Skip to main content
Log in

Revenue and welfare effects of financial sector VAT exemption

  • Policy Watch
  • Published:
International Tax and Public Finance Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This paper provides an analysis of revenue and welfare effects associated with a VAT exemption of financial services, which is common among OECD countries. We follow a general equilibrium approach that considers effects of repealing the VAT exemption not only on consumer demand and intermediate-input demand for financial services, but takes account also of the VAT distortion of labor supply. We derive formal expressions for revenue and welfare effects, which can be quantified with a minimum of information about behavioral effects. Using VAT statistics as well as national accounts, we provide quantitative estimates of the effects of repealing the VAT exemption in Germany. Our baseline estimate indicates that tax revenues would increase by some €1.7 billion or 1.3 % of VAT revenues (excluding import turnover tax). Provided these revenue gains are used to finance a reduction in the VAT rate or in other distortive labor taxes our results indicate a modest welfare gain of about €1 billion, or 0.04 % of GDP.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. The statistical offices in the EU use the interbank lending rate as a benchmark to calculate the price for loan and deposit services using the FISIM (Financial Intermediation Services, Indirectly Measured) approach.

  2. \(\sigma_{i} \equiv\frac{q_{i} h_{i}}{y}\) denotes the share of expenses on good i in relation to total household income.

  3. For a discussion, see De la Feria and Lockwood (2010).

  4. Our analysis uses data from the revised system of European National Accounts. Available since 2004/2005, it provides detailed information on the value added of the financial sector. In difference to some of the previous literature, we, therefore, do not need to provide own estimates about the value added of the financial sector.

  5. Intra-EU purchases and imports from third countries are excluded.

  6. The tax rate varies from 0 % (public administration and defense) and 3.34 % (health and social work services) up to 24.23 % (services auxiliary to financial intermediation). Whereas tax rates below the normal rate of 19 % might just reflect the presence of sales subject to reduced rates of 7 %, the figure above 19 % indicates that the figures suffer from some statistical discrepancies.

  7. This rate is not directly comparable to our rate, because it excludes large exempted sectors (education, medical care, public administration, and financial intermediation services themselves) from the calculation of unrecoverable input taxes. Lockwood also notes that the activity classification does not cleanly divide the financial services sector into subsectors subject to VAT and exempt from VAT.

  8. Note that the consumer price change can be specified as \(\widehat{q}_{n} \equiv\frac{q'_{n}-q_{n}}{q_{n}} = (1+\tau ) \widehat{p}_{n} + \tau\).

References

  • Auerbach, A. J., & Gordon, R. H. (2002). Taxation of financial services under a VAT. The American Economic Review, 92(2), 411–416. Papers and proceedings of the one Hundred fourteenth annual meeting of the American Economic Association.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chen, D. (1999). World consumption economics. Singapore: World Scientific.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • De la Feria, R., & Lockwood, B. (2010). Opting for opting-in? An evaluation of the European commission’s proposals for reforming VAT on financial services. Fiscal Studies 31(2), 171–202.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Genser, B., & Winker, P. (1997). Measuring the fiscal revenue loss of VAT exemption in commercial banking. Finanzarchiv, 54, 563–585.

    Google Scholar 

  • Goulder, L. H., & Williams, R. C. (2003). The substantial bias from ignoring general equilibrium effects in estimating excess burden, and a practical solution. Journal of Political Economy, 111(4), 898–927.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Grubert, H., & Mackie, J. (1999). Must financial services be taxed under a consumption tax? National Tax Journal, 53, 23–40.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hines, J. R. Jr. (1999). Three sides of Harberger triangles. The Journal of Economic Perspectives, 13(2), 167–188.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Huizinga, H. (2002). A European VAT on financial services? Economic Policy, 17(35), 497–534.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • International Monetary Fund (2010). A fair and substantial contribution by the financial sector: final report for the G-20. http://www.imf.org/external/np/g20/pdf/062710b.pdf.

  • Keane, M. P. (2011). Labor supply and taxes: a survey. Journal of Economic Literature, 49(4), 961–1075.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lockwood, B. (2011). Estimates from national accounts data of the revenue effect of imposing VAT on currently exempt sales of financial services companies in the EU. In How the EU VAT exemptions impact the banking sector. PWC-Study. http://www.pwc.com/en_GX/gx/financial-services/pdf/2011-10-18_VAT_Study_final_report.pdf.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lockwood, B. (2012). How should financial intermediation services be taxed? Mimeo.

  • Mirrlees, J., et al. (2011). Mirrlees review—tax by design. http://www.ifs.org.uk/mirrleesReview/design.

  • OECD (2008). Taxing wages 2006/2007. Paris.

  • Statistisches Bundesamt (2009). Umsatzsteuerstatistik 2007, Tabelle 2.3 der Jahrespublikation, Fachserie 14 Reihe 8 (ohne innergemeinschaftliche Erwerbe). Wiesbaden.

  • Statistisches Bundesamt (2010). Volkswirtschaftliche Gesamtrechnungen, Input-Output-Rechnung 2007, Fachserie 18 Reihe 2. Wiesbaden.

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Thiess Buettner.

Appendix

Appendix

1.1 A.1 Producer price effects of repealing the VAT exemption

With perfect competition, the producer price equals unit cost and obeys

$$\begin{aligned} p_j = \sum_{i=1}^n a_{ij}\bigl(1+ (1-\alpha ) (1-I_j )\tau_i \bigr)p_i+b_j, \end{aligned}$$

where I j =1 if the sector j is subject to tax or zero-rated, and I j =0 if the sector is exempt. Therefore, the producer price of a sector depends on the input prices p i and input coefficients a ij as well as on the tax rates τ i and the input tax refund. b j is the per-unit labor input in sector j, as above the wage rate is set to unity.

For sectors other than n, deductibility ensures that producer prices can be determined without taking account of tax effects. For these sectors, we have

$$p_j = \sum_{i=1}^n a_{ij} p_i + b_j \quad \forall j \neq n. $$

For sector n, before exemption is repealed

$$\begin{aligned} p_n = \sum_{i=1}^{n-1} a_{in} p_i \bigl(1+ (1-\alpha )\tau_i\bigr) + {a}_{nn} p_n + {b}_n. \end{aligned}$$
(15)

This would suggest that taxes on inputs paid by sector n matter for the output price of this sector to the extent that the components are necessary as inputs. Yet, depending on the substitution elasticity, input price effects might be compensated by changes of intermediate input demand. This requires us to allow for changes in the intermediate input coefficients. However, according to the Envelope theorem, the changes in the input quantities sum up to zero, i.e., the changes in the technical input coefficients for intermediate inputs and for labor can be disregarded for small price changes. Therefore, we can use the case with fixed input coefficients as a first approximation. After repealing exemption, the price in sector n is

$$p_n' = \sum_{i=1}^{n} a_{in} p_i' + {b}_n. $$

Using (15), we subtract the price under exemption

$$\begin{aligned} p_n'-p_n = \sum _{i=1}^{n} a_{in} \bigl(p_i' -p_i \bigr) - (1-\alpha ) \sum_{i=1}^{n-1} a_{in} p_i \tau_i . \end{aligned}$$

For sectors jn, we have

$$\begin{aligned} p_j'-p_j = \sum _{i=1}^{n} a_{ij} \bigl(p_i' -p_i \bigr). \end{aligned}$$

Translating into value based input coefficients

$$\begin{aligned} \widehat{p}_1 =& \sum_{i=1}^n \widetilde{a}_{i1}\widehat{p}_i, \\ \vdots& \\ \widehat{p}_{n-1} =& \sum_{i=1}^n \widetilde{a}_{in-1}\widehat{p}_i, \\ \widehat{p}_n =& \sum_{i=1}^{n} \widetilde{a}_{in}\widehat{p}_i - { (1-\alpha )}\sum _{i=1}^{n-1}\widetilde{a}_{in} \tau_i, \end{aligned}$$

with \(\widetilde{a}_{ij}=\frac{a_{ij} p_{i}}{p_{j}}\).

With the transpose of the input-coefficient-matrix (excluding row n and column n)

$$\begin{aligned} \widetilde{\mathsf{A}}^T_{n-1\times n-1}= \left [ \begin{array}{c@{\quad}c@{\quad}c@{\quad}c} \widetilde{a}_{11} & \widetilde{a}_{21} &\cdots & \widetilde{a}_{n-11} \\ \widetilde{a}_{12} & & & \\ \vdots &\ddots & &\vdots \\ \widetilde{a}_{1n-1} &\widetilde{a}_{2n-1} &\cdots &\widetilde{a}_{n-1n-1} \end{array} \right ] \end{aligned}$$

we can solve for the vector of the relative price changes. Rewriting the system of equations of relative price changes for n sectors in vector notation:

$$\begin{aligned} \bigl[ \mathsf{I}_{n-1\times n-1}-\widetilde{\mathsf{A}}^T_{n-1\times n-1} \bigr] \left [ \begin{array}{c} \widehat{p}_1\\ \vdots\\ \widehat{p}_{n-1} \end{array} \right ] - \left [ \begin{array}{c} \widetilde{a}_{n1}\\ \vdots\\ \widetilde{a}_{nn-1} \end{array} \right ] \widehat{p}_n =& 0, \\ \left [ \begin{array}{c} \widehat{p}_1\\ \vdots\\ \widehat{p}_{n} \end{array} \right ] =& - { (1-\alpha )} \sum_{i=1}^{n-1} \widetilde{a}_{in} \tau_i, \end{aligned}$$

where I i×j is a i times j identity matrix.

$$\begin{aligned} &\Leftrightarrow\quad \underbrace{\left [ \begin{array}{c@{\quad}c@{\quad}c@{\quad}c} \mathsf{I}_{n-1\times n-1}-\widetilde{\mathsf{A}}^T_{n-1\times n-1}& & & -\widetilde{a}_{n1} \\ & & & \vdots \\ & & & -\widetilde{a}_{nn-1} \\ -\widetilde{a}_{1n} &\cdots& -\widetilde{a}_{n-1n} & 1-\widetilde{a}_{nn} \\ \end{array} \right ]}_{\widetilde{\mathsf{A}}^T_{n\times n}} \left [ \begin{array}{c} \widehat{p}_1\\ \vdots\\ \widehat{p}_n \end{array} \right ]\\ &\hphantom{\Leftrightarrow\quad}\quad = \left [ \begin{array}{c} 0\\ \vdots\\ 0\\ - { (1-\alpha )} \sum_{i=1}^{n-1}\widetilde{a}_{in}\tau_i \end{array} \right ], \end{aligned}$$

where the first set of equations above represent rows 1 to n−1 of the above system—the last equation represents row n. Solving for the vector of relative price changes:

$$\begin{aligned} \Leftrightarrow \quad \left [ \begin{array}{c} \widehat{p}_1\\ \vdots\\ \widehat{p}_n \end{array} \right ] = \bigl(\mathsf{I}_{n\times n}-\widetilde{\mathsf{A}}_{n\times n}^T \bigr)^{-1} \left [ \begin{array}{c} 0\\ \vdots\\ 0\\ - { (1-\alpha )} \sum_{i=1}^{n-1}\widetilde{a}_{in}\tau_i \end{array} \right ], \end{aligned}$$

where the entry in the vector on the right-hand side captures hidden input taxes.

1.2 A.2 Determination of total output change in the financial industry

Using value based input coefficients

$$\begin{aligned}{} [ \mathsf{I}-\widetilde{\mathsf{A}} ] \left [ \begin{array}{c} d (p_1 X_1 )\\ \vdots\\ d (p_n X_{n} ) \end{array} \right ] = \left [ \begin{array}{c} d (p_1 x_1 ) \\ \vdots\\ d (p_n x_{n} ) \end{array} \right ]. \end{aligned}$$

If we follow the above assumption that substantial price effects are only obtained with regard to sector n, we have

$$\begin{aligned} \left [ \begin{array}{c} d (p_1 X_1 )\\ \vdots\\ d (p_n X_{n} ) \end{array} \right ] = [ \mathsf{I}-\widetilde{\mathsf{A}} ]^{-1} \left [ \begin{array}{c} p_1 \frac{\partial h_1}{\partial q_n} d q_n \\ \vdots\\ h_n d p_n + p_n \frac{\partial h_n}{\partial q_n} d q_n \end{array} \right ]. \end{aligned}$$

Using Slutsky symmetry,

$$\begin{aligned} \left [ \begin{array}{c} d (p_1 X_1 )\\ \vdots\\ d (p_n X_{n} ) \end{array} \right ] = [ \mathsf{I}-\widetilde{\mathsf{A}} ]^{-1} \left [ \begin{array}{c} p_1 \frac{\partial h_n}{\partial q_1} d q_n \\ \vdots\\ h_n d p_n + p_n \frac{\partial h_n}{\partial q_n} d q_n \end{array} \right ]. \end{aligned}$$

Rearranging terms, we see that the output changes are linear functions of the price changes.

$$\begin{aligned} \left [ \begin{array}{c} d (p_1 X_1 )\\ \vdots\\ d (p_n X_{n} ) \end{array} \right ] = [ \mathsf{I}-\widetilde{\mathsf{A}} ]^{-1} \left [ \begin{array}{c} (\frac{h_n}{1+\tau_1} ) \epsilon_{n1} d q_n \\ \vdots\\ h_n d p_n + (\frac{h_n}{1+\tau_n} ) \epsilon_{nn} d q_n \end{array} \right ]. \end{aligned}$$

In the case where all taxes are equal τ i =τ,∀i<n, except for τ n =0, initially, and where a tax τ n =τ is introduced, we obtain the changes in the value of gross outputs

$$\begin{aligned} \left [ \begin{array}{c} d (p_1 X_1 )\\ \vdots\\ d (p_n X_{n} ) \end{array} \right ] = p_n h_n [ \mathsf{I}-\widetilde{\mathsf{A}} ]^{-1} \left [ \begin{array}{c} (\frac{ \epsilon_{n1}}{1+\tau} ) (\widehat{p}_n + \tau ) \\ \vdots\\ \widehat{p}_n + \epsilon_{nn} (\widehat{p}_n + \tau ) \end{array} \right ]. \end{aligned}$$

The last element of this vector gives the output change in the exempted sector evaluated at pretax prices.

1.3 A.3 Table of sector-specific VAT rates

See Table 2.

Table 2 Average specific VAT rates in Germany for 2007

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Buettner, T., Erbe, K. Revenue and welfare effects of financial sector VAT exemption. Int Tax Public Finance 21, 1028–1050 (2014). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10797-013-9297-5

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10797-013-9297-5

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation