Conclusion

This paper investigated the determinants of British OFDI in the EU and the EFTA economies across 2009–2019 using the general theory of MNE location choice and BMA estimation. As the data show, the British MNEs continue to be one of the most active capital-exporting firms in the global economy. Their economic relationship with the EU and the EFTA economies has remained close from operational and profit-shifting points despite growing operational uncertainty surrounding the Eurozone crisis or anticipation of Brexit. The employed theoretical framework for the identification of FDI motives and covariate selection has generally been able to meet the proposed hypotheses.

The principal takeaway of the paper is threefold. First, the results highlight the importance of market size characteristics such as size, urban concentration, the rule of law, and the location of major sea trading hubs in attaining horizontal FDI in large (pre-2004) EU economies. On the other hand, the impact of round-tripping is connected to factor cost advantages and geographical position. Second, we find the shift of vertical FDI to CEE and Nordic economies from the large core EU economies. Further, the results document the negative relationship between government effectiveness and inward FDI. Third, for pre-2004 EU accession members, the findings indicate the importance of infrastructure spending (or public investment) and enhanced political stability in attracting both vertical and horizontal FDI. Finally, the results document the negative effects of the Eurozone crisis and Brexit anticipation on FDI stock levels in the EU and the EFTA.

Overall, the empirical findings offer multiple points for discussion and potential research avenues. In particular, we think that close examination of an ongoing FDI-shifting to the Nordic economies could be an interesting extension of this paper and contribute to the study of the East–West FDI structure in Europe. Next, round-tripping via the channel FDI remains a major methodological and data challenge as detailed data on firm-level transactions are extremely scarce and generally not available (Davies et al. 2018). As a result, currently existing cross-country national FDI data should be treated with greater care in future empirical research and undergo additional analysis before being employed to derive results and policy research. The discussed results should be treated with some caution as the employed methodology has several technical limitations, like potential endogeneity of the estimated signs, or selection bias due to log-linearized model specification.