Skip to main content

Blockchain: The New Intellectual Battleground Within Economics

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
Banking and Monetary Policy from the Perspective of Austrian Economics

Abstract

Blockchain technology has been hailed as a technology that could transform large sectors of the economy. The key tenets of the Austrian School will be complemented by blockchain as it allows for private digital currencies and decentralised trading networks free from the control of authorities. Several Austrian School economists, including Hayek, have written about the benefits of private, competing currencies. Orthodox economics will struggle intellectually to model the consequences as it is axiomatic for much of their macroeconomics that central banks can stimulate the economy through the money supply. For the Austrian School, reducing the monetary policy tools of central bankers will bring benefits to the economy.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 149.00
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 199.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD 199.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. 1.

    For a more detailed analysis of Mesopotamian ledger systems, see Snell’s (2007) Ledgers and Prices: Early Mesopotamian Merchant Accounts (Yale Near Eastern Researches).

  2. 2.

    It was in the Summa de arithmetica, geometria. Proportioni et proportionalita (1494) that double entry bookkeeping was first outlined in print along with other areas of mathematics including algebraic theories of the time. Double-entry accounting also possibly developed independently in Korea in the Goryeo dynasty (918-1392) during a time when Kaesong was a regional trading centre.

  3. 3.

    Although around the middle of the thirteenth century in Toulouse 96, shares of the Société des Moulins du Bazacle (Bazacle Milling Company) traded at a value derived from the profits of the mills the society owned, arguably making it the first company. This concept, however, did not proliferate at the time as it would later in the eighteenth century.

  4. 4.

    See Cerf et al. (2012) in “Brief History of the Internet” from the Internet Society.

  5. 5.

    Nakomoto, S (2009) “Bitcoin: A peer-to-peer electronic cash system”. (http://bitcoin.org/bitcoin.pdf).

  6. 6.

    There are now different types of blockchain; some are permissioned (require permission from an authority to access them) while some are permissionless. See the UK Government’s Chief Scientific Adviser’s report on blockchain (Walport 2016) for more information.

  7. 7.

    For a more general introduction to blockchain, see Swan (2015).

  8. 8.

    This is from a 1999 interview with Nobel Laureate Milton Friedman conducted by NTU/F (https://www.youtube.com/watch?v=6MnQJFEVY7s).

  9. 9.

    In most of the key textbooks of macroeconomics, for instance Mankiw’s Principles of Economics (1997, 2014), it is axiomatic to many of the arguments that central banks can “stimulate” the economy through control of the quantity of money.

  10. 10.

    Lecture to the memory of Alfred Nobel, December 11, 1974.

  11. 11.

    See Roger Garrison Time and Money: The Macroeconomics of Capital Structure, Routledge, 2001.

  12. 12.

    See especially Carl Menger The Origins of Money (1892).

  13. 13.

    Carl Menger’s Lectures to Crown Prince Rudolf of Austria (1994) edited by Erich and Monica Streissler, see p. 171 where Menger also relates interest rates to the “abundance of capital” in the economy.

  14. 14.

    Carl Menger The Origins of Money (1892, pp. 34).

  15. 15.

    See for instance p. 225.

  16. 16.

    In this vein The Bank of England, in their analysis of digital currencies (Ali et al. 2014a: 278), considered Radford (1945) with respect to the three functions of money—a store of value, a unit of account, and a medium of exchange—who documented “that cigarettes served all three of these roles within prisoner of war camps during the Second World War”.

  17. 17.

    In The General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money Chapter 17, Keynes (1936) noted that “As a footnote to the above, it may be worth emphasising what has been already stated above, namely, that ‘liquidity’ and ‘carrying-costs’ are both a matter of degree and that it is only in having the former high relatively to the latter that the peculiarity of ‘money’ consists....There is, clearly, no absolute standard of ‘liquidity’ but merely a scale of liquidity—a varying premium of which account has to be taken”.

  18. 18.

    In Aristotle’s Politics Book 1:9[1] (c.350 B.C. translated by Sinclair, revised and re-presented by Saunders (2000)) The Philosopher considered money and came to the conclusion that in a market every good has two uses, first it has the use for which it was designed, the second use being as an item to sell or barter—effectively a form of moneyness as value of such goods in the secondary sense rests largely on their liquidity in the market. Copernicus, in his 1526 report on monetary systems to the King of Poland and the Prussian Diet, included a rudimentary form of the quantity theory of money and Gresham’s Law as well as an early notion of moneyness.

  19. 19.

    See Rosenfeld, Meni (2012). Overview of colored coins. White paper, bitcoil.co.il.

  20. 20.

    Hayek (1978, p. 57), in The Denationalisation of Money, explained that the roots of this conception of money may lie in the legal convenience of it, “Similarly, the legal fiction that there is one clearly defined thing called ‘money’ that can be sharply distinguished from other things, a fiction introduced to satisfy the work of the lawyer or judge, was never true so far as things are to be referred to which have the characteristic effects of events on the side of money. Yet it has done much harm through leading to the demand that, for certain purposes, only ‘money’ issued by government may be used, or that there must always be some single kind of object which can be referred to as the ‘money’ of the country. It has also, as we shall see, led to the development in economic theory of an explanation of the value of units of money which, though under its simplified assumptions it gives some useful approximations, is of no help for the kind of problems we have to examine here”.

  21. 21.

    One of the key criticisms of Bitcoin has been the volatility, for instance the Bank of England point out that “The standard deviation of daily moves for bitcoin is roughly 17 times greater than that for sterling. The worth of bitcoin as a medium or long-term store of value, however, depends on the strength of demand over time, which will in turn depend on users’ evolving beliefs about the ultimate success of the digital currency”.

  22. 22.

    For one of the pre-Bitcoin analyses of smart contracts, see Szabo, N. 1997. Formalizing and securing relationships on public networks—Szabo summarises the concept neatly “The basic idea behind smart contracts is that many kinds of contractual clauses (such as collateral, bonding, delineation of property rights, etc.) can be embedded in the hardware and software we deal with, in such a way as to make breach of contract expensive (if desired, sometimes prohibitively so) for the breacher”.

  23. 23.

    See the Financial Times article “Central banks explore blockchain to create digital currencies” (https://www.ft.com/content/f15d3ab6-750d-11e6-bf48-b372cdb1043a).

  24. 24.

    Altcoin is the term given to the plethora of digital currencies which arose following the development of Bitcoin, for a list of market capitalisations, see here (https://coinmarketcap.com/).

  25. 25.

    The Bank for International Settlements (BIS Working Papers No 346) has commented on this, “In the canonical New Keynesian paradigm, rather paradoxically, they are entirely redundant or at least inessential. The canonical model is that of a money-less economy that can do away with the ultimate settlement medium (Woodford’s (2003) “cashless economy”). Indeed, paradoxically, when settlement balances (money) are introduced, they act as a “friction”, not as the indispensable lubricant in an otherwise inefficient barter-exchange mechanism. It is an economy in which credit is just a vague shadow in the background: since credit does not affect behaviour, its evolution does not need to be tracked. When banks are introduced, credit may have more information content. But, even then, intermediaries do not generate purchasing power; they simply transfer real resources from one sector to the other. The underlying economy is, in this sense, a real economy disguised as a monetary one. Credit is just another real resource that households make available to entrepreneurs. This contrasts sharply with the essence of monetary analysis.”

  26. 26.

    Friedrich Hayek, The Fatal Conceit (1988, Ch. 5 p. 84).

  27. 27.

    See, for instance, the Bank of England’s “multi-year research programme into the implications of a central bank, like the Bank of England, issuing a digital currency” (http://www.bankofengland.co.uk/research/Pages/onebank/cbdc.aspx).

  28. 28.

    Locomotive Act 1865.

  29. 29.

    For one of the first examples of a more elaborate blockchain network where the functionality goes well beyond the monetary aspects, see the evolution of Vitalik Buterin’s initial papers from Buterin, Vitalik (2014a). Multisig: The Future of Bitcoin. to Buterin, Vitalik (2014b). A next-generation smart contract and decentralized application platform. White Paper.

  30. 30.

    See here https://www.weforum.org/agenda/2016/10/blockchain-cryptocurrencies-and-central-banks-opportunity-or-threat

  31. 31.

    See the full speech here http://www.bankofengland.co.uk/publications/Pages/speeches/2015/840.aspx

  32. 32.

    For a fuller discussion, please see IMF working paper WP/15/224 (Agarwal and Kimball 2015) Breaking Through the Zero Lower Bound.

  33. 33.

    See Chapter 5 p. 76, the full quote is as follows “If we had deliberately built, or were consciously shaping, the structure of human action, we would merely have to ask individuals why they had interacted with any particular structure. Whereas, in fact, specialised students, even after generations of effort, find it exceedingly difficult to explain such matters, and cannot agree on what are the causes or what will be the effects of particular events. The curious task of economics is to demonstrate to men how little they really know about what they imagine they can design”.

  34. 34.

    See here https://www.bloomberg.com/view/articles/2016-09-01/on-digital-currencies-central-banks-should-lead

  35. 35.

    For instance see “The New Lombard Street” (2010) by Perry Mehrling for a good description of the banking system, taking into account recent developments such as the shadow banking system. This can be compared with Walter Bagehot’s 1873 classic “Lombard Street: A Description of the Money Market”.

  36. 36.

    For an interesting summary of peer-to-peer lending, see The Business Models and Economics of Peer-to-Peer Lending by Alistair Milne and Paul Parboteeah (European Credit research Institute No. 17 / May 2016).

  37. 37.

    See Roger Garrison’s “Time and Money: The Macroeconomics of Capital Structure” (2001) for an exposition of Austrian Business Cycle Theory compared to other related theories from other schools of economics.

  38. 38.

    I will avoid using the term “natural rate of interest” since it has been used by different economists to convey often incompatible ideas.

  39. 39.

    See for example this outline of monetary policy by the Bank of England (http://www.bankofengland.co.uk/monetarypolicy/Pages/how.aspx).

  40. 40.

    See especially Hayek’s Prices and Production (1931) and Mises ([1912] 1980 and 1999).

  41. 41.

    In The Positive Theory of Capital (1891), written 7 years after Capital and Interest, von Böhm-Bawerk outlines the heterogeneity of capital by using the metaphor of a growing tree; the tree grows in different ways at different stages and exogenous manipulation will distort its natural growth patterns.

  42. 42.

    See, for example, Murray Rothbard’s “America’s Great Depression” (1963) for an elaborate analysis of the formation of a bubble.

  43. 43.

    See The Economics of Housing Bubbles by Mark Thornton (2006).

  44. 44.

    Austrian School tendencies are far from alien to the BIS which has cited the work of Hayek several times.

  45. 45.

    For a useful outline, see Minsky’s Theory of Financial Crises in Global Context by Martin H Wolfson (2001) see also Minsky (1982) and Minsky (1986).

  46. 46.

    Note that “VCs” are “virtual currencies”.

  47. 47.

    The issue of deflation, which surrounds this, was addressed from an Austrian School perspective in Selgin, G (1997): Less than zero: the case for a falling price level in a growing economy in which he challenges the assumption in much of modern economics that deflation is harmful.

  48. 48.

    In Bank of England Chief Economist Andy Haldane’s speech “How Low Can You Go?”, he set forth this very point (note that the ZLB he refers to is “zero lower bound”) “These questions do not have easy answers. That is why work on central bank-issued digital currencies forms a core part of the Bank’s current research agenda (Bank of England 2015). Although the hurdles to implementation are high, so too is the potential prize if the ZLB constraint could be slackened. Perhaps central bank money is ripe for its own great technological leap forward, prompted by the pressing demands of the ZLB”. http://www.bankofengland.co.uk/publications/Pages/speeches/2015/840.aspx

  49. 49.

    See Robert Shiller’s Irrational Exuberance (2000); the updated 2015 version includes commentary on the current valuations of bonds and stocks.

References

  • Agarwal, R., & Kimball, M. (2015). Breaking through the zero lower bound (IMF Working Paper. Middle East and Central Asia Department WP/15/224).

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ali, R., Barrdear, J., Clews, R., & Southgate, J. (2014a). The economics of digital currencies. Bank of England Quarterly Bulletin, 54(3), 276–286.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ali, R., Barrdear, J., Clews, R., & Southgate, J. (2014b). Innovations in payment technologies and the emergence of digital currencies. Bank of England Quarterly Bulletin, 54(3), 262–275.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bagehot, W. (1873). Lombard street: A description of the money market. London: P S King and Son.

    Google Scholar 

  • Böhm-Bawerk, E. v. (1884). Capital and interest: A critical history of economical theory (William A. Smart, trans.). London: Macmillan and Co.

    Google Scholar 

  • Böhm-Bawerk, E. (1891). The positive theory of capital. Auburn, AL: Ludwig von Mises Institute.

    Google Scholar 

  • Borio, C., & Disyatat, P. (2011). Global imbalances and the financial crisis: Link or no link? (BIS Working Papers No 346 Monetary and Economic Department).

    Google Scholar 

  • Borio, C., & Lowe, P. (2002, July). Asset prices, financial and monetary stability: Exploring the nexus (BIS Working Papers No 114).

    Google Scholar 

  • Borio, C., & Lowe, P. (2004, July). Securing sustainable price stability: Should credit come back from the wilderness? (BIS Working Papers No 157).

    Google Scholar 

  • Buterin, V. (2014a). Multisig: The future of bitcoin.

    Google Scholar 

  • Buterin, V. (2014b). A next-generation smart contract and decentralized application platform (White Paper).

    Google Scholar 

  • Cerf, V. G., et al. (2012). Brief History of the Internet. The Internet Society.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dobbs, R., Lund, S., Woetzel, J., & Mutafchieva, M. (February 2015). Debt and (not much) deleveraging. McKinsey Global Institute.

    Google Scholar 

  • European Central Bank. (October 2012). Virtual currency schemes. Frankfurt am Main.

    Google Scholar 

  • Friedman, M., & Schwartz A. (1987). Has government any role in money? (p. 312). University of Chicago Press. ISBN 0-226-74228-8.

    Google Scholar 

  • Garrison, R. W. (2001). Time and money: The macroeconomics of capital structure. London: Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hayek, F. (1931). Prices and production. London: Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hayek, F. (1933). Monetary theory and the trade cycle. New York: Harcourt, Brace & Co.

    Google Scholar 

  • He, D., Habermeier, K., Leckow, R., Haksar, V., Almeida, Y., Kashima, M., Kyriakos-Saad, N., et al. (2016) Virtual currencies and beyond: Initial considerations (IMF Staff Discussion Notes January 2016 SDN/16/03).

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hicks, J. (1935, February). A suggestion for simplifying the theory of money. Economica.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Iansiti, M., & Lakhani, K. (2017). The truth about blockchain. Boston, MA: Harvard Business School Publishing.

    Google Scholar 

  • Keynes, J. (1936). The general theory of employment, interest and money. London: Macmillan. (reprinted 2007).

    Google Scholar 

  • Machlup, F. (1970). Euro-dollar creation: A mystery story. Banca Nazionale del Lavoro Quarterly Review, 23(94), 219–260.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mankiw, G. (2014). Principles of economics (7th ed.). Nashville, TN: South-Western College Pub.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mehrling, P. (2010). The New Lombard Street: How the fed became the dealer of last resort. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Menger, C. ([1892] 1999). On the origins of money. Auburn, AL: Ludwig von Mises Institute

    Google Scholar 

  • Mill, J. S. (1848). The principles of political economy with some of their applications to social philosophy, 7th edition, 1871 as reproduced. J. M. Robson (Ed.), Toronto: University of Toronto Press, 1965.

    Google Scholar 

  • Milne, A., & Parboteeah, P. (2016). The business models and economics of peer-to-peer lending by European Credit research Institute No. 17/May 2016

    Google Scholar 

  • Minsky, H. (1982). Can “It” happen again?: Essays on instability and finance. New York: Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Minsky, H. (1986). Stabilizing an unstable economy. New Haven: Yale University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mises, L. ([1912] 1980). The theory of money and credit. Indianapolis: Liberty Classics.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mises, L. (1944). Omnipotent Government: The rise of the total state and total war. New Haven: Yale University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mises, L ([1949] 1998). Human action. 5th ed. Auburn, AL: Ludwig von Mises Institute

    Google Scholar 

  • Mises, L. (1999). Human action. Auburn, AL: Mises Institute.

    Google Scholar 

  • Nakamoto, S. (2008). Bitcoin: A peer-to-peer electronic cash system. (http://bitcoin.org/bitcoin.pdf)

  • Niepelt, D. (2015). Reserves for everyone—Towards a new monetary regime? VoxEU, January 21.

    Google Scholar 

  • Niepelt, D. (2016). Blockchain, cryptocurrencies, and central banks: Opportunity or threat? World Economic Forum published in Collaboration with VoxEU.

    Google Scholar 

  • Oppers, S. (2002). The Austrian theory of business cycles: Old lessons for modern economic policy? (IMF Working Paper 02/02). Office in Europe.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Peters, G. W., & Panayi, E. (2016). Understanding modern banking ledgers through blockchain technologies: Future of transaction processing and smart contracts on the Internet of money. In P. Tasca, T. Aste, L. Pelizzon, & N. Perony (Eds.), Banking beyond banks and money: A guide to banking services in the twenty-first century (pp. 239–278). Switzerland: Springer.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Radford, R. A. (1945). The economic organisation of a P.O.W. camp. Economica, 12(48), 189–201.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Raskin, M., & Yermack, D. (May 2016). Digital currencies, decentralized ledgers, and the future of Central Banking (NBER Working Paper No. 22238).

    Google Scholar 

  • Rosenfeld, M. (2012). Overview of colored coins (White paper, bitcoil.co.il).

    Google Scholar 

  • Rothbard, M. ([1963] (2000). America’s great depression (5th Ed.). Auburn, AL, Ludwig von Mises Institute.

    Google Scholar 

  • Selgin, G. (1997). Less than zero: The case for a falling price level in a growing economy. London: Institute of Economic Affairs.

    Google Scholar 

  • Shiller, R. (2000). Irrational exuberance. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sinclair T. A. (transl). Revised and re-presented by Trevor J. Saunders (2000); AristotleThe Politics. Pearson; Rev Ed.

    Google Scholar 

  • Snell, D. (2007). Ledgers and prices: Early Mesopotamian Merchant Accounts (Yale Near Eastern Researches). New Haven and London: Yale University Press

    Google Scholar 

  • Swan, M. (2015). Blockchain: Blueprint for a new economy. Newton MA: O’Reilly Media, Inc..

    Google Scholar 

  • Szabo, N. (1997). Formalizing and securing relationships on public networks. First Monday, 2(9).

    Google Scholar 

  • Thornton, M. (2006). The economics of housing bubbles. Auburn, AL: Ludwig von Mises Institute.

    Google Scholar 

  • Walport, M. (2016). Distributed ledger technology: Beyond blockchain (A report by the UK Government Chief Scientific Adviser).

    Google Scholar 

  • Wicksell, K. (1898). Interest and prices (R. F. Kahn, Trans.). London: Royal Economic Society, Macmillan, 1936.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wolfson, M. (2001). Minsky’s theory of financial crises in global context. Journal of Economic Issues, XXXVI(2), 393–400.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Max Rangeley .

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2018 Springer International Publishing AG, part of Springer Nature

About this chapter

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this chapter

Rangeley, M. (2018). Blockchain: The New Intellectual Battleground Within Economics. In: Godart-van der Kroon, A., Vonlanthen, P. (eds) Banking and Monetary Policy from the Perspective of Austrian Economics. Springer, Cham. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-319-75817-6_13

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics