Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

How much should we trust regression-kink-design estimates?

  • Published:
Empirical Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

An Erratum to this article was published on 12 January 2017

This article has been updated

Abstract

In a regression kink (RK) design with a finite sample, a confounding smooth nonlinear relationship between an assignment variable and an outcome variable around a threshold can be spuriously picked up as a kink and results in a biased estimate. In order to investigate how well RK designs handle such confounding nonlinearity, I firstly implement Monte Carlo (MC) simulations and then study the effect of fiscal equalization grants on local expenditure in Japan using an RK design. Results in both the MC simulations and the empirical application suggest that RK estimation without covariates can be easily biased, and this problem can be mitigated by adding observed covariates to the regressors. On the other hand, a smaller bandwidth or a higher-order polynomial, even a quadratic polynomial, tends to result in imprecise estimates although they may be able to reduce estimation bias. In sum, RK estimation with confounding nonlinearity often suffers from bias or imprecision, and estimates are credible only when relevant covariates are controlled for. I also examine how placebo RK estimation can effectively address these issues.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4
Fig. 5
Fig. 6
Fig. 7
Fig. 8

Similar content being viewed by others

Change history

  • 12 January 2017

    An erratum to this article has been published.

Notes

  1. See, among others, Hausman (1985) and Moffitt (1986, (1990) for econometrics issues concerning nonlinear budget sets. Studies of nonlinear budget sets have mostly appeared in the labor-supply literature, but Moffitt (1984), for example, applies these techniques to the study of the effects of federal grants on state and local expenditures.

  2. A closely related but distinctly different study is Dong (2014), which applies an RD design with a binary treatment to a situation in which the treatment probability is not jumped but kinked. A key difference between an RK design and Dong (2014)’s RD design is that treatment is continuous in the former and binary in the latter.

  3. In order to cancel out or reduce estimation bias caused by a quadratic relation which is spuriously picked up as a kink, Landais (2015) proposes a double-difference RK design which exploits the shifting of kink positions over time. Note that Landais (2015) mentions that the double-difference RK design is much more demanding in terms of the precision of estimates than his baseline RD design. In a difference-in-difference framework, Chetty et al. (2014) utilize a change in the slope of pension contributions with respect to income over time that arises at a certain income threshold. These approaches may be able to deal with confounding nonlinearity that is time-invariant, but I do not discuss them in this paper in which my focus is on RK designs with cross-sectional or pooled data.

  4. See also Card et al. (2015) for the application of CCT’s procedures to an RK design.

  5. As for RK studies, Engström et al. (2015) use placebo RK estimation as a robustness check. Ando (2015) also uses similar placebo estimation, exploiting the same kinked variation in a grant formula as in this paper.

  6. See also Card et al. (2015) for a theoretical discussion of generalized RK estimation based on a nonseparable model with a heterogeneous treatment effect. Card et al. (2015) show that an RK estimand can be interpreted as the same “local average response” parameter of Altonji and Matzkin (2005) or equivalently “treatment on the treated” parameter of Florens et al. (2008) if certain conditions are satisfied. Because the objective of this paper is to investigate the performance of an RK design in the presence of a confounding nonlinearity around a cutoff point, I exclusively rely on constant-effect and additive models in the following discussion and MC simulations.

  7. Based on a more general nonparametric kernel regression framework, Card et al. (2012) show that the bias and variance of a constrained RK estimator (i.e., imposing continuity at a cutoff) have the same asymptotic properties as those of an unconstrained RK estimator when the kernel is symmetric.

  8. Card et al. (2012) argue that, unlike in the case of the kind of local polynomial regression for an interior point discussed by Fan and Gijbels (1996), there is a substantial cost in variance incurred by using a local quadratic model instead of a local linear model in RK designs. In addition, Gelman and Imbens (2014) argue that high-order polynomials should not be used for RD estimation because of several unfavorable properties of high-order polynomials, which are also applicable to RK estimation. Although Card et al. (2014) argue that the local linear estimator should not always dominate other higher-order local polynomial estimators in RD and RK designs, my applications of an RK design to both simulated data and real-world data in this study show that high-order local polynomial regressions often result in very imprecise estimation. In another study with an RK design, Simonsen et al. (2016) also adopt only a local linear polynomial in their baseline analysis for the same reason.

  9. See Boadway and Shah (2007) for extensive studies on fiscal equalization programs.

  10. There is an increasing number of studies which explicitly consider the endogeneity problem in grant effects. See, among others, Holtz-Eakin (1986), Knight (2002), Gordon (2004), Dahlberg et al. (2008), Feyrer and Sacerdote (2011), Bravo (2011), Chodorow-Reich et al. (2012), Wilson (2012), Conley and Dupor (2013), Litschig and Morrison (2013), Lundqvist et al. (2014), Suárez and Wingender (2016), and Lundqvist (2015).

  11. The introduction of \(X^2\) and \(U^2\) in Eq. (10) is a rather arbitrary setting for generating the confounding nonlinearity between V and EXP in my DGP. The nonlinear relationship of X and U to some fiscal variables is plausible, given the fact that observed and unobserved socioeconomic factors affect the fiscal variables of local governments through various channels. The introduction of \(\mathrm{CAP}^2\) is also arbitrarily set in order to increase the confounding nonlinearity in my DGP. This may be justified if I can assume that local governments increase their revenue and expenditure (EXP) as much as possible by broadening tax bases, increasing tax rates, or employing some other method when their revenue capacity (CAP) increases.

  12. The confusing name “Local Allocation Tax” comes from the fact that the total amount of the grants is, in principle, a given proportion of revenues from five national taxes.

  13. According to the legal framework in which they are described, the total amount of the LAT grants is stipulated to be a fraction of the revenues from five major national taxes. In reality, however, the total amount is also influenced by other socioeconomic and political factors.

  14. See Appendix “2” and “3” for more detailed definitions and institutional descriptions of NEED (or Standard Fiscal Need) and CAP (or Standard Fiscal Revenue).

  15. Because most municipalities adopted similar tax rates and similar tax bases during the sample period (MIC 2012), a marginal increase in grants should have mainly led to a marginal increase in local expenditure. At the same time, a greater than one-to-one effect may be possible because some local public services are partly financed by earmarked matching grants: One-unit increase in LAT grants can lead to one-unit direct increase in local expenditure and some additional increase in local expenditure by induced matching grants. See MIC (2003) on the trends in local expenditures in 1990s. MIC (2003) shows that administration, welfare, construction, and education were major expenditure items, and welfare and debt payments grew fastest during the period. Ando (2015) investigates the effects of LAT grants on disaggregated expenditures, although the data used are restricted to fiscal years 2003–2004 because of a different research design.

  16. Japanese municipalities consist of cities (shi), towns (cho), villages (son), and special districts in Tokyo (ku). Because the duties of municipalities differ depending on their type, the levels of expenditure per capita are also affected by the type of municipality in question. I therefore use only city (shi) data, excluding other types of municipalities.

  17. The revenue capacity variable is similar to CAP (or Standard Fiscal Revenue), but some modifications have been made in order to reflect real revenue capacity of municipalities. See Appendix “Description of fiscal variables” for further details.

  18. In addition, for linear RK estimation, placebo estimates are still significantly different from zero when placebo cutoffs are around \(\pm 1\). This, however, is presumably not due to confounding nonlinearity around these points. Rather, the placebo estimates with a linear RK model capture the nonlinearity caused by the true kink when the true cutoff is inside the bandwidth.

  19. See also Appendix “stylized description of Japanese fiscal equalization,” where I describe the stylized features of the Japanese fiscal equalization grants with some equations and graphs.

References

  • Altonji JG, Matzkin RL (2005) Cross section and panel data estimators for nonseparable models with endogenous regressors. Econometrica 73(4):1053–1102

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ando M (2013) How much should we trust regression-kink-design estimates? Department of Economics, working paper, Uppsala University, vol 2013, pp 22

  • Ando M (2015) Heterogeneous effects of fiscal equalization grants on local expenditures: evidence from two formula-based variations. IPSS working paper series (E), no. 25

  • Boadway R, Shah A (2007) Intergovernmental fiscal transfers: principle and practice. The World Bank, Washington

    Google Scholar 

  • Bravo J (2011) The Effects of intergovernmental grants on local revenue: evidence from Chile. UC Economics Institute working paper, vol 393

  • Calonico S, Cattaneo MD, Titiunik R (2014a) Robust data-driven inference in the regression-discontinuity design. Stata J 14(4):909–946

    Google Scholar 

  • Calonico S, Cattaneo MD, Titiunik R (2014b) Robust nonparametric confidence intervals for regression-discontinuity designs. Econometrica 82(6):2295–2326

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Calonico S, Cattaneo MD, Titiunik R (2015) Optimal data-driven regression discontinuity plots. J Am Stat Assoc 110(512):1753–1769

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Card D, Lee D, Pei Z (2009) Quasi-experimental identification and estimation in the regression kink design. Princeton University Industrial Relations Section working paper, no. 553

  • Card D, Lee D, Pei Z, Weber A (2012) Nonlinear policy rules and the identification and estimation of causal effects in a generalized regression kink design. NBER working paper series, no. 18564

  • Card D, Lee DS, Pei Z, Weber A (2015) Inference on causal effects in a generalized regression kink design. Econometrica 83(6):2453–2483

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Card D, Pei Z, Lee DS, Weber A (2014) Local polynomial order in regression discontinuity designs. Working paper

  • Chetty R, Friedman JN, Leth-Petersen S, Nielsen T, Olsen t (2014) Active vs. passive decisions and crowd-out in retirement savings accounts: evidence from Denmark Q J Econ 129(3):1141–1219

  • Chodorow-Reich G, Feiveson L, Liscow Z, Woolston WG (2012) Does state fiscal relief during recessions increase employment? Evidence from the American Recovery and Reinvestment Act. Am Econ J Econ Policy 4(3):118–145

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Conley TG, Dupor B (2013) The American Recovery and Reinvestment Act: Solely a government jobs program? J Monet Econ 60(5):535–549

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dafflon B (2007) Fiscal capacity equalization in horizontal fiscal equalization programs. In: Intergovernmental fiscal transfers. The World Bank, pp 361–396

  • Dahlberg M, Mörk E, Rattsø J, Ågren H (2008) Using a discontinuous grant rule to identify the effect of grants on local taxes and spending. J Public Econ 92(12):2320–2335

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dong Y (2014) Jump or kink? Identification of binary treatment regression discontinuity design without the discontinuity. Working paper

  • Ek S (2013) Gaining from local benefits? Unemployment insurance and job quality. In: Essays on unemployment insurance design. Doctoral thesis, Uppsala University

  • Engström P, Nordblom K, Ohlsson H, Persson A (2015) Tax compliance and loss aversion. Am Econ J Econ Policy 7(4):132–164

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fan J, Gijbels I (1996) Local polynomial modelling and its applications. Chapman and Hall, London

    Google Scholar 

  • Feyrer J, Sacerdote B (2011) Did the stimulus stimulate? Real time estimates of the effects of the American Recovery and Reinvestment Act. NBER working paper series, no. 16759

  • Florens J-P, Heckman JJ, Meghir C, Vytlacil EJ (2008) Identification of treatment effects using control functions in models with continuous, endogenous treatment and heterogeneous effects. Econometrica 76(5):1191–1206

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ganong P, Jäger S (2015) A permutation test for the regression kink design. Working paper

  • Gelman A, Imbens G (2014) Why high-order polynomials should not be used in regression discontinuity designs. NBER working paper series, no. 20405

  • Gordon N (2004) Do federal grants boost school spending? Evidence from Title I. J Public Econ 88(9–10):1771–1792

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Guryan J (2001) Does money matter? Regression-discontinuity estimates from education finance reform in Massachusetts. NBER working paper series, no. 8269

  • Hausman JA (1985) The econometrics of nonlinear budget sets. Econometrica 53(6):1255–1282

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hayashi M (2000) Distortionary effects of seemingly lump-sum intergovernmental transfers in Japan: a note. Meiji Gakuin Rev Pap Proc Econ 118:63–71

    Google Scholar 

  • Hayashi M (2006) Chihokohuzei no Keizai Bunseki Genjo to Kadai (The economics studies of the local allocation tax in Japan: a critical survey). J Econ Policy Stud 3(2):6–24 (in Japanese)

    Google Scholar 

  • Holtz-Eakin D (1986) Unobserved tastes and the determination of municipal services. Natl Tax J 39(4):527–533

    Google Scholar 

  • Imbens G, Kalyanaraman K (2012) Optimal bandwidth choice for the regression discontinuity estimator. Rev Econ Stud 79:933–959

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Knight B (2002) Endogenous federal grants and crowd-out of state government spending: theory and evidence from the federal highway aid program. Am Econ Rev 92(1):71–92

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Landais C (2015) Assessing the welfare effects of unemployment benefits using the regression kink design. Am Econ J Econ Policy 7(4):243–278

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lee DS, Lemieux T (2010) Regression discontinuity designs in economics. J Econ Lit 48:281–355

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Litschig S, Morrison KM (2013) The impact of intergovernmental transfers on education outcomes and poverty reduction. Am Econ J Appl Econ 5(4):206–240

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lundqvist H (2015) Granting public or private consumption? Effects of grants on local public spending and income taxes. Int Tax Public Financ 22:41–72

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lundqvist H, Dahlberg M, Mörk E (2014) Stimulating local public employment: do general grants work? Am Econ J Econ Policy 6(1):167–192

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • McCrary J (2008) Manipulation of the running variable in the regression discontinuity design: a density test. J Econom 142(2):698–714

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • MIC (2003) White paper on local public finance, 2003 illustrated. Ministry of internal affairs and communications (MIC). http://www.soumu.go.jp/menu_seisaku/hakusyo/pdf/chihou/2003e_c_visual.pdf. Accessed 13 Dec 2015

  • MIC (2012) Zeiritsu ni Tsuite no Kazei Jishuken no Kakudai ni Tsuite (On the expansion of tax autonomy for local tax rates). Ministry of internal affairs and communications (MIC). http://www.soumu.go.jp/main_content/000174389.pdf. Accessed 13 Dec 2015 (in Japanese)

  • Moffitt R (1984) The effects of grants-in-aid on state and local expenditures: the case of AFDC. J Public Econ 23(3):279–305

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Moffitt R (1986) The econometrics of piecewise-linear budget constraints: a survey and exposition of the maximum likelihood method. J Bus Econ Stat 4(3):317–328

    Google Scholar 

  • Moffitt R (1990) The econometrics of kinked budget constraints. J Econ Perspect 4(2):119–139

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nielsen HS, Sørensen T, Taber C (2010) Estimating the effect of student aid on college enrollment: evidence from a government grant policy reform. Am Econ J Econ Policy 2(2):185–215

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Saez E (2010) Do taxpayers bunch at kink points? Am Econ J Econ Policy 2(3):180–212

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Simonsen M, Skipper L, Skipper N (2016) Price sensitivity of demand for prescription drugs: exploiting a regression kink design. J Appl Econom 31:320–337

  • Serrato JCS, Wingender P (2016) Estimating local fiscal multipliers. NBER working paper series, no. 22425

  • Turner LJ (2014) The road to pell is paved with good intentions: the economic incidence of federal student grant aid. Working paper

  • Wilson DJ (2012) Fiscal spending jobs multipliers: evidence from the 2009 American Recovery and Reinvestment Act. Am Econ J Econ Policy 4(3):251–282

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Michihito Ando.

Additional information

I am grateful to Matz Dahlberg for his comments and advice. I thank Jun Saito for sharing his municipal political economy data sets. I also would like to thank the editor, two anonymous referees, Jon Fiva, Masayoshi Hayashi, David Neumark, Reo Takaku and seminar participants at Uppsala, Stockholm, Taormina, and Gothenburg for their very helpful comments and suggestions. All mistakes are my own.

An erratum to this article is available at https://doi.org/10.1007/s00181-016-1227-9.

Appendices

Appendix 1: MC simulation results for OLS estimation

See Table 5.

Table 5 MC Simulation results for OLS estimation

Appendix 2: Description of fiscal variables

1.1 Expenditure need: NEED

This index measures the cost of a “standard” level of local public services for a municipality. It is officially referred to as “Standard Fiscal Need” (Kijun Zaisei Juyo Gaku) and calculated annually by the Ministry of Internal Affairs and Communications. Standard Fiscal Need is calculated as follows:

$$\begin{aligned} {\mathrm{NEED}}_i = \Sigma _{k}({\textit{Unit}}\,{\textit{Cost}}_k \times {\textit{Measurement}}\,{\textit{Unit}}_{{\textit{ik}}} \times {\textit{Adjustment}}\,{\textit{Coefficient}}_{{\textit{ik}}}), \end{aligned}$$

where k expresses kth public service. \(Unit\ Cost_k\) is a kind of net standard cost per measurement unit for each service item. \(Measurement\ Unit_{ik}\) is in most cases the number or size of the beneficiaries of a particular service. \(\textit{Adjustment Coefficient}_{ik}\) is a modification ratio that reflects the socioeconomic diversity of a local body and modifies the unit cost in order to make it fit the local body’s socioeconomic circumstances.

1.2 Revenue capacity: CAP

This index measures the fiscal revenue capacity of a municipality before fiscal equalization. It is officially referred to as “Standard Fiscal Revenue” (Kijun Zaisei Syunyu Gaku) and calculated annually by the Ministry of Internal Affairs and Communications. CAP is calculated as follows:

$$\begin{aligned} {\mathrm{CAP}}_i = {\textit{Standard}}\,{\textit{Tax}}\,{\textit{Revenue}}_{i} \times \dfrac{3}{4} + {\textit{Local}}\, {\textit{Transfer}}\,{\textit{Tax}},{\textit{etc}}._i \end{aligned}$$

where Standard Tax Revenues are estimated based on standard tax rates, standard tax collection rates, and estimated tax bases which are calculated using relevant statistics or past tax revenues. Local Transfer Tax, etc. represents the sum of revenues from the Local Transfer Tax and the Special Grant for Traffic Safety Measures. In brief, CAP captures the potential amount of local general revenues before fiscal equalization, which cannot be manipulated by municipalities in the short run.

There are two main reasons that Standard Tax Revenue is multiplied by 3/4.Footnote 19 First, the remaining 1/4 of Standard Tax Revenue is excluded from the fiscal equalization process and left for municipalities so that they can cover some remaining fiscal needs that are not taken into account by the Standard Fiscal Needs calculation. Second, this portion of tax revenue is excluded from the fiscal equalization process so that municipalities have some incentive to increase their local tax revenues by enhancing local economic growth. In other words, if the exact amount of Standard Tax Revenue were taken into account in CAP, LAT-receiving local bodies would have less incentive to enhance local economic growth because the increase in Standard Tax Revenue caused by this economic growth would be completely canceled out by the decrease in the LAT grant.

1.3 Revenue capacity (modified for a predetermined covariate)

As is explained above, CAP itself does not represent “real” pre-equalization revenue capacity as it takes into account some policy objectives of the fiscal equalization scheme such as providing economic incentives to municipalities. We can, however, easily recover real pre-equalization revenue capacity by simply replacing 3/4 for 1 in the above definition of CAP.

When I use pre-equalization revenue capacity as a control variable in Sect. 4, I use this modified version of revenue capacity that reflects the real pre-equalization revenue capacity of municipalities. However, because available statistics are only CAP and Local Transfer Tax, I have to assume that revenue from Special Grant for Traffic Safety Measures is negligible. This assumption should not be a major problem because the amount of the Special Grant for Traffic Safety Measures is in general much smaller than the sum of Standard Tax Revenues and Local Transfer Tax.

I therefore estimate this “real” pre-equalization revenue capacity as follows:

$$\begin{aligned}&{\mathrm{RealCAP}}_i \\&= {\textit{Standard}}\,{\textit{Tax}}\,{\textit{Revenues}}_i \times 1 + {\textit{Local}}\,{\textit{Transfer}}\,{\textit{Tax}},{\textit{etc}}._i \\&=({\mathrm{CAP}}_i - {\textit{Local}}\,{\textit{Transfer}}\,{\textit{Tax}},{\textit{etc}}._i) \times 4/3 + {\textit{Local}}\,{\textit{Transfer}}\,{\textit{Tax}},{\textit{etc}}._i \\&\simeq ({\mathrm{CAP}}_i - {\textit{Local}}\,{\textit{Transfer}}\,{\textit{Tax}}_i) \times 4/3 + {\textit{Local}}\, {\textit{Transfer}}\,{\textit{Tax}}_i. \end{aligned}$$

Appendix 3: Stylized description of Japanese fiscal equalization

In this appendix, I explain the stylized features of the Japanese fiscal equalization scheme and describe how the kink based on the LAT grants is generated in more detail. In order to make this description as concise as possible, throughout this appendix I redefine CAP as follows:

$$\begin{aligned} \mathrm{CAP}_i = Standard\ Tax\ Revenue_i \times \dfrac{3}{4}. \end{aligned}$$

In other words, compared with the actual definition in Appendix “Description of fiscal variables,” CAP is simplified by dropping the second term (Local Transfer Tax and some miscellaneous revenues), which is actually much smaller than the first term (Standard Tax Revenue) in the majority of municipalities.

Then, further assuming that there are no additional revenues other than local tax revenues and LAT grants, the relation between pre-equalization standard revenue (denoted as PreRev) and post-equalization standard revenue (denoted as PostRev) can be expressed as follows:

$$\begin{aligned} PostRev_i = \left\{ \begin{array}{ll} PreRev_i,&{} \quad \text {if}\ \ V_i\le 0\\ PreRev_i + \mathrm{GRANT}_i, &{} \quad \text {if}\ \ V_i > 0.\\ \end{array} \right. \end{aligned}$$

By inserting \(PreRev_i = Standard\ Tax\ Revenue_i,V_i = \mathrm{NEED}_i-\mathrm{CAP}_i,\mathrm{GRANT}_i = V_i = \mathrm{NEED}_i - \mathrm{CAP}_i\) (if \(V_i>0\)), and the above definitions of \(\mathrm{CAP}_i\) into these equations, they can be rewritten as

$$\begin{aligned} PostRev_i = \left\{ \begin{array}{ll} \mathrm{CAP}_i + Standard\ Tax\ Revenue_i \times \dfrac{1}{4},&{} \text {if}\ \mathrm{CAP}_i \ge \mathrm{NEED}_i\\ \mathrm{NEED}_i + Standard\ Tax\ Revenue_i \times \dfrac{1}{4},&{} \text {if}\ \mathrm{CAP}_i < \mathrm{NEED}_i. \\ \end{array} \right. \end{aligned}$$
(12)

These two equations represent an essential function of the Japanese fiscal equalization scheme. First, if CAP is larger than NEED, no LAT grant is distributed and post-equalization standard revenue is identical to the sum of CAP and \(Standard\,Tax\,Revenue\,\times 1/4\). Second, when CAP is smaller than NEED, the LAT grant ensures that municipalities receive the sum of NEED and \(Standard\ Tax\ Revenue \times 1/4\). In both cases, this additional amount, \(Standard\ Tax\ Revenue \times 1/4\), exists due to the fact that CAP is calculated by \(Standard\ Tax\ Revenue \times 3/4\) and the other 1/4 of \(Standard\ Tax\ Revenue\) is excluded from the fiscal equalization formula. Because of this excluded part of \(Standard\ Tax\ Revenue\), which is officially referred to as “Reserved Revenues,” a wealthier municipality is always wealthier even after fiscal equalization. Figure 9 presents actual scatter plots and local polynomial smoothing of PreRevPostRev, and NEED against the assignment variable V. It illustrates how the LAT grant phases in at the cutoff point \(V=0\).

Fig. 9
figure 9

Scatter plots of PreRevPostRev, and NEED). Notes The same sample that is described in Sect. 4 is used for this scatter plot. The local polynomials are obtained using the lpoly command in Stata 13 with the default setting. Sources: reports on the Municipal Public Finance, Census, and CPI

Notice that in this graph PostRev is well above NEED around \(V=0\). This implies that municipalities just after \(V>0\) have ample additional fiscal resources in excess of NEED. These additional fiscal resource come from the term \(Standard\ Tax\ Revenue \times 1/4\) in the second equation of (12). This fact benefits our empirical analysis because LAT grants, which phase in after \(V>0\), can be plausibly considered as “general” and “lump-sum” around the threshold, without any difficulties caused by complicated institutional settings of these grants. I conclude this appendix by examining this issue in greater detail.

In this paper, I implicitly assume that LAT grants are “general” and “lump-sum” and local bodies have full discretion in their decision making on spending and taxation. In other words, I presuppose that an estimated coefficient can be straightforwardly interpreted as the effect of general lump-sum grants on local spending under the full discretion of local municipalities.

But it could be misleading to simply assume that LAT grants are completely general and lump-sum as the so-called Bradford-Oates equivalence theorem, and some previous empirical studies in the literature of local public finance have done. The LAT grant is nominally a general grant that a local body can spend on whatever it wants, but at the same time the LAT grant is the grant that guarantees every single municipality a sufficient amount of revenues to cover centrally determined “standard costs” for local public services, which is referred to as Standard Fiscal Needs and denoted as NEED in this paper. It is sometimes pointed out that the central government takes advantage of LAT grants to control local spending by arbitrarily adjusting NEED. In addition to these possibly “centralized” aspects of LAT grants, the provision of local public services is often strongly regulated by the central government through various centralized legal frameworks.

In sum, although local bodies do not have to strictly follow these centrally determined standards, they quite often cannot control their expenditures on some local public services because the basic legal and provisional frameworks of these local services are centrally determined. Hayashi (2000, (2006) provides critical reviews of empirical studies on flypaper effects in Japan and points out that these previous studies do not consider these institutional settings of the Japanese general grant and naively treat it as a general and lump-sum grant as studies of similar schemes in the USA do.

In fact, this obligatory and centralized feature of local public services is part of the institutional basis of LAT grants: Since the central government forces all local bodies to provide particular levels of local public services, fiscal resources for these services have to be guaranteed by the intergovernmental fiscal transfer which reflects the expected costs of these services. This feature of the LAT grant is officially referred to as a function of “fiscal resource guarantee.”

According to Fig. 9, however, I would argue that LAT grants can be considered to be general and lump-sum around the threshold \(V=0\) regardless of the centralized features of these grants and local administration. In other words, around the threshold, PostRev is well above NEED, and therefore, the relatively obligatory local public services that are reflected in the calculation of NEED can be financed even without the LAT grant. It is thus possible to assume that the marginal increase in the LAT grant around the threshold affects local bodies’ expenditure in exactly the same way that standard general and lump-sum grants do.

Appendix 4: Description of data arrangement

Japan is a unitary state which has three tiers of administrative authorities: the central government, 47 prefectures, and 1750 municipalities (as of 2010). Municipalities are classified into four categories: cities (shi), towns (cho), villages (son), and special districts (ku). Cities are generally larger than towns and villages, and in principle the minimum population required to become a city is 50,000. Even if the population of a city becomes less than 50,000, however, it does not have to become a town or village. The 23 special districts are all located in Tokyo Metropolis (prefecture) and have similar duties to other municipalities but follow a different vertical fiscal equalization scheme managed by the prefecture. Cities and towns/villages have similar duties under the LAT grant fiscal equalization scheme, but cities have more responsibilities in some areas.

In this paper, I only use the datasets for cities, but not all cities are included in my analysis. First, I exclude so-called designated cities, which consisted of the 12 largest cities in Japan during the sample period. I drop these cities from the sample because their response to the marginal increase in their LAT grants might be institutionally different from other cities as a result of the fact that some of the duties normally assigned to prefectures are delegated to them and their administrative responsibility is thus larger than that of normal cities. Second, I also remove the cities that experienced amalgamation between 1975 and 1999 because the calculation of the LAT grants for these merged cities was affected by special measures. Because this special measure was in effect for 5 years after amalgamation, municipalities which merged before 1975 were not affected by this measure after 1980. Finally, there are some LAT-receiving municipalities whose need-capacity gap is apparently different from the amount of their LAT grant, possibly due to measurement errors or typos. Therefore, I drop 18 observations in which |Need-capacity gap − LAT grant per capita| is larger than 10,000 yen.

Appendix 5: RK estimation validity check

1.1 Smooth density of the assignment variable

Following a density test applied to an RD design in McCrary (2008), Card et al. (2015) presents a density test applied to an RK design using collapsed data with equal-sized bins based on an assignment variable. Two required variables in this collapsed data set are the number of observations in each bin and the midpoint values of the assignment variable in each bin. I use bins with width 2 and bandwidth \([-50,+50]\), which is a benchmark bandwidth for local regressions in this paper. Table 6 shows that in each sample an RK estimate is statistically insignificant if the order of polynomial is equal to or larger than two. The value of Akaike information criteria (AIC) is smallest when the order of polynomial is two. Figure 10 graphically illustrates that there seems to be no kink at the threshold.

Table 6 RK estimates for the density of the assignment variable (\(bin\ size=2,bandwidth\ |V|<50\))
Fig. 10
figure 10

Density of the assignment variable (\(bin\ size=2,bandwidth\ |V|<50\)). Notes Bin size is 2 and fitted curves are based on the quadratic, cubic, and quartic RK models that impose continuity at the cutoff

1.2 Distributions of covariates against V

See Fig. 11.

Fig. 11
figure 11

Covariates against need-capacity gap (\(bandwidth\ |V|<50\)). Notes Optimal data-driven plots are generated by the default setting of rdplot command with Stata 13, which is developed by Calonico et al. (2015). Quadratic fits are based on the quadratic RK model that imposes continuity at the cutoff

Appendix 6: OLS results from the empirical application

See Table 7.

Table 7 OLS estimates for total expenditure

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Ando, M. How much should we trust regression-kink-design estimates?. Empir Econ 53, 1287–1322 (2017). https://doi.org/10.1007/s00181-016-1155-8

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s00181-016-1155-8

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation