Skip to main content
Log in

Constitutional Interpretation: Burke and Buchanan and their 18th Century Intellectual Roots

  • Original Article
  • Published:
Constitutional Political Economy Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

There is a respectable tradition of Burkean constitutional interpretation in legal scholarship whereas Edmund Burke is a relatively neglected figure in constitutional political economy. A comparison of the constitutional interpretations of constitutional political economy and Burkean legal scholarship provides a potentially fruitful outcome for both. This is particularly so given the 18th century intellectual roots of each. An examination of the Burkean tradition demonstrates why it is methodologically inductive, evolutionary and pessimistic, compared to the deductive, individualistic and optimistic approach of the Smithian tradition of constitutional political economy. Interestingly, these sharp distinctions in method produce similar results.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. It is probably also why there is only one reference to Edmund Burke in The Collected Works of James M. Buchanan. Appendix 1 in The Calculus of Consent is titled ‘Marginal Notes on Reading Political Philosophy’. In it Buchanan says “[o]ur theory of constitutional choice is avowedly individualistic in this analytical-methodological approach. Therefore, we react sympathetically to the works of those political theorists who have most clearly discussed the logic of collective organisation in terms of an individual calculus ... methodologically he [Burke] was clearly anti-individualist, and he vigorously rejected all attempts to explain collective activity on the basis of rational individual choice” (CW, 3: 316–318).

  2. Barrington (1954) sources this quote from page 429 in Robert Bisset's second edition of The Life of Edmund Burke. Providing a range of examples, Winch (1996, p. 128) points out that this anecdote is cited according to taste.

  3. It is important to note that Buchanan does not apply the exchange paradigm to the judiciary. He states that the “judiciary, in its umpire role, must take a truth-judgement approach, an approach that is inappropriate in the workings of ordinary politics” (Buchanan, 1988, p. 137).

  4. Olson (1996) provides a similar cajoling of economists.

  5. North (1981) identifies a similar role for ideas in evolutionary change. The direction of causation is unidirectional as explained in Rizzello and Turvani (2000).

  6. It is similar to what Brennan and Hamlin (2004) identify as the conservative disposition.

  7. To borrow a Buchanan line from his comparison of Smith and John Rawls, Burke and Smith are “closer to each other than either would be to the image that intellectual fashion has imposed on him” (CW, 1: 293).

  8. A sample of the variety of interpretations placed on Burke's writings can be found in Kramnick (1999, pp. xxii–xxxiii).

  9. However, there remains some doubt about the seriousness with which A Vindication can be taken as representative of the Burkean view. Originally it was published anonymously and it was only in the second edition that Burke claimed authorship and stated that the book was a satirical or ironical look at the natural order. It is far from clear which version to believe (Rothbard, 1958, Kramnick, 1999).

  10. In his Address to the Electors of Bristol (1774), Burke explained that he was their representative not their delegate.

  11. Similarities between Burke's views and those of late 20th century thought on budgetary institutions can be found in Considine (2002) and Considine (2005).

  12. Reflections is presented as a motivational force for the 19th century work of Karl von Savigny's German Historical school of jurisprudence (Kilcommins, 2004). It is also seen as influencing the thought of 20th century conservative Michael Oakeshott (McClelland, 1996).

  13. They also share the distinction of having part of their intellectual legacy questioned on the grounds of consistency. The Edmund Burke Problem is the name given to the difficulties reconciling “his defense of the ancien regime with his endorsement ... of those economic forces that ... would eventually undermine the traditional monarchical, aristocratic, and ecclesiastical order” (Winch, 1996, p. 128). Das Adam Smith Problem is the name given to the difficulties late 19th century German scholars had in establishing consonance “between his writings as a moral philosopher and political economist” (Winch, 1996, p. 35).

  14. It is also accepted that “Smith's political economy furnishes a major clue to Burke's thinking, which in turn helps us understand Smith's politics” (Winch, 1996, pp. 128–129).

  15. While Buchanan agrees that Smith rejected the notion of a social contract he argues that Smith's impartial spectator performs a similar role (CW, 1:298).

  16. Dunn (1941) traces the changes in terminology between the Theory of Moral Sentiments and the Wealth of Nations.

References

  • N. Barry (1997) The political economy of Edmund Burke I. Crowe (Eds) Edmund Burke: His life and legacy Four Courts Press Dublin 104–114

    Google Scholar 

  • D. Barrington (1954) ArticleTitleEdmund Burke as an economist Economica 21 252–258

    Google Scholar 

  • G. Brennan A. Hamlin (2004) ArticleTitleAnalytic conservatism British Journal of Political Science 34 675–691 Occurrence Handle10.1017/S0007123404000249

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • J. M. Buchanan (1988) ArticleTitleContractarian political economy and constitutional intrepretation American Economic Review 78 IssueID2 135–139

    Google Scholar 

  • The Collected Works of James M. Buchanan. Indianapolis: Liberty Fund.

  • J. M. Buchanan (2004) ArticleTitleThe status of the status Quo Constitutional Political Economy 15 IssueID2 133–144 Occurrence Handle10.1023/B:COPE.0000029639.96250.45

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • F. Canavan (1995) The political economy of Edmund Burke Fordham University Press New York

    Google Scholar 

  • J Considine (2002) ArticleTitleBudgetary institutions and fiscal discipline: Edmund Burke's insightful contribution European Journal of History of Economic Thought 9 IssueID4 591–607 Occurrence Handle10.1080/0967256021000024691

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Considine, J., James M. Buchanan and Edmund Burke (2005). Opposite sides of the same fiscal constitutional coin. Journal of History of Economic Thought, forthcoming.

  • C. Cruise O’Brien (1992) The great melody: A thematic biography Sinclair-Stevenson London

    Google Scholar 

  • W. C. Dunn (1941) ArticleTitleAdam Smith and Edmund Burke: Complementary contemporaries Southern Economic Journal 7 IssueID3 330–346 Occurrence Handle10.2307/1053043

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • M. D. A. Freeman (2001) Lloyd's introduction to jurisprudence EditionNumber7 Sweet and Maxwell London

    Google Scholar 

  • L. Gibbons (2003) Edmund Burke and Ireland Cambridge University Press Cambridge, UK

    Google Scholar 

  • M. F. Grady M. T. McGuire (1999) ArticleTitleThe Nature of Constitutions Journal of Bioeconomics 1 227–240 Occurrence Handle10.1023/A:1010043127129

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • F. Hayek Particlevon (1982) Law, legislation and liberty Routledge London

    Google Scholar 

  • S. Kilcommins (2004) The historical school of jurisprudience T. Murphy (Eds) Western jurisprudence Thompson Round Hall Dublin 144–167

    Google Scholar 

  • I. Kramnick (1999) The portable Edmund Burke Penguin Books London

    Google Scholar 

  • J. S. McClelland (1996) A history of western political thought Routledge London

    Google Scholar 

  • McDowell, R. B. (Ed.) (1991). The Writings and Speeches of Edmund Burke – Volume IX, I: The Revolutionary War 1794–1797; II: Ireland. Clarendon Press, Oxford.

  • R. B. McDowell (2003) Historical essays [1938–2001] Lilliput Press Dublin

    Google Scholar 

  • J. O. McGinnis (1997) ArticleTitleThe original constitution and its decline: A public choice perspective Harvard Journal of Law & Public Policy 21 195–210

    Google Scholar 

  • T. W. Merrill (1996) ArticleTitleBork v. Burke Harvard Journal of Law & Public Policy 19 509–523

    Google Scholar 

  • Mitchell, L. G. (Ed.) (1989). The writings and speeches of Edmund Burke, Volume VIII. Oxford: Clarendon Press.

  • D. C. North (1981) Structure and change in economic history Cambridge University Press Cambridge, MA

    Google Scholar 

  • M. Olson (1996) ArticleTitleBig bills left on the sidewalk: Why some countries are rich and others are poor? Journal of Economic Perspectives 10 IssueID2 3–26

    Google Scholar 

  • S Ratnapala (2001) ArticleTitleEighteenth-century evolutionary thought and its relevance in the age of legislation Constitutional Political Economy 12 51–75 Occurrence Handle10.1023/A:1016681121137

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • S. Rizzello M Turvani (2000) ArticleTitleInstitutions meet mind: The way out of an impasse Constitutional Political Economy 11 IssueID2 165–180 Occurrence Handle10.1023/A:1009085717188

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • M. N. Rothbard (1958) ArticleTitleA note on Burke's vindication of natural society Journal of the History of Ideas 19 IssueID1 114–118

    Google Scholar 

  • E Rothchild (1992) ArticleTitleAdam Smith and conservative economics Economic History Review 45 IssueID1 74–96

    Google Scholar 

  • V. J. Vanberg (2004) ArticleTitleThe status quo in contractarian-constitutionist perspective Constitutional Political Economy 15 IssueID2 153–170 Occurrence Handle10.1023/B:COPE.0000029641.48448.19

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • J. G. Wilson (1986) ArticleTitleJustice diffused: A comparison of Edmund Burke's conservatism with the views of five conservative, academic judges University of Miami Law Review 40 913–971

    Google Scholar 

  • D. Winch (1996) Riches and poverty: An intellectual history of political economy in Britain, 1750–1834 Cambridge University Press Cambridge, UK

    Google Scholar 

  • B. Yandle (1991) ArticleTitleOrganic constitutions and common law Constitutional Political Economy 2 IssueID2 225–241 Occurrence Handle10.1007/BF02404429

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • E. Young (1994) ArticleTitleRediscovering conservatism: Burkean political theory and constitutional interpretation North Carolina Law Review 72 619–725

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to John Considine.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Considine, J. Constitutional Interpretation: Burke and Buchanan and their 18th Century Intellectual Roots. Constit Polit Econ 17, 71–85 (2006). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10602-006-0004-8

Download citation

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10602-006-0004-8

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation