1 Introduction

The econometric modeling of energy/electricity demand (e.g., determining income/output and price effects) improves understanding regarding how energy/electricity consumption and its economic drivers have evolved historically, and how projections of income/output and price will shape future energy/electricity demand. Planning energy strategies and climate policy requires insights about long-run energy/electricity demand patterns. Specifically, these insights are useful to demand-side policymakers for managing electricity consumption using tools such as energy prices, tax rates, and tariffs. These same insights are also useful to the policymakers dealing with supply and security of energy/electricity to be generated to meet the demand adequately.

The literature includes various modeling attempts to gain insights into long-run energy demand, by examining various factors that influence that demand (e.g., energy prices, income/output/value added). While there is a substantial literature applying single-equation models to estimate the long-run energy price and economic activity elasticities of residential and transport energy demand, for example, there have been very few similar studies focused on industry energy demand (and even fewer studies on industry electricity demand). Although industry energy consumption has remained fairly steady at one-third to one-quarter of total energy consumption, electricity’s use in industry has increased substantially.Footnote 1

The share of electricity consumption in industry’s total energy consumption has been growing steadily since the 1970s, as Fig. 1 demonstrates. The figure shows the traces of electricity’s share of energy consumption for OECD Asia-Oceania, OECD Europe, OECD North America (Canada and US), and for the 30 middle-income countries in our sample. The share of electricity has been growing in nearly all of the individual 30 middle-income countries (that make up our sample) as well, and has climbed to over 30% in several of them.Footnote 2

Fig. 1
figure 1

Electricity’s share of industry energy consumption, 1971–2017. Data from IEA’s World Energy Balances. OECD Asia-Oceania includes Australia, Israel, Japan, South Korea, and New Zealand; OECD Europe excludes Turkey; OECD North America is comprised of Canada and USA; Middle-income countries are listed in Appendix Table 7 (and include Chile, Mexico, and Turkey)

Electricity also is important because industrial energy services derived from electricity typically do not have substitution possibilities from other fuels. For example, ventilation and air conditioning, lighting, cooling, and machine tool operation usually require electricity only. Indeed, Steinbuks (2012), who examined UK disaggregated manufacturing data, concluded that electricity was a poor substitute for other fuels as well, a finding that was true even for heating processes in which inter-fuel substitution is technologically more likely. Furthermore, electrification is key to unlocking efficiency improvements in industry, like the electric arc furnace and electric heat pumps.

We estimate price and output elasticities of aggregate industry electricity demand for panels of 35 high-income (mostly OECD) and 30 middle-income (mostly non-OECD) countries employing a heterogeneous dynamic panel estimator that addresses nonstationarity and cross-sectional dependence. Some of the earlier industry-focused literature have addressed issues like controlling for underlying forces or efficiency improvements (Dilaver and Hunt 2011), asymmetric price responses (Adeyemi and Hunt 2014), or dynamic panel bias (Cialani and Mortazavi 2018). However, that literature has mostly ignored other important issues—e.g., nonstationarity and cointegration, cross-sectional dependence, heterogeneity, and allowing for dynamics more complicated than the partial adjustment model. In addition, there has been a limited number of panel studies of aggregate industry energy/electricity consumption for OECD countries, and no such coverage for non-OECD country panelsFootnote 3—with only a rather limited number of single, non-OECD country studies—because of a lack of energy/electricity price data for countries outside OECD/IEA.

Hence, we contribute to this literature by: (i) considering a larger high-income/OECD panel than has been examined before, and one that focuses on industry electricity demand and estimates an industry output elasticity as opposed to considering aggregate income/GDP measures, as have previous studies; (ii) applying a more flexible dynamic model; and (iii) using methods that address heterogeneity and cross-sectional dependence and thereby account for both (a) unobserved factors that commonly affect the panel members and (b) country-specific factors that make each panel member different from other members. Moreover, for the first time we present estimates of price and output elasticities of industry electricity based on a panel of middle-income, mostly non-OECD countries, roughly three-quarters-to-half of which, to our knowledge, have never been analyzed before (even in a single country setting). So, for the first time to our knowledge, we are able to answer the question: whether industry price and output elasticities differ between high-income/OECD and middle-income/non-OECD countries and, if so, by how much?Footnote 4 In addition, we derived policy insights from our findings to inform demand-side management, supply-side planning, and environmental aspects of industrial electricity consumption.

2 Literature review

We surveyed papers that investigated the effects of both output and price on industrial energy/electricity demand at the aggregate (rather than firm) level. While there have been several single country OECD estimates (particularly so for UK and US), we concentrate our review on OECD panel analyses. Hence, we first grouped papers that considered cross-national (as opposed to inter-state/province) panels, and we summarized such studies in Table 1. Next, since there have been relatively few papers that focused on analyzing output and price elasticities of industry electricity/energy demand in non-OECD countries (effectively no panels, only single country studies), we summarized these (single-country) papers in Table 2 and discuss them briefly below as well. In other words, we have attempted to produce a more or less exhaustive list of OECD panel studies and single-country non-OECD studies.

Table 1 Cross-national panel studies of industrial energy (electricity) demand
Table 2 Individual non-OECD country studies of industrial electricity (or energy) demand

We focus on the long-run estimations of the elasticities. However, many papers that employed a dynamic model did not report the statistical significance of their long-run estimations; yet, they did report the significance of their short-run estimations, and so, from those reported statistics we can surmise the likely significance of the long-run estimations.

Industry energy, cross-national panel estimations of price and output elasticities have focused on OECD/European panels as outlined in Table 1. All five of these cross-national panel analyses have used the less flexible dynamic partial adjustment model, have employed methods that did not address cross-sectional dependence, and were homogeneous. They also did not address nonstationarity and cointegration properties of the data used.Footnote 5 (These omissions are despite the fact that four of the five papers are rather recent.)

Adeyemi and Hunt (2007) estimated long-run output and price elasticities of 0.56 and − 0.22, respectively, for a panel of 15 OECD countries. Given that the short-run estimate for price was highly insignificant (t-value below 0.7), the long-run estimate was likely insignificant as well. (In a separate regression, Adeyemi and Hunt allowed for asymmetric responses to price changes, and some of those coefficients were statistically significant.)

Chang et al. (2019) considered a panel of 20 OECD countries and 16 industry sectors. They reported long-run output and price elasticities of 0.88 and − 0.05, respectively, for their full panel and preferred specification. In addition, Chang et al. estimated elasticities for a panel of the five most energy intensive sectors and a panel of the remaining less energy intensive sectors. Their long-run results suggested that energy-intensive sectors have larger output elasticities of energy demand than do less-intensive sectors: 1.23 compared to 0.48, respectively. But energy-intensive sectors are less price sensitive than less-energy-intensive sectors, i.e., they calculated long-run price elasticities of − 0.13 and − 0.23 for the intensive and less-intensive panels, respectively. All three long-run price elasticities were likely insignificant since the short-run price elasticities were highly insignificant.

Sharimakin et al. (2018) estimated industrial energy demand for 29 European countries over 1995–2009. Their long-run panel elasticities for output and price of 0.83 and − 0.77, respectively, are relatively large compared to the previous two studies (at least their price elasticity is large in absolute terms). The methodology they employed, Multilevel Data Structures Modeling, while common in several disciplines (e.g., political science, education, and health),Footnote 6 has rarely been applied in energy demand modeling. One obvious reason for its lack of use in energy demand is that the highly data dependent method requires having sufficient sample size at all levels of hierarchy to satisfy size and power conditions (other issues are (i) being less robust and (ii) being more specification sensitive; see, e.g., Gelman 2006; Ponce 2013).

The only panel industry aggregate/country electricity demand studies we know of are Cialani and Mortazavi (2018) and Csereklyei (2020), who considered nearly identical panels of European countries. Cialani and Mortazavi estimated a statistically significant long-run price elasticity for industrial electricity of − 0.2; however, they did not estimate an industry output elasticity (but rather, included economy-wide GDP in the regression, making that coefficient difficult to interpret in terms of industry electricity demand). Csereklyei estimated considerably higher price elasticities of between − 0.75 and − 1.0, depending on method,Footnote 7 and similarly, did not estimate an industry output elasticity (but rather, considered economy-wide GDP per capita).

While not a panel analysis, per se, Adeyemi and Hunt (2014) estimated industry energy consumption elasticities for 15 OECD countries individually. Their output elasticity estimates ranged from 0.3 to 0.96 with an average of 0.6. Rather than estimate a single price elasticity, Adeyemi and Hunt (2014) were interested in asymmetric price responses and uncovered substantial heterogeneity among the OECD countries in that regard.

Table 2 displays the results for the non-OECD industry studies we found (all single-country, and all but two focused on electricity). The countries analyzed skewed towards West and South Asia, with several countries examined more than once (and they considered only eight different countries in total). The estimated elasticities for both output and price varied considerably—from insignificant to small and significant to relatively large and significant (in absolute value)—and that variation occurred among the studies that examined the same country (and, sometimes, by the same authors), as well as for the table as a whole.

Thus, it appears we have very little understanding of the price and output elasticities for aggregate industry electricity/energy consumption for non-OECD countries and a limited appreciation for those elasticities for OECD countries; such understanding is particularly limited at an electricity panel level, with only two highly divergent panel industry price estimates for electricity demand and no panel industry output estimates for electricity demand.

3 Data

Both electricity price for industry (in 2015 US cents per kilowatt hour) and electricity final consumption for industry (in Mtoe) are from Enerdata’s Global Energy and CO2 database.Footnote 8 The price data begin in 1978. Energy price data—particularly for non-OECD countries—can be challenging to assemble (almost certainly a reason for the dearth of non-OECD analyses). The price series have been expanded/enhanced by using a real electricity price index from Pesaran et al. (1998) for Indonesia, India, and Taiwan, and by using a real electricity price index for industry from IEA for several IEA countries.

Real industry value added (in constant 2010 USD) was compiled from several sources (i.e., IEA, OECD, World Bank, and national statistical agencies). Observations for both electricity prices and value added are unbalanced. The unbalanced data span 1978–2016 and include 35 high-income (mostly OECD) countries and 30 middle-income (mostly non-OECD) countries; those countries and their data coverage are summarized in Appendix Table 7.

Table 3 reports summary statistics—displayed separately for the high-income and middle-income panels. The mean electricity price is actually slightly higher for the middle-income panel, but the spread of prices is much larger for that group than for the high-income countries. Calculating the average electricity intensity of each group—by dividing the mean of electricity consumption by the mean of value added—suggests that industry is about 13% more electricity intensive on average in the middle-income countries than in the high-income countries.

Table 3 Summary statistics for regression data, high-income and middle-income panels

Figures 2 and 3 display balanced (aggregate) data for high-income and middle-income countries covering the periods 1980–2016 and 1994–2014, respectively. Both figures illustrate that industrial electricity consumption has closely followed industrial value added for most of those periods—this is particularly so for middle-income countries (Fig. 3). However, for the high-income countries (Fig. 2), consumption and value added have moved in opposite directions since 2011.

Fig. 2
figure 2

Industry value added (VA) and electricity consumption (E) are shown (on the left and right y-axes, respectively) for a balanced panel of 27 high-income (mostly OECD) countries over 1980–2016

Fig. 3
figure 3

Industry value added (VA) and electricity consumption (E) are shown (on the left and right y-axes, respectively) for a balanced panel of 30 middle-income (mostly Non-OECD) countries over 1994–2014

High-income industrial electricity consumption grew from 178.4 Mtoe in 1980 to 234.9 Mtoe in 2016—a compounded annual growth rate of 0.8%, whereas industrial value added increased from 5.8 trillion 2010 USD in 1980 to 10.3 trillion 2010 USD in 2016—a compounded annual growth rate of 1.6%. These compounded annual growth rates were several times higher for middle-income countries—i.e., 4.4% for industrial electricity consumption and 3.2% for industrial value added over 1994–2014. Despite the large differences in compounded annual growth rates between the two sets of countries, total industrial electricity consumption and value added for middle-income countries was half or less than that compared to high-income countries in 2014.

While several manufacturing sectors are known to be energy intensive—pulp and paper, chemicals, non-metallic minerals (e.g., glass, cement), iron and steel, and non-ferrous metals (e.g., aluminum smelting)—only non-ferrous metals are also electricity intensive, i.e., electricity comprises over half of the sector’s energy consumption. For those other four sectors, electricity’s share of energy consumption is similar to industry’s overall share (at least for OECD countries). The share of industry electricity consumption for sectors that are non-energy intensive (e.g., transport equipment, machinery, wood products) ranges from 30–40% for OECD countries, but is considerably higher for middle-income countries at closer to 60%. However, in OECD countries, these non-energy-intensive sectors have become more electricity intensive since electricity’s share of energy consumption in these sectors has increased to over 40% for OECD North America and Europe and to 60% for OECD Asia-Oceana. So, the importance of electricity in industry is a combination of industry structure (i.e., energy-intensive sectors vs. non-energy-intensive sectors) and the extent of electrification in industry (i.e., electricity’s share of the energy mix in any particular sector).

Figure 4 shows the industry electricity prices for the 65 countries over 1978–2016 (in 2015 US cents/kWh). The figure illustrates the substantial disparity in yearly electricity prices for the individual countries (i.e., the empty circles). Indeed, any given year, countries can experience very different prices from the global average (the filled in circle). This yearly cross-country range is very large relative to the variation over time of the average price for all countries.

Fig. 4
figure 4

Industry electricity prices (in 2015 US cents/kWh) for 65 countries over 1978–2016. The average price for each year is displayed with solid fill

For the variables we consider, cross-sectional correlation/dependence is expected because of, for example, regional and macroeconomic linkages that manifest themselves through (i) global shocks (income/prices); (ii) institutional memberships like OECD and World Trade Organization; and (iii) technology transfer. The results of the Pesaran (2015) cross-sectional dependence (CD) test,Footnote 9 which employs the correlation coefficients between the time-series for each panel member, are shown in Table 4. For all three variables, the test rejected the null hypothesis of weak cross-sectional dependence at the highest level of significance. For each variable considered, the absolute value mean correlation coefficients ranged from 0.4 to 0.75 (see Table 4). The difference between the absolute value mean correlation coefficient and the mean correlation coefficient suggests that for prices, some of the correlations are negative (as well as positive), but output and electricity consumption tend to move in concert among the countries.

Table 4 Pesaran (2015) CD test and Correlation Coefficients, 65 Countries, unbalanced

Recently, Pesaran (2015) argued that when the number of cross-sections is large, the null hypothesis of independence is extreme, and a null of weak cross-sectional dependence is more appropriate. Furthermore, Pesaran argued that cross-sectional dependence is a concern when it is pervasive (across the panel members) and of the strong form (i.e., caused by common shocks or trends), but weak cross-sectional dependence does not pose serious issues. When the errors of panel regressions are strongly cross-sectionally correlated, standard estimation methods can produce both inconsistent parameter estimates and incorrect inferences (Baltagi and Pesaran 2007; Kapetanios et al. 2011; Pesaran 2015). Thus, because cross-sectional dependence can impart bias problems as well as inefficiency, only making adjustments to the standard errors (e.g., via Driscoll and Kraay 1998) may not be sufficient.

The variables analyzed are also trending and may be nonstationary—in other words, their mean and/or variance might change over time. The Pesaran (2007) panel unit root test for heterogeneous panels (CIPS), which allows for cross-sectional dependence to be caused by a single (unobserved) common factor,Footnote 10 suggests that the variables are likely nonstationary in levels, but stationary in first differences—see Table 5. When ordinary least squares (OLS) regressions are performed on time-series (or on time-series cross-sectional) variables that are not stationary, then measures like R-squared and t-statistics are unreliable, and there is a serious risk of the estimated relationships being spurious if the regression residuals are not stationary (Kao 1999; Beck 2008; Enders 2015).

Table 5 Pesaran (2007) CIPS Panel Unit Root Test Results, 65 Countries, unbalanced

Lags are added to unit root tests to correct for potential serial correlation. The version of the CIPS test that we run does not allow for heterogenous lag structure. So to frame the optimal numbers of lags, we first run a procedure that determines the number of lags for each panel member that minimizes either the AIC or BIC in a panel ADF regression. The panel average number of lags chosen ranged from 0.26 to 1.12; hence, for robustness we report results for (homogenous) panel lags of 0–2.

4 Model and methods

Following previous industry panel analyses (e.g., Adeyemi and Hunt 2007; Chang et al. 2019), we model industry electricity consumption as a function of energy price and industry output.Footnote 11 Adeyemi and Hunt (2007) noted that the single equation, log-linear functional form has become standard in energy demand modeling. Further, Pesaran et al. (1998) claimed that this approach typically outperforms more complex specifications. Further still, to incorporate the gradual adjustments imposed by new capital/technology gradually replacing older vintages, we consider a dynamic, adjustment model whereby the lag of the dependent variable (electricity consumption) is included on the right-hand-side along with industrial output/value added, energy price, and their one period lags (short-hand notation, ARDL (1, 1, 1)):

$$\ln E_{it} = \alpha_{i} + \gamma_{t} + \beta_{i}^{1} \ln {\text{VA}}_{it} + \beta_{i}^{2} \ln {\text{price}}_{it} + \beta_{i}^{3} \ln {\text{VA}}_{it - 1} + \beta_{i}^{4} \ln {\text{price}}_{it - 1} + \beta_{i}^{5} \ln E_{it - 1} + \varepsilon_{it}$$
(1)

where subscripts it denote the ith cross section and tth time period, E is total final electricity consumption for industry, VA is real value added for industry, and price is the real electricity price for industry, α is a cross-sectional specific constant, \(\gamma\) are common time effects, the βs are (potentially) cross-sectional specific coefficients to be estimated, and ε is the error term. So, the long-run value added and price elasticities, respectively, are:

$$\frac{{\beta^{1} + \beta^{3} }}{{\left( {1 - \beta^{5} } \right)}}\quad {\text{and}}\quad \frac{{\beta^{2} + \beta^{4} }}{{\left( {1 - \beta^{5} } \right)}}$$
(2)

Another popular model in the literature is the partial adjustment model—ARDL (1,0,0)—where only the dependent variable (electricity consumption) is lagged. In this case, the long-run elasticities would differ from Eq. (2) in that there would be no \({\beta }^{3}\) and \({\beta }^{4}\) terms.

We believe it is likely that the elasticities will not be the same for each country—i.e., there should be a substantial degree of heterogeneity. And if one mistakenly assumes that parameters are homogeneous (when the true coefficients of a dynamic panel in fact are heterogeneous), then all parameter estimates of the panel will be inconsistent (Pesaran and Smith 1995). Hence, we use a mean group estimator (MG) that first estimates cross-sectional specific regressions and then averages those estimated individual-country coefficients to arrive at panel coefficients (standard errors are constructed nonparametrically as described in Pesaran and Smith 1995).

When using MG methods, there are two ways to calculate panel long-run parameters from a dynamic model.Footnote 12 First, one applies to Eq. (2) the panel short-run estimates (which themselves are the average of the individual country short-run coefficients). Such an approach is referred to as the long-run average (LRA) and is the most common approach in the literature (standard errors are then computed via the Delta method). The second approach first computes the long-run coefficient for each country (again applying Eq. 2) and then computes the average (of country-long-run coefficients) to arrive at the panel coefficient. This average long-run (ALR) method is closer to the spirit of MG estimations since the panel long-run coefficient is directly based on the average of the individual country long-run coefficients.

In addition to the individual country elasticities being different, there are several reasons why the panel average elasticities for high- and middle-income countries may differ (although given data constraints, e.g., a lack of information on capital stock vintages, it is beyond the scope of the present paper to definitively assess which reason may govern). For example, price elasticities might differ because middle-income countries are more likely to subsidize electricity. Output elasticities could differ because technology differs. And the technology argument could work in either direction: high-income countries could have access to better/more efficient technology, or middle-income countries could have newer capital stocks that are embodied with more technological advances. Additionally, output elasticities could differ if industry structure differs—for example, if industry in middle-income countries is skewed more toward the electricity intensive sectors (like smelting and iron and steel). This last argument follows from the Chang et al. (2019) finding that energy-intensive sectors had higher output elasticities than non-energy-intensive sectors in OECD countries.

The Pesaran (2006) Common Correlated Effects mean group (CCE) estimator accounts for the presence of unobserved common factors by including in the regression cross-sectional averages of the dependent and independent variables, and it is robust to nonstationarity, cointegration, breaks, and serial correlation. The CCE estimator is not consistent in dynamic panels, however, since the lagged dependent variable is no longer strictly exogenous. Chudik and Pesaran (2015) demonstrated that the estimator becomes consistent again when additional ∛T lags (in our case, 2, for series with at least 19 years) of the cross-sectional means are included. Hence, we employ the Dynamic Common Correlated Effects (DCCE) estimator of Chudik and Pesaran (2015).Footnote 13 The combination of independent variables, their lags, cross-sectional average terms, and two additional lags of those cross-sectional average terms, means each cross section must have at least 18 observations for the ARDL(1, 1, 1) model; fewer observations are required for the partial adjustment or ARDL(1,0,0) model.Footnote 14

The DCCE estimator applied to the ARDL (1, 1, 1) model, looks like:

$$\ln E_{it} = \alpha_{i} + \beta_{i}^{1} \ln {\text{VA}}_{it} + \beta_{i}^{2} \ln {\text{price}}_{it} + \beta_{i}^{3} \ln {\text{VA}}_{it - 1} + \beta_{i}^{4} \ln {\text{price}}_{it - 1} + \beta_{i}^{5} \ln E_{it - 1} + Z_{it} + \varepsilon_{it}$$
(3)

where Z represents the cross-sectional average terms. The cross-sectional average terms from Eq. (3) are displayed in Eq. (4) below:

$$Z_{i,t} = \mathop \sum \limits_{l = 0}^{2} \rho_{i}^{l} \overline{{E_{t - l} }} + \mathop \sum \limits_{l = 0}^{2} \rho_{i}^{l} \overline{{{\text{VA}}_{t - l} }} + \mathop \sum \limits_{l = 0}^{2} \rho_{i}^{l} \overline{{{\text{price}}_{t - l} }}$$
(4)

where the bar represents an average over the cross-sections (countries), and l stands for the number of lags.

Dynamic models estimated with panel data are subject to a downward bias, called the dynamic panel or Nickell bias. In the literature this bias is often addressed using the general methods of moments (GMM) estimator (e.g., Cialani and Mortazavi 2018), but GMM was designed for short T panels, and thus, does not necessarily handle nonstationarity. Moreover, since the instrument count increases rapidly with time observations, Roodman (2009) warns that the risk of over-parameterization for GMM is great when T exceeds 10. In addition, GMM was not intended to manage heterogeneity and cross-sectional dependence. Since downward bias is on the order of 1/T (Nickell 1981), having several time observations can mitigate such bias. Bruno (2005) determined that in unbalanced panels (like ours), the bias declines with average group (cross-section) size (i.e., the bias is not determined entirely by the shortest series). While the shortest cross section has 19 years of data, 59 countries have at least 22 observations, and our average cross-section size is over 30.Footnote 15 (Again, panel coverage is displayed in Appendix Table 7.)

Energy efficiency improvements do affect energy demand. Indeed, there is a separate literature that aims to model the price-induced and autonomous improvements of the energy efficiency of capital stock (e.g., Sue Wing 2008; Steinbuks and Neuhoff 2014). However, this literature employs substantially different models, methods, and data than the present paper. Some reduced-form demand analyses have included time trends (deterministic or stochastic) to account for this autonomous increase in energy efficiency (e.g., Adeyemi and Hunt 2007; Dilaver and Hunt 2011). The cross-sectional average terms (included in CEE-type estimations) of variables like electricity consumption and output might provide some accounting for energy efficiency improvements (likely better than deterministic time trends do); such terms also might address several of the concerns raised in (i) Adeyemi and Hunt (e.g., modeling heterogeneous responses to socioeconomic and structural conditions) and (ii) Dilaver and Hunt (e.g., avoiding biased income/output elasticity estimations by not accounting for downward sloping efficiency improvements).

Lastly, in addition to being aggregated over time, the price variable we use only approximates the (sometimes highly) nonlinear electricity tariff schedules that consumers actually face. Ideally, one would want to estimate price elasticities at the marginal tariff, but such data is rarely available. Furthermore, although electricity tariffs are often set exogenously by regulators, some analysts are concerned that price in many aggregate studies is endogenous because price is constructed as average revenue equal to total revenues divided by consumption, which is the dependent variable. Yet, recent evidence suggests that for macro-models, demand elasticity estimates vary little depending on whether an instrument for price was used (Burke and Abayasekara 2018; Csereklyei 2020). However, a related endogeneity issue could occur at the individual sector/firm level since some large industries/firms negotiate prices directly with regulators. Steinbuks and Neuhoff (2014) argued that this potential endogeneity is mitigated when one uses prices that are aggregated at the entire industry/manufacturing sector level (as we do).

5 Results and discussion

Table 6 displays the elasticity estimation results. For all the regressions, the residuals are stationary. While those unit root test results for the residuals suggest cointegration, the critical values for panel cointegration tests are stricter than those for panel unit root tests. However, the corresponding statistics from the CIPS tests reported in Table 6 easily exceed the critical values calculated by Banerjee and Carrion-I-Silvestre (2017), who designed a second-generation panel cointegration test that is based on CCE.

Table 6 Industry electricity output and price elasticities. High-income vs Middle-income panels

In addition, we considered two heterogenous, residual-based first-generation cointegration tests (Pedroni 2004; Westerlund 2005) in which we first subtract the cross-sectional averages from each series (a procedure Levin et al. 2002 recommended to mitigate cross-sectional dependence). The main difference between the Pedroni (2004) and the Westerlund (2005) cointegration tests is that the alternative hypothesis of Pedroni is that all cross-sections are cointegrated, whereas the alternative for the Westerlund test is that some of the cross-sections are cointegrated (the null hypothesis for both tests is no cointegration). The results of both tests (shown in Appendix Table 8) strongly reject the null of no cointegration.

Considering the CD tests, weak cross-sectional dependence cannot be rejected (at least at standard levels) for the high-income panel (Regression II). Adding the cross-sectional average terms does substantially reduce the CD test static (comparing Regressions I and II). Hence, Regression II would be preferred for the high-income panel, while the test statistic is still marginally significant in Regression II, it can be difficult to completely remove evidence of strong cross-sectional dependence in OECD panels (see, e.g., Eberhardt and Presbitero 2015; Liddle and Huntington 2020). For the middle-income panel and the ARDL (1, 1, 1) model, the CD test statistic is similar (in magnitude) for both the MG and DCCE regressions (albeit, marginally significant for Regression IV). For the middle-income panel, a partial adjustment or ARDL (1,0,0) model was runFootnote 16 since contemporaneous price was highly insignificant in the ARDL (1, 1, 1) model. For the ARDL (1,0,0) model, DCCE (Regression VI) is clearly superior to MG since the CD test implies that strong cross-sectional dependence has been completely removed, whereas for the CD test on Regression V, weak dependence is rejected at the highest level of significance. Yet, for each of the regressions (I–VI) the long-run coefficients for output and price (both the average long-run and long-run average versions) are mostly similar.

The long-run output elasticity for high-income countries is around 0.5, and is statistically significant (Regression II). In case of the average long-run, the estimate is substantially significantly less than unity. Both long-run output elasticity estimates (long-run average and average long-run) are quite similar to the earliest OECD panel estimate in which industry energy consumption was the dependent variable—Adeyemi and Hunt (2007). The long-run price elasticities (long-run average and average long-run) for the high-income panel are around − 0.25. These elasticities, both statistically significant, are similar to those of Adeyemi and Hunt and to the European panel estimate of Cialani and Mortazavi (2018), who also focused on electricity demand (and did report their long-run price estimate as being statistically significant).

For the middle-income panel, most of the long-run output estimates are greater than one, and for all cases, unity is well within the 95% confidence intervals. All of the long-run price elasticity estimates for the middle-income panel are small and insignificant. Considering individual country long-run price elasticities, only about one-half of the middle-income countries had negative elasticities, and only about one-third of those were likely statistically significant. Several middle-income countries subsidize electricity, which would be expected to mute price responses. Indeed, according to the IEA fossil fuel subsidies database (which has data from 2010–2018), 12 countries in our middle-income panel have subsidized/do subsidize electricity.Footnote 17 So, the insignificant middle-income panel long-run price elasticity probably results from a combination of the temporal and sectorial data aggregation and subsidized energy prices. Liddle and Huntington (2020), who focused on economy-wide energy consumption and prices, similarly calculated insignificant price elasticities for non-OECD/middle-income panels (and long-run price elasticities between − 0.2 and − 0.3 for an OECD/high-income panel).

Comparing the average long-run (ALR) output elasticities for the high-income and middle-income panels, it appears that the middle-income elasticity is statistically significantly larger than the high-income elasticity since none of their confidence intervals overlap. If the middle-income countries have industry structures skewed more towards electricity-intensive sectors than the high-income countries, this finding of a larger output elasticity for middle-income countries would be in line with the recent evidence from Chang et al. (2019), who found a similar difference in energy output elasticities between energy-intensive sectors and non- energy-intensive industry sectors based on OECD panels. Again, on average, it appears that industry is somewhat more electricity intensive in middle-income countries. Also, Figs. 2 and 3 suggest that industry output and electricity consumption were much more aligned in middle-income countries.

To further investigate industry structure’s role in explaining the significantly larger output elasticity for middle-income as compared to high-income countries, we create Fig. 5. Figure 5 shows a plot of the individual country (for all 65 countries) long-run value added elasticity estimates (from Regressions II and IV) by the average (1978–2014) share of manufacturing value added contributed by the four most energy-intensive sectors. Those sectors, listed with their ISIC Revision 3.1 codes in parentheses, are: chemicals and chemical products (24); non-metallic mineral products (26); and basic metals (27), which includes both iron and steel and non-ferrous metals.Footnote 18 The figure does indicate a positive relationship between the output/value added elasticity and an energy-intensive manufacturing structure (the R-squared for a linear trend line is 0.2).

Fig. 5
figure 5

Individual country long-run value added (VA) elasticity estimates (y-axis) are plotted against the average share of manufacturing value added from the four most energy intensive sectors (x-axis) for the full, 65-country panel (and ARDL (1, 1, 1) model). Value added data is from UNIDO. Trend line, equation, and R-squared also displayed

Figure 5 provides some visual evidence that suggests parameter/slope heterogeneity for the output elasticity. Yet, that figure does not indicate whether those elasticities are statistically significantly different from one another. So, to conclude the analysis, we consider several statistical tests of heterogeneity.

First, we determine the number of countries (from each income-based panel) whose long-run (output and price) elasticities are statistically different from the corresponding panel average long-run coefficient (reported in Table 6) at the 10% level. (For simplicity/consistency we use the ARDL (1, 1, 1) model for both the high-income and middle-income country panels, i.e., Regressions II and IV.) For the 35 high-income countries, 17 had output elasticities that were statistically significantly different (at 10%) from the panel average long-run output coefficient, and seven had statistically significantly different price elasticities. For the 30 middle-income countries, those two counts were 11 and six for output and price elasticities, respectively. If the true individual coefficients were the same as the panel average, one would expect statistically different results because of random error for 3.5 and three countries (from the high-income and middle-income panels, respectively). According to the binomial distribution, producing twice as many statistically different coefficients as expected (as is the case for the price elasticity) has only a 5% chance of occurring randomly (finding 10 out of 35 or nine out of 30 would have a 0.1% chance).

Next, we calculate Wald statistics, as suggested by Canning and Pedroni (2008):

$$W_{\theta } = \mathop \sum \limits_{i} \frac{{\left( {{\theta_{i}}^{\prime} - \overline{\theta }} \right)^{2} }}{{{\text{Var}}\left( {\theta_{i} } \right)}}$$
(5)

where \({\mathop{\theta}^{\prime}}_{i}\) is the country-specific parameter estimate, \(\mathrm{Var}\left({\theta }_{i}\right)\) is the variance of the country-specific parameter estimates, and \(\stackrel{-}{\theta }\) is the (unweighted) average of the country-specific estimates. (Again, we use the ARDL (1, 1, 1) model, i.e., Regressions II and IV.) This statistic is distributed as Chi-squared under the null that all countries have the same parameter value with degrees of freedom of N (in our case 65). For both output and price elasticities, these statistics (1035 and 178, respectively) strongly reject homogenous parameter values.

Finally, we consider a test based on Pesaran and Yamagata (2008) that compares the difference between coefficients obtained by a pooled, fixed effects regression and by a mean-group regression (while adjusting each ARDL (1, 1, 1) regression by adding cross-sectional average terms).Footnote 19 That test (based on the entire 65-country sample) rejects model slope homogeneity at the 0.001 level (delta statistic was 30.5). Separate tests for the high-income and middle-income panels (i.e., Regressions II and VI) also rejected slope homogeneity at the highest level (corresponding adjusted delta statistics were 13.9 and 8.6, respectively).

Hence, it appears that we were correct in assuming/allowing for heterogeneity. Yet, we note that if the true elasticities were the same for all countries, both the mean-group and pooled/fixed effects estimators would be unbiased and consistent, but fixed effects would be more efficient. However, given the presence of nonstationary and cross-sectionally correlated regressors, one might still prefer a mean-group estimator since CCE-MG has been shown to outperform the pooled/fixed effects version (CCEP) in applications in those areas (see, e.g., Eberhardt and Presbitero 2015; Eberhardt and Teal 2020; Liddle and Huntington 2020).

5.1 Some policy implications and further discussion

The output elasticity of around 0.5 for high-income countries suggests that industry has partially decoupled from electricity consumption—i.e., value added can grow at twice the rate of electricity consumption. However, for industry in middle-income countries, value added/output and electricity consumption grow in concert. This finding—particularly with respect to the industrializing, middle-income countries—coupled with the relatively low price elasticities (for both high- and middle-income countries) emphasize the importance of policies that aim to decarbonize electricity (e.g., feed-in tariffs, minimum standards for generation share from renewables) as opposed to policies that are more focused on lowering consumption (e.g., taxes). In other words, a carbon tax, if passed on to end-use customers, may have a limited impact on reducing electricity demand (and thus, lowering emissions).

The relatively large output elasticity for middle-income countries suggests that supply-side authorities/planners need to consider an expansion of the power generation sector. One possible explanation for the different sizes of the output elasticities is that electricity use is more efficient in high-income countries. This explanation opens the possibility for planners in middle-income countries to lower electricity industry demand (and thus avoid electricity generation expansion) via technology transfer (from high-income countries). However, efficiency is an unlikely explanation for two reasons. First, the middle-income countries have electrified more recently, and thus, on average, may have better/more recent vintage technology (of course, subsidizing electricity could lead to inefficient use despite state-of-the-art technology). There is evidence that the current economy-wide, energy elasticities of GDP are similar for high- and middle-income countries (e.g., Liddle and Huntington 2020), and that the current such elasticity for middle-income countries is indeed lower than such elasticity for high-income countries was in the 1960s–1970s (Liddle and Huntington 2021a). Second, as we imply in Fig. 5, the higher output elasticity in middle-income countries could be the result of having more energy/electricity-intensive industry structure. Again, Chang et al. (2019) came to a similar conclusion regarding OECD countries and differences between the output elasticity for energy-intensive sectors vs. non-energy-intensive sectors. So, middle-income countries could restructure their industry sectors to be less energy intensive, and thus reduce industry electricity demand (or reduce the need to expand their generation sectors). Of course, unless global demand for electricity intensive products (e.g., aluminum, copper) is reduced, energy/electricity intensive industry would have to locate somewhere.

Two previous electricity demand studies that focused on Europe also considered residential electricity demand. Cialani and Mortazavi (2018) found that residential customers were slightly (but probably not significantly) more sensitive to prices than industry customers (long-run price elasticities of − 0.3 compared to − 0.2, respectively). Whereas, Csereklyei (2020) determined the opposite—industry customers were more sensitive to prices than residential customers (with the long-run residential price elasticity being around − 0.5 or half to a third less than industry). If we compare our industry results to the residential electricity demand results of Liddle and Huntington (2021b), for high income countries the price elasticity is nearly the same for industry customers (− 0.25) and residential customers (Liddle and Huntington estimated a price elasticity of − 0.22 for residential). However, for middle-income countries, residential customers may be more price sensitive than industry customers—Liddle and Huntington (2021b) estimated a significant but small (less than − 0.1 in absolute terms) long-run residential price elasticity.

6 Summary and final conclusions

There have been relatively few panel estimations of aggregate OECD industry energy demand (although there have been several single OECD country studies). We believe ours is the first such study to (i) employ methods that address heterogeneity and cross-sectional dependence; and (ii) focus on industry electricity demand and estimate both price and output elasticities (i.e., we consider industry output rather than a function of economy-wide output, which can introduce miss-aggregation/alignment bias). Our output and price elasticity estimates of around 0.5 and − 0.25, respectively, are most similar to the earliest OECD panel study Adeyemi and Hunt (2007). However, given that Adeyemi and Hunt focused on energy rather than electricity demand, considered a substantially smaller sample (15 OECD vs 35 high-income countries), and a much different time span (adding years 1962–1977 but not including years 2004–2016), there was no a priori reason to expect our estimates would be similar. Our results also are similar to the Chang et al. (2019) estimates for less energy-intensive sectors, but are quite different from their full/all sectors results (Chang et al. considered energy rather than electricity, too).

Much less is known regarding aggregate non-OECD industry energy/electricity demand. We believe ours is the first study to perform panel elasticity estimations of such demand and among the first to consider/analyze non-OECD countries from outside South and West Asia. Indeed, an important advancement in our estimates is the incorporation of time-series data on industry electricity prices for 28 countries outside the IEA/OECD.Footnote 20 When combined with the more widely available OECD prices, this information allows a more reliable estimate of demand by providing an important control variable that separates high-price from low-price periods/countries. For middle-income/non-OECD countries our output elasticity estimations were near unity and likely statistically significantly larger than the output elasticity estimations for high-income/OECD countries.

Our price elasticity for middle-income countries was highly insignificant. Rather than suggesting that industries in middle-income countries are totally unresponsive to price, we believe this finding probably reflects the several high levels of aggregation in our analysis. Electricity price data has been aggregated over time and across both industry sectors and geographic regions; such aggregation likely dampened the estimated price response for both middle-income and high-income panels. Moreover, several middle-income countries in our panel subsidized electricity, which would likewise dampen the price response of electricity consumption. Since this level of aggregation was necessary for data compilation, we reserve a more disaggregated analysis of industry electricity demand across countries for future work.

Finally, we performed several pre- and post-estimation tests (e.g., for unit roots, cross-sectional dependence, cointegration, and heterogeneity). Analysts considering similar variables and models might save time by not replicating all of those tests and instead assuming that nonstationarity, cross-sectional dependence, and heterogeneity are issues worth addressing. Also, our preferred estimation method for addressing those issues—DCCE—is OLS-based; thus, it is no (or not much) more computationally complex than fixed effects, and is substantially simpler/more transparent than other previously employed approaches, such as System-GMM, Structural Time Series Modeling, or Dynamic Multilevel Modeling (which, additionally, may not fully address those three issues).