Skip to main content

Assessing Globalization and Regionalization Through Network Indices

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
Indicator-Based Monitoring of Regional Economic Integration

Part of the book series: United Nations University Series on Regionalism ((UNSR,volume 13))

Abstract

The authors use network analysis (NA) in order to study the impact of globalization and regionalization on the entire structure of trade flows. NA focuses on trade flows as a network, therefore emphasizing the relationship between countries – the nodes – and the network structure itself. According to the authors, this approach is particularly fit to offer a unified view of the system’s properties, help develop trade policies, and analyze changes in the world trading system. This is why the authors present the changes in the trade networks by studying indices that describe the network’s characteristics: density, closeness, betweenness and degree distribution. The authors conclude that network completeness is indeed achieved in some sub-regional components; however the level of heterogeneity between countries has increased.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 84.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Hardcover Book
USD 109.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. 1.

    The literature analyzing world trade flows as a network is growing. Some earlier papers emphasize the topological properties of this network, but lack to a very large extent the economic interpretation of these findings. See for example, Bhattacharya et al. (2008), Fagiolo et al. (2008), Garlaschelli and Loffredo (2005), Serrano and Boguna (2003). More recently, this type of analysis was used to assess the economic implications of the properties of the international trade network. See for example, De Benedictis and Tajoli (2010, 2011), and Chaney (2011). For a general analysis of economic networks, see Jackson (2008).

  2. 2.

    The choice of the trade data is not neutral for describing the network. Even if the origin of all data is the same database, a long time span might introduce some discontinuities. A number of countries (especially the smallest and poorest ones) are not always reporting trade data. Additional problems in assessing our dataset come from the fact that over time new countries were born (e.g. the Czech Republic and Slovakia), and a few disappeared (e.g. Yugoslavia), changing the size of the network. We use import data because they are more reliable in terms of coverage and completeness, but import data can give rise to a network structure that is slightly different than the one found with exports – as shown by Kali and Reyes (2007) and by De Benedictis and Tajoli (2008) – or with average trade flows (the average of exports and imports). The same is true in a gravity context; see Subramanian and Wei (2007).

  3. 3.

    In 2000, 90% of total trade value corresponded to 855 flows out of nearly 12,000 registered trade flows, and only 82 countries out of the 157 reporting countries generate again 90% of trade.

  4. 4.

    Working at the aggregate level, we are aware of the fact that apparently unconnected countries (for example Malta or United Arab Emirates, showing no link at all in some years) are in fact not reporting data and the missing links therefore do not indicate that the country does not trade at all. By consequence, removing vertices without any link will eliminate a few meaningful (but unobserved) links and some meaningless zeros, but it should not introduce a systematic bias, even if it changes the size of the network.

  5. 5.

    We include all the definitions of the indices in the Annexes.

  6. 6.

    Larger networks are expected to have a lower density, because an increase in the number of vertices requires a much more than proportional increase in the number of links to keep the density constant.

  7. 7.

    This finding is in line with the evidence gathered through gravity models, showing that geographical distance is important in trade relations, as well as sharing a border and other proximity indicators.

  8. 8.

    A similar image is sometimes used to describe the network of preferential trade relationship between the European Union and its partner countries, particularly in developing regions, which is depicted as a hub-and-spoke system. The lack of preferential agreements among the spokes of the system is sometimes considered as a factor that can inhibit their ability to reap the benefits of their integration with the EU.

  9. 9.

    Goods’ complexity here is following the definition given by Nunn (2007), which refers to the number of intermediate inputs necessary to produce a final good.

  10. 10.

    For further analysis of the international trade network at the sector level, see De Benedictis et al. (2013). The paper is also providing a large set of centrality indicators for individual countries, to understand countries’ position in the WTN and their evolution over time.

  11. 11.

    For a general discussion on the concept of centrality in networks, see Bonacich (1987).

  12. 12.

    The standardized degree centrality of a vertex is also often used, given by the vertex degree divided by the maximum possible degree: \( {C}_i^{sd}=\frac{d}{n-1} \).

  13. 13.

    The indices presented here are developed by Iapadre and Tironi (2009) to which we refer for further details.

  14. 14.

    In the network analysis literature, node degree is sometimes called neighborhood degree.

  15. 15.

    IBCC i can be computed only if IND i >1.

  16. 16.

    See Kali and Reyes (2007).

  17. 17.

    Fagiolo, Reyes and Schiavo (2008) show why WNA is more informative than BNA in describing the world trade network.

  18. 18.

    The minimum IAC of −1 (perfect disassortativity) is reached when Tr( R ) = 0 (no intra-regional trade) and ‖R 2‖ = 0.5. The latter parameter depends on the distribution of extra-regional flows and on the number of regions. It can be shown that ‖R 2‖ is equal to 0.5 only for a two-region world with no intra-regional trade. For a symmetric matrix with a number of regions larger than 2, the minimum IAC is higher than −1 and grows with the number of regions.

References

  • Bhattacharya, K., Mukherjee, G., Saramäki, J., Kaski, K., & Manna, S.S. (2008). The international trade network: Weighted network analysis and modeling. Journal of Statistical Mechanics: Theory and Experiment, P02002.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bonacich, P. (1987). Power and centrality: A family of measures. The American Journal of Sociology, 92(5), 1170–1182.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Borgatti, S. P. (2005). Centrality and network flow. Social Networks, 27(1), 55–71.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brahmbhatt, M. (1998). Measuring Global Economic Integration: A Review of the Literature and Recent Evidence (Working Paper). The World Bank.

    Google Scholar 

  • Chaney, T. (2011). The Network Structure of International Trade (NBER Working Paper, 16753).

    Google Scholar 

  • De Benedictis, L., & Tajoli, L. (2008). La rete degli scambi mondiali. L’Italia nell’economia internazionale. ICE 2007-2008. Istituto Nazionale per il Commercio Estero, Roma.

    Google Scholar 

  • De Benedictis, L., & Tajoli, L. (2010). Comparing sectoral international trade networks. Aussen-Wirtschaft, 65, 167–189.

    Google Scholar 

  • De Benedictis, L., & Tajoli, L. (2011). The world trade network. The World Economy, 34, 1417–1454.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • De Benedictis L., Nenci, S., Santoni, G., Tajoli, L., Vicarelli, C. (2013). Network Analysis of World Trade using the BACI-CEPII database (CEPII Working Paper, 2013-24).

    Google Scholar 

  • Fagiolo, G., Reyes, J., & Schiavo, S. (2008). On the topological properties of the world trade web: A weighted network analysis. Physica A, 387, 3868–3873.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Freeman, L. (1979). Centrality in social networks: Conceptual clarifications. Social Networks, 23(1), 215–239.

    Google Scholar 

  • Garlaschelli, D., & Loffredo, M. I. (2005). Structure and evolution of the world trade network. Physica A, 35, 138–144.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Goyal, S. (2007). Connections. An introduction to the economics of networks. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Iapadre, L. (2006). Regional integration agreements and the geography of world trade: Statistical indicators and empirical evidence. In P. De Lombaerde (Ed.), Assessment and measurement of regional integration (pp. 65–85). London: Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Iapadre, L., & Plummer, M. (2011). Statistical measures of regional trade integration. In P. De Lombaerde, R. Flôres, L. Iapadre, & M. Schulz (Eds.), The regional integration manual (pp. 98–123). Abingdon/Routledge: Oxon.

    Google Scholar 

  • Iapadre, L., & Tajoli, L. (2014). Emerging countries and trade regionalization. A network analysis. Journal of Policy Modeling., 36(S1), 89–110.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Iapadre, L., & Tironi, F. (2009). Measuring trade regionalisation: The case of Asia (UNU-CRIS Working Paper, 2009/9).

    Google Scholar 

  • Jackson, M. O. (2008). Social and economic networks. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kali, R., & Reyes, J. (2007). The architecture of globalization: A network approach to international economic integration. Journal of International Business Studies, 38, 595–620.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Newman, M. E. J. (2003a). Mixing patterns in networks. Physical Review E, 67, 026126.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Newman, M. E. J. (2003b). The structure and function of complex networks. SIAM Review, 45, 167–256.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nunn, N. (2007). Relationship-specificity, incomplete contracts, and the pattern of trade. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 122(2), 569–600.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Piccardi, C., & Tajoli, L. (2012). Existence and significance of communities in the world trade web. Physical Review E, 85, 066119.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Serrano, M. A., & Boguña, A. (2003). Topology of the world trade web. Physical Review E, 68, 015101.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Subramanian, A., & Wei, S. J. (2007). The WTO promotes trade, strongly but unevenly. Journal of International Economics, 72, 151–175.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Vega Redondo, F. (2007). Complex social networks. New York: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • WTO. (2010). International trade statistics. Geneva: World Trade Organization.

    Google Scholar 

  • WTO. (2011). The WTO and preferential trade agreements: From co-existence to coherence. In World Trade Report 2011. Geneva: World Trade Organization.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Lucia Tajoli .

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

Annexes

Annexes

1.1 Annex A.1: Definition of a Network

A network consists of a graph plus some additional information on the vertices or the lines of the graph. In its general form, a network:

$$ N=\left( V, L, W, P\right) $$
(15.1)

consists of a graph G = (V,L), where V = (1, 2, …. n) is a set of vertices and L is a set of lines between pairs of vertices. In simple graphs, L is a binary variable, and L ij ϵ (0,1) denotes the link between two vertices i and j, taking a value of 1 if there exists a link between i and j and 0 otherwise. Another convenient way (Vega-Redondo 2007) of representing simple graphs is through its adjacency matrix, a V × V-dimensional matrix denoted by a ij such that:

$$ {a}_{ij}=\kern0.5em \left\{\begin{array}{cc}\hfill 1\hfill & \hfill if\ \left( i, j\right)\in L\hfill \\ {}\hfill 0\hfill & \hfill otherwise\hfill \end{array}\right. $$

Therefore, two vertices are said to be adjacent (or at just one-step distance) if they are connected by a line. The concept of geodesic distance in networks refers to the number of steps needed to connect two vertices V i and V j , named δij. The shortest the distance between two vertices the closest is the connection between them.

Weighted networks add to simple graph some additional information on the lines of the graph. The additional information is contained in the line value function W, where line values are positive weights associated to each line, usually indicating the strength of the relation. In the ij case, w ij is the link’s weight. The additional information on the vertices is contained in the vertex value function P, assembling different properties or characteristics of the vertices.

The size of a network is expressed by the number of vertices n and the number of lines m. The set of vertices that are connected to any given V i defines its neighborhood where d ≥ 0 denotes the number of neighbors of V i . Since, in simple directed graphs, a vertex can be both a sender and a receiver, the indegree of a vertex is the number of arcs it receives, and the outdegree is the number of arcs it sends. The notion of neighborhood is associated to the one of clustering. The clustering coefficient of a vertex V i is the proportion of a vertex’s neighbors which are neighbors of each other. The clustering coefficient for the network as a whole can be derived taking a weighted or an unweighted average across vertices in the network.

1.2 Annex A.2: Structural Properties and Centrality of a Network

The density of a network is the number of lines in a simple network, expressed as a proportion of the maximum possible number of lines. It is defined by:

$$ \gamma =\frac{m}{m_{m ax}} $$
(15.2)

where in a simple directed graph, m max  = n(n − 1).

Accordingly, a complete network is a network with maximum density.

The position of every vertex in a network is measured in terms of centrality.Footnote 11 The simplest measure of centrality of V i is the number of its neighbors, i.e. its degree centrality, \( {\ C}_i^d= d. \) Footnote 12

The degree centralization of a network is defined in relative terms (like most other measures of centralization) looking at the unevenness of the distribution of links among nodes in the network. The minimum degree for any component of the network is 0 and the maximum possible degree is n−1. If \( {C}_i^{d^{*}} \) is the centrality of the vertex that attains the maximum centrality score, the variation in the degree of vertices is the summed absolute differences between the centrality scores of the vertices and the maximum centrality score among them. So, as the maximum sum of degree centrality absolute differences is (n−2)(n−1), the degree centralization of a network is defined as:

$$ {C}^d=\frac{\sum_{i=1}^n\left|{C}_i^d-{C}_i^{d^{*}}\right|}{\left( n-1\right)\left( n-2\right)} $$
(15.3)

and the higher the variation in the degree of vertices, the higher the centralization of a network. The degree centralization of any regular network is 0, while a pure star has a degree centralization of 1.

The notion of geodesic distance is the base of a second definition of centrality: closeness centrality. The closeness centrality of a vertex V i is the number of other vertices divided by the sum of all distances between V i and all others vertices:

$$ {C}_i^c=\frac{n-1}{\sum_{i\ne j}^{n-1}{\delta}_{i j}} $$
(15.4)

At the network level, if \( {C}_i^{c^{*}} \) is the centrality of the vertex that attains the maximum closeness centrality score, the closeness centralization of a network is (Freeman 1979; Goyal 2007):

$$ {C}^c=\frac{\sum_{i=1}^n\left|{C}_i^c-{C}_i^{c^{*}}\right|}{\left( n-1\right)\left( n-2\right)/\left(2 n-3\right)} $$
(15.5)

A third notion of centrality often used in the literature is based on the intuition that a vertex V i is central if it is essential in the indirect link between V j and V k . A vertex that is located on the geodesic distance between many pairs of vertices plays a central role in the network, because it is necessary for all periphery vertices in order to be mutually reachable. This concept of centrality is called betweenness centrality. The betweenness centrality of vertex V i is the proportion of all geodesic distances between pairs of other vertices that include this vertex (Vega-Redondo 2007):

$$ {C}_i^b=\sum_{j\ne k}\frac{\delta_{j k}^i}{\delta_{j k}} $$
(15.6)

where δ jk is the total number of shortest paths joining any two vertices V j and V k , and \( {\delta}_{jk}^i \) is the number of those paths that connect V j and V k through V i . The core of a star network has maximum betweenness centrality, because all geodesic distances between pairs of other vertices include the core. In contrast, all other vertices have minimum betweenness centrality, because they are not located between other vertices.

The betweenness centralization is the variation in the betweenness centrality of vertices divided by the maximum variation in betweenness centrality scores possible in a network of the same size:

$$ {C}^b=\frac{\sum_{i=1}^n\left|{C}_i^b-{C}_i^{b^{*}}\right|}{n^2-\left( n-1\right)/\left(2 n-1\right)} $$
(15.7)

1.3 Annex A.3: Network Analysis of Regional Trade Flows

1.3.1 Binary Network Analysis

The simplest indicator that can be used to analyze the structure of a regional trade network is the intra-regional node degree (IND i ),Footnote 13 that is the number of regional partner countries of each country i, which can be expressed in absolute terms, or as an intra-regional density index (IDI i ), that is as a ratio of the total number of possible regional partner countries (n − 1):

$$ {IDI}_i={IND}_i/\left( n{\textstyle\ \hbox{--}\ }1\right) $$
(15.8)

The intra-regional density index can be computed also for the entire region r, where it measures to what extent the actual number of trade linkages corresponds to its maximum potential level:

$$ {IDI}_r={\varSigma}_i{IND}_i/\left[ n\left( n{\textstyle\ \hbox{--}\ }1\right)\right] $$
(15.9)

The density of a regional trade network can be compared with a pre-defined external benchmark area o that can be a set of other regions or the rest of the world made of m countries. Denoting with END i the extra-regional node degree, that is the number of country i’s trading partners located in the external benchmark, a relative intra-regional density index (RIDI i ) can be defined as:

$$ {RIDI}_i=\left({IDI}_i{\textstyle\ \hbox{--}\ }{EDI}_i\right)/\left({IDI}_i+{EDI}_i\right) $$
(15.10)

where: EDI i = END i /m

RIDI i ranges between −1 and 1and is equal to zero if IDI i = EDI i (geographic neutrality). At the regional level:

$$ {RIDI}_r=\left({IDI}_r{\textstyle\ \hbox{--}\ }{EDI}_r\right)/\left({IDI}_r+{EDI}_r\right) $$
(15.11)

where: EDI r = Σ i END i /(n∙m)

Another indicator frequently used in the BNA of the world trade network is the average nearest neighbor degree (ANND i ), which is simply the average node degree of country i’s partners. In our context, to reduce the complexity of notation, we will replace the phrase nearest neighbor with partner, and define an intra-regional average partner degree (IAPD i ) as follows:

$$ {\mathbf{IAPD}}_{\mathbf{i}}\kern0.28em =\kern0.28em \left({\boldsymbol{A}}_{\left(\mathbf{i}\right)}\cdot \boldsymbol{A}\cdot \mathbf{1}\right)/{\mathbf{IND}}_{\mathbf{i}} $$
(15.12)

where A (i) is the ith row of the adjacency matrix A describing the network and 1 is a unitary vector. The maximum level of IAPD i is reached when all country i’s regional partners’ IDI j are equal to one, that is when all the possible n(n − 1) trade linkages exist. This allows us to define an average intra-regional partner density index (IPDI i ) as follows:

$$ {IPDI}_i={IAPD}_i/\left( n{\textstyle\ \hbox{--}\ }1\right) $$
(15.13)

At the regional level IAPD r and IPDI r can simply be computed as the averages of the corresponding country indicators.

An extra-regional average partner degree (EAPD i ) and an extra-regional partner density index (EPDI i ) can be defined as follows:

$$ {EAPD}_i=\left({\boldsymbol{EA}}_{(i)}\cdot \boldsymbol{OA}\cdot 1\right)/{END}_i $$
(15.14)
$$ {EPDI}_i={EAPD}_i/\left( m{\textstyle\ \hbox{--}\ }1\right) $$
(15.15)

where EA is the n×m adjacency matrix of linkages between the region’s members and the benchmark area’s countries, and OA is the m × m adjacency matrix of linkages among the benchmark area’s countries.

Finally, a relative intra-regional partner density index (RIPDI i ), ranging from −1 to 1 with a neutrality threshold of zero, can be computed as:

$$ {RIPDI}_i=\left({IPDI}_i{\textstyle\ \hbox{--}\ }{EPDI}_i\right)/\left({IPDI}_i+{EPDI}_i\right) $$
(15.16)

The fact that a country has a certain average partner degree does not necessarily imply that all its partners are connected between each other. In order to capture this feature of the network, a third indicator has been developed, named binary clustering coefficient (BCC i ), aimed at measuring to what extent a country’s partners tend to cluster into triangles, that is to trade between each other. BCC has also been used to detect a possible hierarchic structure of the network.

The intra-regional binary clustering coefficient (IBCC i ) can be defined as:

$$ {IBCC}_i={\left({\boldsymbol{A}}^3\right)}_{i i}/\left[{IND}_i\left({IND}_i-1\right)\right] $$
(15.17)

where (A 3) ii is the i-th entry on the main diagonal of A A A. Given IND i , IBCC i measures the actual number of bilateral linkages between country i′s regional partners, relative to its potential.Footnote 14

Another useful concept is the degree of centrality, which is used to assess to what extent trade linkages tend to concentrate towards one or more hub countries. The maximum degree of centralization is reached in a star network, where only one country is connected with all the others, whereas each of the others is connected only with the center of the network.

Several indicators have been proposed to measure the centrality of a node and the centralization of a network. At the country level, intra-regional node centrality (INC i ) can simply be measured as:

$$ {INC}_i=\left(1{\textstyle\ \hbox{--}\ }{IBCC}_i\right) $$
(15.18)

INC i measures to what extent a country is connected to regional partners that are not connected between each other.

At the network level, an intra-regional centralization index (ICI r ) can be defined as:

$$ {ICI}_r= \max [{INC}_i]={\varSigma}_{\mathsf{i}}( \max [{IND}_i]{\textstyle \text{\ \hbox{--}\ }}{IND}_i)/[(n{\textstyle \text{\ \hbox{--}\ }}1)(n{\textstyle \text{\ \hbox{--}\ }}2)] $$
(15.19)

This indicator measures the network’s actual centralization as a proportion of its theoretical maximum, defined by the number of missing linkages in the corresponding star network, which is equal to (n − 1)(n − 2).Footnote 15

1.3.2 Weighted Network Analysis

The weighted network analysis (WNA) of international trade represents the intensity of linkages among the network nodes through the actual matrix of their bilateral trade flows (W) expressed in absolute or relative terms.Footnote 16

Apart from the difference between the respective matrices, indicators used in WNA are similar to those used in BNA. In our context, node degree is replaced by intra-regional node value (INV i ), which is the value of a country’s total trade with its region. However, since there is no given maximum value for trade, a density index similar to that used in BNA cannot be easily defined, and there are several options to build a normalized INV i .

If we refer to the geographic neutrality criterion mentioned in the text (Sect. 15.3.1), we can introduce intensity and revealed trade preference indices into the context of WNA. Since INV i refers to intra-regional trade, we can define extra-regional node value (ENV i ) as the total value of country i’s trade with the benchmark area, and the density index of BNA can be replaced by a homogeneous (country-size-independent) trade intensity index HI ir . More precisely:

$$ {HI}_{ir}={S}_{ir}/{V}_{or} $$
(15.20)

where:

$$ \begin{array}{l}{S}_{i r}={INV}_i/\left({INV}_i+{ENV}_i\right)\\ {}{V}_{or}={\varSigma}_k{ENV}_k/{\varSigma}_k\left({ENV}_k+{INV}_k\right)\end{array} $$

and k = 1, …, m refers to countries of the benchmark area o.

HI ir is higher (lower) than one if country i’s intra-regional trade share is higher (lower) that the share of region r in the benchmark area’s trade.

In a similar way, a homogeneous extra-regional trade intensity index (HE ir ) can be defined as:

$$ {HE}_{ir}=\left(1{\textstyle\ \hbox{--}\ }{S}_{ir}\right)/\left(1{\textstyle\ \hbox{--}\ }{V}_{or}\right) $$
(15.21)

and finally the relative intra-regional revealed trade preference index (RIRTP ir ) can be computed as:

$$ {RIRTP}_{ir}=\left({HI}_{ir}{\textstyle\ \hbox{--}\ }{HE}_{ir}\right)\left({HI}_{ir}+{HE}_{ir}\right) $$
(15.22)

This index measures unambiguously if intra-regional trade is more or less intense than what implied by the geographic neutrality criterion.

Other WNA indicators can be used to better illustrate the topology of regional trade networks in terms of connectivity and centralization, taking into account not only direct bilateral linkages between a country and its partners, but also linkages among the latter.

Reminding that the importance of a node in a network depends not only on its own degree, but also on the degree of its partners, we can adapt the binary indicator of IAPD i to WNA in several ways.

The first possibility is to compute an intra-regional weighted average partner degree (IWAPD i ) through the following formula:

$$ {IWAPD}_i=\left({\boldsymbol{W}}_{(i)}\boldsymbol{A}1\right)/{INV}_i $$
(15.23)

where W (i) is the i-th row of the weight matrix W.

A similar indicator could be built for extra-regional partners and the two indicators could be compared as for the previous ones. However, IWAPD i , although weighting each partner with its trade value, is still to be considered as a binary indicator, since its unit of measurement remains the number of partners.

A more appropriate WNA equivalent of the binary IAPD i is the intra-regional average partner value (IAPV i ), which is the average value of a country’s regional partners’ intra-regional trade:

$$ {IAPV}_i=\left({\boldsymbol{A}}_{(i)}\boldsymbol{W}1\right)/{IND}_i $$
(15.24)

The maximum level of IAPV i can be defined as follows:

$$ Max{(IAPV)}_i={\varSigma}_k{INV}_k/{IND}_i $$
(15.25)

where k = 1, … IND i are the possible regional partners of country i ranked according to their total trade value. This implies that Σ k INV k necessarily grows less than proportionally than IND i . It is also important to note that, for any given IND, the list of possible partners changes across countries, because it cannot include country i. As a consequence, Max(IAPV) i is negatively related to INV i and will be reached only if the actual regional trade partners of country i happen to be those with the highest total trade value.

This definition allows us to build an intra-regional normalized average partner value (INAPV i ) as the ratio between IAPV i and its maximum.

At the regional level IAPV r and INAPV r can simply be computed as the weighted averages of the corresponding country indicators.

The binary concept of clustering into triangles can easily be adapted to WNA. The intra-regional weighted clustering coefficient (IWCC i ) is defined as follows:

$$ {IWCC}_i={{\left({\boldsymbol{W}}^{\left[1/3\right]}\right)}^3}_{i i}/\left[{IND}_i\left({IND}_i-1\right)\right] $$
(15.26)

where W [1/3] is the matrix obtained by raising each element of the W matrix to 1/3 and (W [1/3])3 ii is the i-th entry on the main diagonal of W [1/3] · W [1/3] · W [1/3]. IWCC i measures the intensity of trade among country i′s regional partners relative to the total number of their potential connections. So, it is positively related to the actual density of these connections (IBCC) and to their intensity.

For any given IND i , the maximum level of IWCC i is not scale-independent. This problem can be solved by dividing each element in the W matrix by their maximum, which results into an intra-regional normalized weighted clustering coefficient (INWCC i ), ranging from 0 to 1:

$$ {INWCC}_i={{\left({\boldsymbol{NW}}^{\left[1/3\right]}\right)}^3}_{i i}/\left[{IND}_i,\left({IND}_i-1\right)\right] $$
(15.27)

where NW is the matrix of trade flows within region r normalized with respect to their maximum.

1.3.3 Assortative Mixing (Homophily) and Trade Regionalization

This application of network analysis is aimed at detecting the degree of regionalization of the world trade network (Iapadre and Plummer 2011), and is based on the weighted equivalent of the binary assortativity coefficient proposed by Newman (2003a, b).

The starting point is a matrix of international trade flows classified by regions, reporting intra-regional trade values on the main diagonal and inter-regional flows in the remaining cells. The resulting intra-regional assortativity coefficient (IAC) is:

$$ \mathbf{I}\mathbf{A}\mathbf{C}=\left(\mathbf{Tr}\left(\boldsymbol{R}\right)\ {\textstyle \mathbf{\hbox{--}}}\ ||{\mathbf{R}}^{\mathbf{2}}||\right)/\left(\mathbf{1}{\textstyle\ \mathbf{\hbox{--}}}\ \left|\right|{\boldsymbol{R}}^{\mathbf{2}}\left|\right|\right) $$

where R is the matrix of intra- and inter-regional trade flows, divided by their total, Tr is the trace operator, and ‖R 2‖ is the sum of all the elements of matrix R 2.

IAC is equal to zero in the case of geographic neutrality, which is when regions trade among each other in proportion to their total trade values, and reaches a maximum value of one in the limiting case of no inter-regional trade. On the other hand, in the limiting case of no intra-regional trade, the minimum (negative) value of IAC is equal to – ‖R 2‖/(1 − ‖R 2‖).Footnote 17

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2017 Springer International Publishing AG

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Iapadre, P.L., Tajoli, L. (2017). Assessing Globalization and Regionalization Through Network Indices. In: De Lombaerde, P., Saucedo Acosta, E. (eds) Indicator-Based Monitoring of Regional Economic Integration. United Nations University Series on Regionalism, vol 13. Springer, Cham. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-319-50860-3_15

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics