Skip to main content

Resource Economics

  • Living reference work entry
  • First Online:
Handbook of Dynamic Game Theory
  • 670 Accesses

Abstract

This chapter provides a selective survey of dynamic game models of exploitation of natural resources. It covers both renewable resources and exhaustible resources. In relation to earlier surveys (Long, A survey of dynamic games in economics, World Scientific, Singapore, 2010; Long, Dyn Games Appl 1(1):115–148, 2011), the present work includes many references to new developments that appeared after January 2011 and additional suggestions for future research. Moreover, there is a greater emphasis on intuitive explanation.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    For a review of the game theoretic approach to water resources, see Dinar and Hogarth (2015). For some recent models of differential games involving water transfer between two countries, see Cabo et al. (2014) and in particular Cabo and Tidball (2016) where countries cooperate in the infrastructure investment stage but play a noncooperative game of water transfer in a second stage. Cabo and Tidball (2016) design a time-consistent imputation distribution procedure to ensure cooperation, along the lines of Jørgensen and Zaccour (2001).

  2. 2.

    Dictionnaire LE ROBERT, Société du Nouveau Littré, Paris: 1979.

  3. 3.

    However, as pointed out by Ostrom (1990), in some societies, thanks to good institutions, the commons are efficiently managed.

  4. 4.

    See Fudenberg and Tirole (1991) on the comparison of the concepts of open-loop equilibrium and feedback or Markov-perfect equilibrium.

  5. 5.

    It has been estimated that about 80 % of fish stocks are exploited at or beyond their maximum sustainable yields. See FAO (2009).

  6. 6.

    We assume that the upper bound constraint on effort is not binding at the steady state.

  7. 7.

    If the amount harvested depends only on the effort level and not on the level of the stock, i.e., h i  = γ L i , then in an open-loop equilibrium, there is no dynamic overcrowding production externality. In that case, it is possible that open-loop exploitation is Pareto efficient; see Chiarella et al. (1984).

  8. 8.

    The farsightedness concept was formalized in Greenberg (1990) and Chwe (1994) and has been applied to the literature on public goods (Ray and Vohra 2001) and international environmental agreements (de Zeeuw 2008; Diamantoudi and Sartzetakis 2015).

  9. 9.

    For ownership risks, see Bohn and Deacon (2000).

  10. 10.

    In contrast, in the standard models, where all utility functions are concave, it can be shown that the equilibrium trajectory of the state variable must eventually become monotone. See Dutta and Sundaram (1993b).

  11. 11.

    Sundaram and Dutta (1993b) extend this “no tragedy” result to the case with mild discounting: as long as the discount rate is low enough, if players use discontinuous strategies that threaten to make a drastic increase in consumption when the stock falls below a certain level, they may be able to lock each other into a stock level that is dynamically inefficient and greater than the cooperative steady state.

  12. 12.

    Except possibly the cooperative steady state (Dutta and Sundaram 1993b, Theorem 3).

  13. 13.

    Dockner and Sorger (1996), Lemma 1.

  14. 14.

    Dockner and Long (1993) find similar results in a pollution game.

  15. 15.

    Efficiency can also be ensured if players can resort to trigger strategies, see Cave (1987) and Benhabib and Radner (1992), or if there exist countervailing externalities, as in Martin and Rincón-Zapareto (2005).

  16. 16.

    See e.g. Fudenberg and Levine (20062012).

  17. 17.

    See Salo and Tahvonen (2001) for the modeling of economic exhaustion in a duopoly.

  18. 18.

    See Gaudet (2007) for the theory and empirics related to the Hotelling Rule.

  19. 19.

    For a proof of the time inconsistency of open-loop Stackelberg equilibrium, see, for example, Dockner et al. (2000), or Long (2010).

  20. 20.

    See also Lewis and Schmalensee (1980).

  21. 21.

    This corresponds to the result that, in a closed economy, the market power of an oil monopolist with zero extraction cost disappears when the elasticity of demand is constant. See, e.g., Stiglitz (1976).

  22. 22.

    This is confirmed in Brander and Djajic (1983), who consider a two-country world in which both countries use oil to produce a consumption good, but only one of them is endowed with oil.

  23. 23.

    See also Karp (1984) and Maskin and Newbery (1990) for the time-inconsistency issue.

  24. 24.

    For discussions of the concept of global feedback Stackelberg equilibrium, see Basar and Olsder (1982) and Long and Sorger (2010). An alternative notion is the stagewise Stackelberg leadership, which will be explained in more detail in Sect. 3.3 below.

  25. 25.

    In a stagewise Stackelberg equilibrium, no commitment of any significant length is possible. The leader can only commit to the current period decision.

  26. 26.

    This result is confirmed by Rubio and Estriche (2001) who modify the model of Tahvonen (1996) by assuming that the per-unit extraction cost in period t is c × (S(0) − S(t)), where c is a positive parameter.

  27. 27.

    Dasgupta and Heal (1979, Ch. 12) consider the open-loop Nash equilibrium of a similar seepage problem, with just two firms, and reach similar results.

  28. 28.

    Sinn (1984) considers a different concept of equilibrium in the seepage model: each firm is committed to achieve a given time path of its stock.

  29. 29.

    Bolle (1980) obtains a similar result, assuming that there is only one common stock that all m firms have equal access.

  30. 30.

    The case of open-loop Nash equilibrium was addressed by Kolstad (1994) and Keutiben (2014).

  31. 31.

    This is related to the so-called SLOSS debate in ecology, in which authors disagree as to whether a single large or several small (SLOSS) reserves would be better for conservation.

  32. 32.

    Myerson and Weibull (2015) formalize the idea that “social conventions usually develop so that people tend to disregard alternatives outside the convention.”

  33. 33.

    For a sample of papers that deal with evolutionary dynamics, see Bala and Long (2005), ?, and Sethi and Somanathan (1996).

References

  • Alvarez-Cuadrado F, Long NV (2011) Relative consumption and renewable resource extraction under alternative property rights regimes. Resour Energy Econ 33(4):1028–1053

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Amir R (1987) Games of resource extraction: existence of Nash equilibrium. Cowles Foundation Discussion Paper No. 825

    Google Scholar 

  • Amir R (1989) A Lattice-theoretic approach to a class of dynamic games. Comput Math Appl 17:1345–1349

    Article  MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

  • Bala V, Long NV (2005) International trade and cultural diversity with preference selection. Eur J Polit Econ 21(1):143–162

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Basar T, Olsder GJ (1982) Dynamic non-cooperative game theory. Academic, London

    MATH  Google Scholar 

  • Behringer S, Upmann T (2014) Optimal harvesting of a spatial renewable resource. J Econ Dyn Control 42:105–120

    Article  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  • Benchekroun H (2008) Comparative dynamics in a productive asset oligopoly. J Econ Theory 138:237–261

    Article  MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

  • Benchekroun H, Halsema A, Withagen C (2009) On non-renewable resource oligopolies: the asymmetric case. J Econ Dyn Control 33(11):1867–1879

    Article  MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

  • Benchekroun H, Halsema A, Withagen C (2010) When additional resource stocks reduce welfare. J Environ Econ Manag 59(1):109–114

    Article  MATH  Google Scholar 

  • Benchekroun H, Gaudet G, Lohoues H (2014) Some effects of asymmetries in a common pool natural resource oligopoly. Strateg Behav Environ 3:213–235

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Benchekroun H, Gaudet G (2015) On the effects of mergers on equilibrium outcomes in a common property renewable asset oligopoly. J Econ Dyn Control 52:209–223

    Article  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  • Benchekroun H, Long NV (2006) The curse of windfall gains in a non-renewable resource oligopoly. Aust Econ Pap 45(2):99–105

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Benchekroun H, Long NV (2016) Status concern and the exploitation of common pool renewable resources. Ecol Econ 125(C):70–82

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Benchekroun H, Withagen C (2012) On price-taking behavior in a non-renewable resource Cartel-Fringe game. Games Econ Bahav 76(2):355–374

    Article  MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

  • Benhabib J, Radner R (1992) The joint exploitation of a productive asset: a game-theoretic approach. Econ Theory 2:155–190

    Article  MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

  • Bergstrom T (1982) On capturing oil rents with a national excise tax. Am Econ Rev 72(1):194–201

    Google Scholar 

  • Bohn H, Deacon RT (2000) Ownership risk, investment, and the use of natural resources. Am Econ Rev 90(3):526–549

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bolle F (1980) The efficient use of a non-renewable common-pool resource is possible but unlikely. Zeitschrift für Nationalökonomie 40:391–397

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brander J, Djajic S (1983) Rent-extracting tariffs and the management of exhaustible resources. Canad J Econ 16:288–298

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Breton M, Keoula MY (2012) Farsightedness in a coalitional great fish war. Environ Resour Econ 51(2):297–315

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Breton M, Sbragia L, Zaccour G (2010) A dynamic model of international environmental agreements. Environ Resour Econ 45:25–48

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cabo F, Tidball M (2016) Promotion of cooperation when benefits come in the future: a water transfer case. Resour Energy Econ (to appear)

    Google Scholar 

  • Cabo F, Erdlenbruch K, Tidball M (2014) Dynamic management of water transfer between two interconnected river basins. Resour Energy Econ 37:17–38

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cave J (1987) Long-term competition in a dynamic game: the Cold Fish War. Rand J Econ 18: 596–610

    Article  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  • Chiarella C, Kemp MC, Long NV, Okuguchi K (1984) On the economics of international fisheries. Int Econ Rev 25 (1):85–92

    Article  MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

  • Chichilnisky G (1996) An axiomatic approach to sustainable development. Soc Choice Welf 13:231–257

    Article  MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

  • Chou S, Long NV (2009) Optimal tariffs on exhaustible resources in the presence of Cartel behavior. Asia-Pac J Account Econ 16(3):239–254

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chwe M (1994) Farsighted coalitional stability. J Econ Theory 63:299–325

    Article  MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

  • Clark CW (1990) Mathematical bioeconomics. Wiley, New York

    MATH  Google Scholar 

  • Clark CW, Munro G (1990) The economics of fishing and modern capital theory. J Environ Econ Manag 2:92–106

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Clemhout S, Wan H Jr (1985) Dynamic common property resources and environmental problems. J Optim Theory Appl 46:471–481

    Article  MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

  • Clemhout S, Wan H Jr (1991) Environmental problems as a common property resource game. In: Hamalainen RP, Ehtamo HK (eds) Dynamic games and economic analyses. Springer, Berlin, pp 132–154

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Clemhout S, Wan H Jr (1995) The non-uniqueness of Markovian strategy equilibrium: the case of continuous time models for non-renewable resources. In: Paper presented at the 5th international symposium on dynamic games and applications, Grimentz

    Google Scholar 

  • Colombo L, Labrecciosa P (2013a) Oligopoly exploitation of a private property productive asset. J Econ Dyn Control 37(4):838–853

    Article  MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

  • Colombo L, Labrecciosa P (2013b) On the convergence to the Cournot equilibrium in a productive asset oligopoly. J Math Econ 49(6):441–445

    Article  MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

  • Colombo L, Labrecciosa P (2015) On the Markovian efficiency of Bertrand and Cournot equilibria. J Econ Theory 155:332–358

    Article  MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

  • Cornes R, Long NV, Shimomura K (2001) Drugs and pests: intertemporal production externalities. Jpn World Econ 13(3):255–278

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Couttenier M, Soubeyran R (2014) Drought and civil war in Sub-Saharan Africa. Econ J 124(575):201–244

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Couttenier M, Soubeyran R (2015) A survey of causes of civil conflicts: natural factors and economic conditions. Revue d’Economie Politique 125(6):787–810

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Crabbé P, Long NV (1993) Entry deterrence and overexploitation of the fishery. J Econ Dyn Control 17(4):679–704

    Article  MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

  • Dasgupta PS, Heal GM (1979) Economic theory and exhaustible resources. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    MATH  Google Scholar 

  • Dawkins R, Krebs J (1979) Arms races between and within species. Proc R Soc Lond Ser B 10:489–511

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • de Frutos J, Martín-Herrán G (2015) Does flexibility facilitate sustainability of cooperation over time? A case study from environmental economics. J Optim Theory Appl 165(2):657–677

    Article  MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

  • Deacon R, Bohn H (2000) Ownership risk, investment, and the use of natural resources. Am Econ Rev 90(3):526–549

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • de Zeeuw A (2008) Dynamic effects on the stability of international environmental agreements. J Environ Econ Manag 55:163–174

    Article  MATH  Google Scholar 

  • Diamantoudi F, Sartzetakis E (2015) International environmental agreements: coordinated action under foresight. Econ Theory 59(3):527–546

    Article  MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

  • Dinar A, Hogarth M (2015) Game theory and water resources: critical review of its contributions, progress, and remaining challenges. Found Trends Microecon 11(1–2):1–139

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dinar A, Zaccour G (2013) Strategic behavior and environmental commons. Environ Develop Econ 18(1):1–5

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dockner E, Long NV (1993) International pollution control: cooperative versus non-cooperative strategies. J Environ Econ Manag 24:13–29

    Article  MATH  Google Scholar 

  • Dockner E, Sorger G (1996) Existence and properties of equilibria for a dynamic game on productive assets. J Econ Theory 71:209–227

    Article  MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

  • Dockner E, Feichtinger G, Mehlmann A (1989) Noncooperative solution for a differential game model of fishery. J Econ Dyn Control 13:11–20

    Article  MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

  • Dockner ESJ, Long NV, Sorger G (2000) Differential games in economics and management science. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Book  MATH  Google Scholar 

  • Dutta PK, Sundaram RK (1993a) How different can strategic model be? J Econ Theory 60:42–91

    Article  MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

  • Dutta PK, Sundaram RK (1993b) The tragedies of the commons? Econ Theory 3:413–426

    Article  MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

  • Fesselmeyer E, Santugini M (2013) Strategic exploitation of a common resource under environmental risk. J Econ Dyn Control 37(1):125–136

    Article  MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

  • Food and Agriculture Organization (FAO) (2009) The state of world fisheries and aquaculture 2008. FAO Fisheries and Aquaculture Department, Food and Agriculture Organization of the United Nations, Rome

    Google Scholar 

  • Frey BS, Stutzer A (2007) Economics and psychology. MIT Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Fudenberg D, Levine DK (2006) A dual-self model of impulse control. Am Econ Rev 96: 1449–1476

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fudenberg D, Levine DK (2012) Timing and self control. Econometrica 80(1):1–42

    Article  MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

  • Fudenberg D, Tirole J (1991) Game theory. MIT Press, Cambridge

    MATH  Google Scholar 

  • Fujiwara K (2011) Losses from competition in a dynamic game model of renewable resource oligopoly. Resour Energy Econ 33(1):1–11

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fujiwara K, Long NV (2011) Welfare implications of leadership in a resource market under bilateral monopoly. Dyn Games Appl 1(4):479–497

    Article  MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

  • Fujiwara K, Long NV (2012) Optimal tariffs on exhaustible resources: the case of quantity setting. Int Game Theory Rev 14(04):124004-1-21

    Google Scholar 

  • Gaudet G (2007) Natural resource economics under the rule of hotelling. Canad J Econ 40(4):1033–1059

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gaudet G, Lohoues H (2008) On limits to the use of linear Markov strategies in common property natural resource games. Environ Model Assess 13:567–574

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gaudet G, Long NV (1994) On the effects of the distribution of initial endowments in a non-renewable resource duopoly. J Econ Dyn Control 18:1189–1198

    Article  MATH  Google Scholar 

  • Grafton Q, Kompas T, Long NV (2016) A brave new world? Interaction among Kantians and Nashians, and the dynamic of climate change mitigation. In: Paper presented at the Tinbergen Institute conference on climate change, Amsterdam

    Google Scholar 

  • Greenberg J (1990) The theory of social situations: an alternative game-theoretic approach. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Book  MATH  Google Scholar 

  • Gilbert R (1978) Dominant firm pricing policy in a market for an exhaustible resource. Bell J Econ 9(2):385–395

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Groot F, Withagen C, de Zeeuw A (2003) Strong time-consistency in a Cartel-versus-Fringe model. J Econ Dyn Control 28:287–306

    Article  MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

  • Hardin G (1968) The tragedy of the commons. Science 162:1240–1248

    Google Scholar 

  • Haurie M, Tavoni BC, van der Zwaan C (2011) Modelling uncertainty and the climate change: recommendations for robust energy policy. Environ Model Assess 17:1–5

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Heal G (2009) The economics of climate change: a post-stern perspective. Clim Change 96: 275–297

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Herrmann M, Gaudet G (2009) The economic dynamics of antibiotic efficacy under open access. J Environ Econ Manag 57:334–350

    Article  MATH  Google Scholar 

  • Hoel M (1978) Resource extraction, substitute production, and monopoly. J Econ Theory 19(1): 28–37

    Article  MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

  • Hoel M (2011) The supply side of CO 2 with country heterogeneity. Scand J Econ 113(4):846–865

    Article  MATH  Google Scholar 

  • Jørgensen S, Yeung DWK (1996) Stochastic differential game model of common property fishery. J Optim Theory Appl 90(2):381–404

    Article  MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

  • Jørgensen S, Zaccour G (2001) Time consistent side payments in a dynamic game of downstream pollution. J Econ Dyn Control 25:1973–87

    Article  MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

  • Kagan M, van der Ploeg F, Withagen C (2015) Battle for climate and scarcity rents: beyond the linear-quadratic case. Dyn Games Appl 5(4):493–522

    Article  MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

  • Kahneman D, Tversky A (1984) Choices, values and frames. Am Psychol 39:341–350

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kaitala V, Hamalainen RP, Ruusunen J (1985) On the analysis of equilibria and bargaining in a fishery game. In: Feichtinger G (ed) Optimal control theory and economic analysis II. North Holland, Amsterdam, pp 593–606

    Google Scholar 

  • Karp L (1984) Optimality and consistency in a differential game with non-renewable resources. J Econ Dyn Control 8:73–97

    Article  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  • Karp L, Newbery D (1991) Optimal tariff on exhaustible resources. J Int Econ 30:285–99

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Karp L, Newbery D (1992) Dynamically consistent oil import tariffs. Canad J Econ 25:1–21

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Katayma S, Long NV (2010) A dynamic game of status-seeking with public capital and an exhaustible resource. Opt Control Appl Methods 31:43–53

    MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

  • Katayama S, Long NV, Ohta H (2014) Carbon tax and comparison of trading regimes in fossil fuels. In: Semmler W, Tragler G, Verliov V (eds) Dynamics optimization in environmental economics. Springer, Berlin, pp 287–314

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Kemp MC, Long NV (1979) The interaction between resource-poor and resource-rich economies. Aust Econ Pap 18:258–267

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kemp MC, Long NV (1980) Exhaustible resources, optimality, and trade. North Holland, Amsterdam

    Google Scholar 

  • Kemp MC, Long NV (1984) Essays in the economics of exhaustible resources. North Holland, Amsterdam

    Google Scholar 

  • Keutiben O (2014) On capturing foreign oil rents. Resour Energy Econ 36(2):542–555

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Khalatbary F (1977) Market imperfections and the optimal rate of depletion of natural resources. Economica 44:409–14

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kolstad CD (1994) Hotelling rents in hotelling space: product differentiation in exhaustible resource markets. J Environ Econ Manag 26:163–180

    Article  MATH  Google Scholar 

  • Krugman P, Obstfeld M, Melitz M (2015) International economics: theory and policy, 10th edn. Pearson, Boston

    Google Scholar 

  • Kwon OS (2006) Partial coordination in the Great Fish War. Environ Resour Econ 33:463–483

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lahiri S, Ono Y (1988) Helping minor firms reduce welfare. Econ J 98:1199–1202

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lambertini L, Mantovani A (2014) Feedback equilibria in a dynamic renewable resource oligopoly: pre-emption, voracity and exhaustion. J Econ Dyn Control 47:115–122

    Article  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  • Laurent-Lucchetti J, Santugini M (2012) Ownership risk and the use of common-pool natural resources. J Environ Econ Manag 63:242–259

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Levhari D, Mirman L (1980) The great fish war: an example using a dynamic Cournot Nash solution. Bell J Econ 11:322–334

    Article  MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

  • Lewis T, Schmalensee R (1980) On oligopolistic markets for nonrenewable natural resources. Q J Econ 95:471–5

    Article  MATH  Google Scholar 

  • Liski M, Tahvonen O (2004) Can carbon tax eat OPEC’s rents? J Environ Econ Manag 47:1–12

    Article  MATH  Google Scholar 

  • Long NV (1975) Resource extraction under the uncertainty about possible nationalization. J Econ Theory 10(1):42–53

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Long NV (1977) Optimal exploitation and replenishment of a natural resource. Essay 4 in Pitchford JD, Turnovsky SJ (eds) Applications of control theory to economic analysis. North-Holland, Amsterdam, pp 81–106

    Google Scholar 

  • Long NV (1994) On optimal enclosure and optimal timing of enclosure. Econ Rec 70(221): 141–145

    Google Scholar 

  • Long NV (2010) A survey of dynamic games in economics. World Scientific, Singapore

    Book  MATH  Google Scholar 

  • Long NV (2011) Dynamic games in the economics of natural resources: a survey. Dyn Games Appl 1(1):115–148

    Article  MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

  • Long NV (2015a) Kant-Nash equilibrium in a dynamic game of climate change mitigations. In: Paper presented at the CESifo area conference on climate and energy, Oct 2015 (CESifo), Munich

    Google Scholar 

  • Long NV (2015b) The green paradox in open economies: lessons from static and dynamic models. Rev Environ Econ Policies 9(2):266–285

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Long NV (2016a) Kant-Nash equilibrium in a quantity-setting oligopoly. In: von Mouche P, Quartieri F (eds) Contributions on equilibrium theory for Cournot oligopolies and related games: essays in Honour of Koji Okuguchi. Springer, Berlin, pp 171–192

    Google Scholar 

  • Long NV (2016b) Mixed-strategy Kant-Nash equilibria in games of voluntary contributions to a public good. In: Buchholz W, Ruebbelke D (eds) The theory of externalities and public goods. Springer

    Google Scholar 

  • Long NV, McWhinnie S (2012) The tragedy of the commons in a fishery when relative performance matters. Ecol Econ 81:140–154

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Long NV, Sorger G (2006) Insecure property rights and growth: the roles of appropriation costs, wealth effects, and heterogeneity. Econ Theory 28(3):513–529

    Article  MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

  • Long NV, Sorger G (2010) A dynamic principal-agent problem as a feedback Stackelberg differential game. Central Eur J Oper Res 18(4):491–509

    Article  MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

  • Long NV, Soubeyran A (2001) Cost manipulation games in oligopoly, with cost of manipulating. Int Econ Rev 42(2):505–533

    Article  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  • Long NV, Staehler F (2014) General equilibrium effects of green technological progress. CIRANO working paper 2014s-16. CIRANO, Montreal

    Google Scholar 

  • Long NV, Wang S (2009) Resource grabbing by status-conscious agents. J Dev Econ 89(1):39–50

    Article  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  • Long NV, Prieur F, Puzon K, Tidball M (2014) Markov perfect equilibria in differential games with regime switching strategies. CESifo working paper 4662. CESifo Group, Munich

    Google Scholar 

  • Loury GC (1986) A theory of oligopoly: Cournot equilibrium in exhaustible resource market with fixed supplies. Int Econ Rev 27(2):285–301

    Article  MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

  • Martin-Herrán G, Rincón-Zapareto J (2005) Efficient Markov-perfect Nash equilibria: theory and application to dynamic fishery games. J Econ Dyn Control 29:1073–96

    Article  MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

  • Maskin E, Newbery D (1990) Disadvantageous oil tariffs and dynamic consistency. Am Econ Rev 80(1):143–156

    Google Scholar 

  • McDonald SL (1971) Petroleum conservation in the United States: an economic analysis. Johns Hopkins Press, Baltimore

    Google Scholar 

  • McMillan J, H-W Sinn (1984) Oligopolistic extraction of a common property resource: dynamic equilibria. In: Kemp MC, Long NV (eds) Essays in the economics of exhaustible resources. North Holland, Amsterdam, pp 199–214

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • McWhinnie SF (2009) The tragedy of the commons in international fisheries: an empirical investigation. J Environ Econ Manag 57:312–333

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mirman L, Santugini M (2014) Strategic exploitation of a common-property resource under rational learning about its reproduction. Dyn Games Appl 4(1):58–72

    Article  MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

  • Myerson R, Weibull J (2015) Tenable strategy blocks and settled equilibria. Econometrica 83(3):943–976

    Article  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  • Ostrom E (1990) Governing the commons: the evolution of institutions for collective actions. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Ray D, Vohra R (2001) Coalitional power and public goods. J Polit Econ 109(6):1355–1384

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Roemer JE (2010) Kantian equilibrium. Scand J Econ 112(1):1–24

    Article  MATH  Google Scholar 

  • Roemer JE (2015) Kantian optimization: a microfoundation for cooperation. J Public Econ 127: 45–57

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rubio SJ (2011) On capturing rent from non-renewable resource international monopoly: prices versus quantities. Dyn Games Appl 1(4):558–580

    Article  MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

  • Rubio SJ, Estriche L (2001) Strategic Pigouvian taxation, stock externalities and polluting non-renewable resources. J Public Econ 79(2):297–313

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Russell B (1945) A history of western philosophy. George Allen and Unwin, London

    Google Scholar 

  • Salant S (1976) Exhaustible resources and industrial structure: a Nash-Cournot approach to the World oil market. J Polit Econ 84:1079–94

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Salant S, Switzer S, Reynolds R (1983) Losses from horizontal merger: the effects of an exogenous change in industry structure on Cournot Nash equilibrium. Q J Econ 98(2):185–199

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Salo S, Tahvonen O (2001) Oligopoly equilibria in nonrenewable resource markets. J Econ Dyn Control 25:671–702

    Article  MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

  • Sethi R, Somanathan E (1996) The evolution of social norms in common property resource use. Am Econ Rev 86(4):766–88

    Google Scholar 

  • Sidgwick H (1874) The method of ethics, 7th edn. 1907. Macmillan, London. Reprinted by the Hackett Publishing Company (1981)

    Google Scholar 

  • Sinn H-W (1984) Common property resources, storage facilities, and ownership structure: a Cournot model of the oil market. Economica 51:235–52

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Smith A (1776) An inquiry into the nature and causes of the wealth of nations. In: Cannan E (ed) The modern library, 1937. Random House, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Smith A (1790) The theory of moral sentiments. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, UK. Republished in the series Cambridge texts in the history of philosophy, 2002. Edited by K. Haakonssen

    Google Scholar 

  • Stiglitz JE (1976) Monopoly power and the rate of extraction of exhaustible resources. Am Econ Rev 66:655–661

    Google Scholar 

  • Sundaram RK (1989) Perfect equilibria in non-randomized strategies in a class of symmetric games. J Econ Theory 47:153–177

    Article  MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

  • Tahvonen O (1996) Trade with polluting non-renewable resources. J Environ Econ Manag 30:1–17

    Article  MATH  Google Scholar 

  • Tornell A (1997) Economic growth and decline with endogenous property rights. J Econ Growth 2(3):219–257

    Article  MATH  Google Scholar 

  • Tornell A, Lane P (1999) The voracity effect. Am Econ Rev 89:22–46

    Article  MATH  Google Scholar 

  • Ulph A, Folie GM (1980) Exhaustible resources and Cartels: an intertemporal Nash-Cournot model. Canad J Econ 13:645–58

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • van der Meijden KR, Withagen C (2016) Double limit pricing. In: Paper presented at the 11th Tinbergen Institute conference on climate change, Amsterdam

    Google Scholar 

  • van der Ploeg R (2010) Rapacious resource depletion, excessive investment and insecure property rights. CESifo working paper no 2981, University of Munich

    Google Scholar 

  • Veblen TB (1899) The theory of the Leisure class: an economic study of institutions. Modern Library, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Watkins GC (1977) Conservation and economic efficiency: Alberta oil proration. J Environ Econ Manag 4:40–56

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wirl F (1994) Pigouvian taxation of energy for flow and stock externalities and strategic non-competitive energy pricing. J Environ Econ Manag 26:1–18

    Article  MATH  Google Scholar 

  • World Trade Organization (2010) World trade report, 2010, Washington, DC

    Book  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Ngo Van Long .

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

Section Editor information

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2016 Springer International Publishing AG

About this entry

Cite this entry

Long, N. (2016). Resource Economics. In: Basar, T., Zaccour, G. (eds) Handbook of Dynamic Game Theory. Springer, Cham. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-319-27335-8_15-1

Download citation

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-319-27335-8_15-1

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Publisher Name: Springer, Cham

  • Online ISBN: 978-3-319-27335-8

  • eBook Packages: Springer Reference Religion and PhilosophyReference Module Humanities and Social SciencesReference Module Humanities

Publish with us

Policies and ethics