Skip to main content
Log in

Law, Social Welfare, and Net Neutrality

  • Published:
Review of Industrial Organization Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Net neutrality generates wealth transfers from one type of internet content provider to another. In theory, these transfers might be socially desirable, and could be justified on the basis of informational externalities similar to those cited to justify fair use in copyright law. In practice, however, the conditions that justify fair use do not hold where net neutrality operates. Moreover, the internal subsidization required by net neutrality generates a regressive transfer. The welfare gains that might come from controlling anticompetitive abuse or government coercion through implementation of net neutrality can be achieved by alternative policies with less harmful consequences.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. As Becker et al. (2010, p. 498) explain, the net neutrality principle has devolved into four specific requirements: broadband providers are “prohibited from: (1) prioritizing traffic and charging differential prices based on the priority status; (2) imposing congestion-related charges; (3) adopting business models that offer exclusive content or that establish exclusive relationships with particular content providers; and (4) charging content providers to access the Internet based on factors other than the bandwidth supplied”.

  2. On the variation in network services and costs, see Yoo (2013).

  3. The similarity is that in both contexts, one observes large up-front capital expenses to construct a facility, and the incremental cost of using the facility is comparatively small. The economics of bridges is a topic with an extensive literature. See e.g., Hotelling (1938) and Minasian (1979). The difficult problem of optimal supply that was analyzed in the earlier literature has important implications for the treatment of different types of users, and the extent to which one can determine when the pricing of bridge services inefficiently advantages one user at the expense of another user. I will oversimplify and avoid most of these difficulties here.

  4. I use the term cross-subsidy as an equivalent to “internal subsidy”, as in Posner (1971). This is a popular, though admittedly non-rigorous use of the term. In my treatment, a cross-subsidy or internal subsidy results from a regulation (such as a net neutrality requirement) when a firm is forced to change its pricing structure, as a result of the regulation, in a manner that benefits one group of consumers and disadvantages another group of consumers. The concept of cross-subsidy is difficult and would require a much more extensive treatment than is offered here to deal with adequately in economic terms. A rigorous treatment of the concept of cross-subsidy is provided in Faulhaber (1975).

  5. Here I refer to the simplest form of Ramsey pricing that results from profit maximization by a multi-product monopolist. For simplicity, I assume that the user demand functions are independent of each other. For a straightforward presentation, see Tirole (1980).

  6. See generally Baumol and Bradford (1970).

  7. See Clark (2014).

  8. See e.g., Becker et al. (2010) and Peitz and Schuett (2015). In my example in the text, if the privately-chosen prices are relatively close to the socially optimal Ramsey prices, then unregulated monopoly would enhance welfare relative to the equal-pricing rule.

  9. Although the empirical importance of such depreciation may be entirely speculative, for a model that incorporates depreciation as a factor, see Odlyzko (1997).

  10. Gordon (1982).

  11. Rawls (1971).

  12. See e.g., Posner (1981, p. 59). Of course, one could say that this is just an ordinary social welfare function that takes risk-aversion into account. See id.

  13. http://civicscience.com/wp-content/uploads/2015/05/CivicScience-Netflixs-New-Users-May-2015-Final.pdf.

  14. 224 U.S. 383 (1912).

  15. See e.g., Hazlett and Wright (2012).

  16. On Ramsey pricing and broadband networks, see Yoo (2013, p. 580).

  17. See Hazlett and Wright (2012, p. 782).

  18. Most people have only one high-speed broadband provider; see http://consumerist.com/2014/12/18/govt-report-true-high-speed-broadband-competition-in-the-u-s-remains-largely-nonexistent/.

  19. See Google Curbs Expansion of Fiber Optic Network, Cutting Jobs, New York Times, http://www.nytimes.com/2016/10/26/technology/google-curbs-expansion-of-fiber-optic-network-cutting-jobs.html?_r=0.

  20. See http://consumerist.com/2015/10/29/shortlist-of-future-google-fiber-cities-keeps-getting-longer-three-more-cities-added/.

  21. See Google Curbs Expansion of Fiber Optic Network, Cutting Jobs, New York Times, http://www.nytimes.com/2016/10/26/technology/google-curbs-expansion-of-fiber-optic-network-cutting-jobs.html?_r=0. Another new alternative is the use of small satellites to provide internet service: http://consumerist.com/2015/06/11/the-guy-who-started-tesla-wants-to-shoot-the-internet-to-you-from-space/.

  22. MGM Studios, Inc. v. Grokster, Ltd., 545 U.S. 913 (2005); BMG Rights Management (US) LLC et al. v. Cox Enterprises Inc. et al., case number 1:14-cv-01611, in the U.S. District Court for the Eastern District of Virginia.

  23. For example, on Comcast’s government business, see http://business.comcast.com/ethernet/industry-solutions/government.

References

  • Baumol, W. J., & Bradford, D. F. (1970). Optimal departures from marginal cost pricing. The American Economic Review, 60(3), 265–283.

    Google Scholar 

  • Becker, G. S., Carlton, D. W., & Sider, H. S. (2010). Net neutrality and consumer welfare. Journal of Competition Law and Economics, 6(3), 497–519.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Clark, D. (2014). Measuring Internet congestion: A preliminary report. https://ipp.mit.edu/sites/default/files/documents/Congestion-handout-final.pdf.

  • Economides, N., & Tåg, J. (2012). Net neutrality on the internet: A two-sided market analysis. Information Economics and Policy, 24(2), 91–104.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Faulhaber, G. R. (1975). Cross-subsidization: Pricing in public enterprises. The American Economic Review, 65(5), 966–977.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gordon, W. J. (1982). Fair use as market failure: A structural and economic analysis of the Betamax case and its predecessors. Columbia Law Review, 82(8), 1600–1657.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hazlett, T. W., & Wright, J. D. (2012). The law and economics of network neutrality. Indiana Law Review, 45(3), 767–840.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hotelling, H. (1938). The general welfare in relation to problems of taxation and of railway and utility rates. Econometrica, 6(3), 242–269.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Minasian, J. R. (1979). Indivisibility, decreasing cost, and excess capacity: The bridge. Journal of Law and Economics, 22(2), 385–397.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Odlyzko, A. (1997). A modest proposal for preventing internet congestion. http://www.dtc.umn.edu/~odlyzko/doc/modest.proposal.pdf.

  • Peitz, M., & Schuett, F. (2015). Net neutrality and inflation of traffic. TILEC Discussion Paper No. 2015-006. Available at SSRN: http://ssrn.com/abstract=2573466 or http://dx.doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.2573466.

  • Posner, R. A. (1971). Taxation by regulation. The Bell Journal of Economics and Management Science, 2(1), 22–50.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Posner, R. A. (1981). The economics of justice. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rawls, J. (1971). Theory of justice. Cambridge, MA: Belknap Press of Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tirole, J. (1980). The theory of industrial organization. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Yoo, C. S. (2013). Is there a role for common carriage in an internet-based world? Houston Law Review, 51(2), 545–608.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

I thank Michelle Connolly, Thomas Hazlett, David Sappington, Elliot Maxwell, Roger Noll, Scott Wallsten, Chris Yoo, and Lawrence White for very helpful comments. All errors and omissions are my own. I have also benefited from suggestions of participants at the Tech Policy Institute’s Conference on Net Neutrality, January 8, 2016, in Washington, DC.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Keith N. Hylton.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Hylton, K.N. Law, Social Welfare, and Net Neutrality. Rev Ind Organ 50, 417–429 (2017). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11151-016-9552-x

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11151-016-9552-x

Keywords

Navigation