Skip to main content

An Investigation of Interregional Trade Network Structures

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
Complex Networks and Dynamics

Abstract

We provide empirical evidence on the network structure of trade flows between European regions and discuss the theoretical underpinning of such a structure. First, we analyze EU regional trade data using Social Network Analysis. We describe the topology of this network and compute local and global centrality measures. Finally, we consider the distribution of higher order statistics, through the analysis of local clustering and main triadic structures in the triad census of interregional trade flows. In the theoretical part, we explore the relationship between trade costs and trade links. As shown by Behrens (J Urban Econ 55(1):68–92, 2004), Behrens (Reg Sci Urban Econ 35(5):471–492, 2005a) and Behrens (J Urban Econ 58(1):24–44, 2005b) in a two-region linear new economic geography (NEG) model, trade costs and the local market size determine, even with finite trade costs, unconditional autarky and unilateral trade, that is, a one-directional flow from one region to the other. Following these contributions and guided by the empirical evidence, we clarify the relationship between market competition, trade costs and the patterns of trade in a three-region NEG model. We identify a larger set of trade network configurations other the three elementary ones that occur at the dyadic level between two regions (no trade, one-way trade, reciprocated two-way trade), and relate the model with the triad census.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

eBook
USD 16.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 16.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    In the NEG literature, Ago et al. (2006), Melitz and Ottaviano (2008) and Behrens (2011) put also forward three-region linear models à la Ottaviano et al. (2002). However, they limit their analysis to specific trade cost structures.

  2. 2.

    The sub-network including links with w > 25 is still weakly connected, but not strongly connected, that is not every vertex r is reachable from every s by a directed walk.

  3. 3.

    Networks with high modularity have dense connections between the nodes within modules but sparse connections between nodes in different modules. We use modularity to detect the community structure of the EU regional trade network. See Newman (2006) on this issue.

  4. 4.

    The degree centrality (C r d) is classified as a local measure of centrality since it takes into consideration only the direct links of a node, its nearest neighborhood, regardless of the position of the node in the network’s structure. Contrary to the local measures, global measures of centrality uncover the effect of others at a higher level of connection, including the direct and the indirect effect of potentially all nodes in the network. In particular, the eigenvector centrality captures the idea that the more central the neighbors of a vertex are, the more central that vertex itself is. In other words, eigenvector centrality gives greater weight to a node the more it is connected to other highly connected nodes. Thus, it is often interpreted as measuring a node’s network importance.

  5. 5.

    A crucial difference between human and, for example, knowledge capital is that the former is embodied into the owner, whereas the second is separated. In a NEG model, this difference enters into play only when factor migration is allowed. When human capital is considered, changes in real incomes alters the migration choice also via the so-called “price index effect” so that changes in local prices may affect the long-run distribution of the industrial sector. Instead, when knowledge capital is concerned, factor movements are only driven by regional nominal profit differentials. A new economic geography (NEG) model in which the mobile factor is human capital (or, alternatively, skilled labor or entrepreneurship) is known as Footloose Entrepreneur (FE) model (developed originally in Forslid and Ottaviano 2003); a NEG model in which the mobile factor is separated from the owner (such as physical or knowledge capital) is labeled Footloose Capital (FC) model (developed firstly in Martin and Rogers 1995). As mentioned above, this distinction becomes relevant moving from the short to the long-run when factor migration is allowed. Even if the basic structure of the model is equivalent for FC and FE models, we consider the factor specific to the M-sector an entrepreneur.

  6. 6.

    A specific configuration could emerge after empirical analysis. We could have, for example, a “hub and spoke” structure by letting: T rs  ≤ T rk  ≤ T sk , with T rs T rk and/or T rk T sk . This would stress the locational advantage of region r (the “hub”) with respect to s and k (the “spokes”).

  7. 7.

    See Behrens (20042005b2011). On the empirical relevance of the zero in the trade flow matrix, see Melitz (2003).

  8. 8.

    Note that analogous expressions can be obtained for s or for k by simple switching r and s or r and k.

  9. 9.

    Notice that the assumption of identical workers population has no significant impact on the short-run analysis and it can be easily removed; whereas in the long run, it determines the regional entrepreneurial shares and, via these shares, the trade flows.

References

  • Ago T, Isono I, Tabuchi T (2006) Locational disadvantage of the hub. Ann Reg Sci 40(4):819–848

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Anderson JE (2011) The gravity model. Ann Rev Econ 3(1):133–160

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Behrens K (2004) Agglomeration without trade: how non-traded goods shape the space-economy. J Urban Econ 55(1):68–92

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Behrens K (2005a) How endogenous asymmetries in interregional market access trigger regional divergence. Reg Sci Urban Econ 35(5):471–492

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Behrens K (2005b) Market size and industry location: traded vs non-traded goods. J Urban Econ 58(1):24–44

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Behrens K (2011) International integration and regional inequalities: how important is national infrastructure? Manch Sch 79(5):952–971

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • De Benedictis L, Tajoli L (2011) The world trade network. World Econ 34(8):1417–1454

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • De Benedictis L, Nenci S, Santoni G, Tajoli L, Vicarelli C (2014) Network analysis of world trade using the BACI-CEPII dataset. Glob Econ J 14(3–4):287–343

    Google Scholar 

  • De Nooy W, Mrvar A, Batagelj V (2011) Exploratory social network analysis with Pajek. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Forslid R, Ottaviano GI (2003) An analytically solvable core-periphery model. J Econ Geogr 3(3):229–240

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Freeman LC (1979) Centrality in social networks conceptual clarification. Soc Networks 1(3):215–239

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hanneman R, Riddle M (2005) Introduction to social network methods. University of California, Riverside, CA. http://faculty.ucr.edu/hanneman/nettext

    Google Scholar 

  • Head K, Mayer T (2014) Gravity equations: workhorse, toolkit, and cookbook. In: Gopinath G, Helpman E, Rogoff K (eds) Handbook of international economics, vol 4. Elsevier, Amsterdam, pp 131–195

    Google Scholar 

  • Holland PW, Leinhardt S (1970) A method for detecting structure in sociometric data. Am J Sociol 76:492–513

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jackson MO (2008) Social and economic networks. Princeton University Press, Princeton

    Google Scholar 

  • Krugman PR (1991) Geography and trade. MIT Press, Cambridge, MA

    Google Scholar 

  • Martin P, Rogers CA (1995) Industrial location and public infrastructure. J Int Econ 39(3):335–351

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Melitz MJ (2003) The impact of trade on intra-industry reallocations and aggregate industry productivity. Econometrica 71(6):1695–1725

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Melitz MJ, Ottaviano GI (2008) Market size, trade, and productivity. Rev Econ Stud 75(1):295–316

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Newman ME (2003) The structure and function of complex networks. SIAM Rev 45(2):167–256

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Newman ME (2006) Modularity and community structure in networks. Proc Natl Acad Sci 103(23):8577–8582

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Okubo T, Picard PM, Thisse J-F (2014) On the impact of competition on trade and firm location. J Reg Sci 54(5):731–754

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ottaviano GI, Tabuchi T, Thisse J-F (2002) Agglomeration and trade revisited. Int Econ Rev 43:409–436

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Thissen M, Diodato D, Van Oort F (2013a) Integrated regional Europe: European regional trade flows in 2000. PBL Netherlands Environmental Assessment Agency, The Hague

    Google Scholar 

  • Thissen M, Van Oort F, Diodato D (2013b) Integration and convergence in regional Europe: European regional trade flows from 2000 to 2010. PBL Netherlands Environmental Assessment Agency, The Hague

    Google Scholar 

  • Thissen M, Lankhuizen M, Jonkeren O (2015) Multi-regional trade data for Europe in 2010. Project for the Institute for Prospective Technological Studies. PBL Netherlands Environmental Assessment Agency, The Hague

    Google Scholar 

  • Wasserman S, Faust K (1994) Social network analysis: methods and applications. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Book  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

This Chapter is based upon work from COST Action ISCH COST Action IS1104 “The EU in the new complex geography of economic systems: models, tools and policy evaluation”, supported by COST (European Cooperation in Science and Technology) www.cost.eu. We also sincerely thank the IPTS (Institute for Prospective Technological Studies) for providing the data on interregional trade in Europe, and an anonymous referee for providing constructive comments and help in improving the contents of this chapter.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Pasquale Commendatore .

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

Appendix

Appendix

See Table 3.

Table 3 Regional NUTS-2 classification

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2016 Springer International Publishing Switzerland

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Basile, R., Commendatore, P., De Benedictis, L., Kubin, I. (2016). An Investigation of Interregional Trade Network Structures. In: Commendatore, P., Matilla-García, M., Varela, L., Cánovas, J. (eds) Complex Networks and Dynamics. Lecture Notes in Economics and Mathematical Systems, vol 683. Springer, Cham. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-319-40803-3_6

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics