Skip to main content
Log in

Hotelling was right with decreasing returns to scale and a coalition-proof refinement

  • Original Paper
  • Published:
The Annals of Regional Science Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This paper provides a simple, realistic, and very slightly modified version of the production technology in Hotelling’s (Econ J 39:41–57, 1929) spatial model with linear transportation costs to overcome the nonexistence problem of equilibrium—decreasing returns to scale. It is shown that a pure strategy Nash equilibrium in price competition always exists for all location pairs and guarantees uniqueness if we utilize a coalition-proof refinement introduced by Bernheim et al. (J Econ Theory 42:1–12, 1987). Decreasing returns to scale reduce the profit a firm can capture through price undercutting and stabilize the price equilibrium due to the increasing average production cost of firms. As a consequence, duopoly firms agglomerating at the center of a line are shown to be at the unique location equilibrium. This paper confers a new validity to the so-called principle of minimum differentiation, in some sense, with the least deviation from the original Hotelling (Econ J 39:41–57, 1929) model.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. It is well known that Hotelling’s (1929) spatial model also has an explanation for product locations. Pinkse and Slade (1998) provide an empirical study example, finding that the market share effect (i.e. a firm can steal some of its rivals’ customers) dominates, leading to a clustering of product locations.

  2. When allowing price discrimination, Lederer and Hurter (1986), Eber (1997), and Colombo (2011) show the existence of intermediate equilibrium locations in the Hotelling model.

  3. Matsumura and Matsushima (2011) present that the agglomeration results in Jehiel (1992) and Friedman and Thisse (1993) never appear when there is a cost difference between firms. Moreover, Ago (2008) also shows the spatial agglomeration result in the case of monopolistic competition.

  4. Anderson (1988) investigates the combination of linear and quadratic terms in a convex transportation cost function, finding that a pure strategy perfect equilibrium in the two-stage location-price game exists only under very stringent conditions, requiring a zero linear component of the cost specification.

  5. See Dixon (1990) for related discussions.

  6. The reason for adapting the same assumption as Chamberlin (1933) is to avoid the well-known non-existence of a Nash equilibrium in pure strategies. Under the same assumption, Dastidar (1995), Chowdhury and Sengupta (2004), and Hirata and Matsumura (2010) study Bertrand competition with decreasing returns to scale technology in a non-spatial context.

  7. More specifically, a modified perfectly coalition-proof Nash equilibrium (PCPNE) is applied to be the equilibrium concept in this two-stage game, which allows for deviations by self-enforcing groups of players (firms), but rules out threats that are dynamically inconsistent and behavior by coalitions that is not self-enforcing.

  8. Concerning pure geographical location competition and regarding the midpoint as a border between two countries (or regions), such a restriction is applicable if cross-border buying by consumers is permitted, but cross-border planting of firms is prohibited due to regulations or cost impacts. On the other hand, concerning the degree of product differentiation, Hauser (1988) suggests such an assumption can be seen as: (1) the firms are already in the market and (2) their current positions are sticky. In this case, firms’ rank order along the horizontal axis does not change due to a firm’s own technical expertise, as well as its previous advertising and inertia in consumer perceptions.

  9. Suppose that the firms anticipate a symmetric equilibrium price denoted by \(p_{i}^{*}\in [{p}^{\prime },{p}^{\prime \prime }]\), for \(i\in \{1,2\}\), that will be realized. Now consider the case in which the rival firm quotes a different price due to an exogenous shock. If the rival firm quotes a price lower than \(p_{i}^{*} \), then a firm’s profit is zero for any anticipated symmetric price, \(p_{i}^{*}\in [{p}^{\prime },{p}^{\prime \prime }]\). On the other hand, if the rival firm quotes a price higher than \(p_{i}^{*}\), then a firm’s profit is given by \(p_{i}^{*}-C(1)\). It is clear that the highest price on the range, \(p_{i}^{*}={p}^{\prime \prime }\), leads to the highest profit of a firm. We thank an anonymous referee for suggesting this interpretation.

  10. See “Appendix” for a detailed derivation.

  11. Note that for any symmetric location, \(\pi _{i}^{*}(x_{1},x_{2}=1-x_{1} )={(2t+c)}/4,\) \(\forall x_{1}\in [0,1/2),\)   and that \(\pi _{i}^{*} (x_{1}=1/2,x_{2}=1/2)={p}^{\prime \prime }/2-C(1/2)=c/2.\) In this sense, \(\pi _{i}^{*}(x_{1}=1/2,x_{2}=1/2)\ge \pi _{i}^{*}(x_{1},x_{2}=1-x_{1})\), \(\forall x_{1}\in [0,1/2),\)  if and only if \(c\ge 2t\).

References

  • Ago T (2008) Central agglomeration of monopolistically competitive firms. J Econ Geogr 8:811–823

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Anderson S (1988) Equilibrium existence in the linear model of spatial competition. Economica 55:479–491

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bernheim BD, Peleg B, Whinston MD (1987) Coalition-proof Nash equilibria: I. Concepts. J Econ Theory 42:1–12

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bester H (1998) Quality uncertainty mitigates product differentiation. RAND J Econ 29:828–844

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bhaskar V (1997) The competitive effects of price-floors. J Ind Econ 45:329–340

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chamberlin EH (1933) The theory of monopolistic competition. Harvard University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Chowdhury PR, Sengupta K (2004) Coalition-proof Bertrand equilibria. Econ Theory 24:307–324

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Colombo S (2011) Discriminatory prices and the prisoner dilemma problem. Ann Reg Sci 46:397–416

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • d’Aspremont C, Gabszewicz JJ, Thisse J-F (1979) On Hotelling’s ‘stability in competition’. Econometrica 47:1145–1150

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dastidar KG (1995) On the existence of pure strategy Bertrand equilibrium. Econ Theory 5:19–32

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dixon H (1990) Bertrand-Edgeworth equilibria when firms avoid turning customers away. J Ind Econ 39:131–146

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Eber N (1997) A note on the strategic choice of spatial price discrimination. Econ Lett 55:419–423

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Economides N (1984) The principle of minimum differentiation revisited. Eur Econ Rev 24:345–368

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Edgeworth F (1922) The mathematical economics of Professor Amaroso. Econ J 32:400–407

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Friedman JW, Thisse J-F (1993) Partial collusion fosters minimum product differentiation. RAND J Econ 24:631–645

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hauser JR (1988) Competitive price and positioning strategies. Mark Sci 7:76–91

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hinloopen J, Marrewijk CV (1999) On the limits and possibilities of the principle of minimum differentiation. Int J Ind Organ 17:735–750

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hirata D, Matsumura T (2010) On the uniqueness of Bertrand equilibrium. Oper Res Lett 38:533–535

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hotelling H (1929) Stability in competition. Econ J 39:41–57

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jehiel P (1992) Product differentiation and price collusion. Int J Ind Organ 10:633–641

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lederer PJ, Hurter AP (1986) Competition of firms: discriminatory pricing and locations. Econometrica 54:623–640

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Matsumura T, Matsushima N (2011) Collusion, agglomeration, and heterogeneity of firms. Games Econ Behav 72:306–313

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Osborne MJ, Pitchik C (1987) Equilibrium in Hotelling’s model of spatial competition. Econometrica 55:911–922

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pinkse J, Slade ME (1998) Contracting in space: an application of spatial statistics to discrete-choice models. J Econ 85:125–154

    Google Scholar 

  • Zhang ZJ (1995) Price-matching policy and the principle of minimum differentiation. J Ind Econ 43: 287–299

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Chia-Hung Sun.

Appendix

Appendix

1.1 Definition of a coalition-proof Nash equilibrium

Following Chowdhury and Sengupta (2004), let \(N\) be the set of firms in the market, where \(\left|N\right|=n\ge 2\). A coalition \(T\subseteq N\) has a profitable deviation from the price vector \(p\) if there exists \({p}^{\prime }(T)=({p}_{i}^{\prime })_{i\in T}\) such that:

$$\begin{aligned} \pi _{i}({p}^{\prime }(T),p(N/T))>\pi _{i}(p), \forall i\in T, \end{aligned}$$

where \(p(N/T)\) is the restriction of \(p\) on \(N/T\).

A coalition \(T\) with \(\left| T \right| =1\) has a self-enforcing profitable deviation from the price vector \(p\) if \(T\) has a profitable deviation from \(p\).

Suppose now we have defined a self-enforcing profitable deviation \(\forall S\subset N\), with \(\left| S \right| \le m\le n-1\) and for all price vectors \(p \). Now consider a coalition \(T\subseteq N\) such that \(\left| T \right| =m+1\).

Coalition \(T\) is said to have a self-enforcing profitable deviation from \(p\) if there exists a vector \({p}^{\prime }(T)\) such that:

  1. 1.

    Coalition \(T\) has a profitable deviation from \(p\) using the price vector \({p}^{\prime }(T)\).

  2. 2.

    For any \(S\subset T\), \(S\ne T\), the coalition \(S\) has no self-enforcing profitable deviation from \(({p}^{\prime }(T),p(N/T))\).

Definition 1

A vector of prices \(\hat{p}\) is said to be a CPNE if no coalition \(T\) has a self-enforcing profitable deviation from \(\hat{p}\).

Proof of Lemma 1

We define a new function \(m_{1}(x_{1},x_{2})\) as:

$$\begin{aligned} m_{1}(x_{1},x_{2})&= p_{1}^{*}(x_{1},x_{2})-{C}^{\prime }\left(Q_{1}^{*} (x_{1},x_{2})\right)\nonumber \\&= \frac{t(x_{1}+x_{2}+2)}{3}+\frac{{C}^{\prime }(Q_{2}^{* }\left(x_{1},x_{2})\right)}{3}-\frac{{C}^{\prime }\left(Q_{1}^{*}(x_{1},x_{2})\right)}{3}, \end{aligned}$$

where the second equality is derived from the first-order condition for the maximizing profit of a firm in Eq. (2). Differentiating the function \(m_{1}(x_{1},x_{2})\) with respect to \(x_{i}\), for \(i=1,2\), and taking into account Eqs. (5) and (6) yield:

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial m_{1}(x_{1},x_{2})}{\partial x_{i}}&= \frac{\partial p_{1}^{*}(x_{1},x_{2})}{\partial x_{i}}-{C}^{\prime \prime }\left(Q_{1}^{* }(x_{1},x_{2})\right)\cdot \frac{\partial Q_{1}^{*}(x_{1},x_{2})}{\partial x_{i}}\\&= \frac{t\left[2t\!+\!{C}^{\prime \prime }(Q_{1}^{\!*\!})\right]}{6t\!+\!{C}^{\prime \prime } (Q_{1}^{\!*\!})\!+\!{C}^{\prime \prime } (Q_{2}^{\!*\!})}\!-\!{C}^{\prime \prime } \left(Q_{1}^{\!*\!}(x_{1},x_{2})\right)\cdot \frac{t}{6t\!+\!{C}^{\prime \prime }(Q_{1}^{\!*\! })\!+\!{C}^{\prime \prime }(Q_{2}^{\!*\!})}\\&= \frac{2t^{2}}{6t+{C}^{\prime \prime } (Q_{1}^{*})+{C}^{\prime \prime } (Q_{2}^{*})}>0, \end{aligned}$$

which is unambiguously positive. In this sense, the function \(m_{1} (x_{1},x_{2})\) reaches its minimum at \((x_{1}=0,x_{2}=1/2)\) and reaches its maximum at \((x_{1}=1/2,x_{2}=1)\):

$$\begin{aligned}&m_{1}(x_{1}=0,x_{2}=1/2)\nonumber \\&\quad \quad \quad \quad =\frac{5t}{6}+\frac{{C}^{\prime }\left(Q_{2}^{*}(x_{1}=0,x_{2}=1/2)\right)}{3} -\frac{{C}^{\prime }\left(Q_{1}^{*}(x_{1}=0,x_{2}=1/2)\right)}{3}\nonumber \\&\quad \quad \quad \quad \ge \frac{5t}{6}+\frac{{C}^{\prime }(Q_{2}^{*}=1/2)}{3}-\frac{{C} ^{\prime }(Q_{1}^{*}=1/2)}{3}=\frac{5t}{6}>0, \end{aligned}$$
(16)
$$\begin{aligned}&m_{1}(x_{1}=1/2,x_{2}=1)\nonumber \\&\quad \quad \quad \quad =\frac{7t}{6}+\frac{{C}^{\prime }\left(Q_{2}^{*}(x_{1}=1/2,x_{2}=1)\right)}{3} -\frac{{C}^{\prime }\left(Q_{1}^{*}(x_{1}=1/2,x_{2}=1)\right)}{3}\nonumber \\&\quad \quad \quad \quad \le \frac{7t}{6}+\frac{{C}^{\prime }(Q_{2}^{*}=1/2)}{3}-\frac{{C} ^{\prime }(Q_{1}^{*}=1/2)}{3}=\frac{7t}{6}<2t, \end{aligned}$$
(17)

where the first inequalities in Eqs. (16) and (17) are derived from the assumption of a convex production cost function (\({C}^{\prime \prime } (Q_{i})\ge 0)\). From Eqs. (16) and (17), it follows that \(0<m_{1} (x_{1},x_{2})<2t\) for all \(x_{1}\in [0,1/2]\) and \(x_{2}\in [1/2,1]\).

We next define a new function \(m_{2}(x_{1},x_{2})\) as:

$$\begin{aligned} m_{2}(x_{1},x_{2})&= p_{2}^{*}(x_{1},x_{2})-{C}^{\prime }\left(Q_{2}^{*} (x_{1},x_{2})\right)\\&= \frac{t(4-x_{1}-x_{2})}{3}+\frac{{C}^{\prime }\left(Q_{1}^{* }(x_{1},x_{2})\right)}{3}-\frac{{C}^{\prime }\left(Q_{2}^{*}(x_{1},x_{2})\right)}{3}, \end{aligned}$$

where the second equality is derived from the first-order condition for the maximizing profit of a firm in Eq. (2). The first-order derivative of \(m_{2}(x_{1},x_{2})\) with respect to \(x_{i}\), for \(i=1,2\), can be calculated as:

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial m_{2}(x_{1},x_{2})}{\partial x_{i}}&= \frac{\partial p_{2}^{*}(x_{1},x_{2})}{\partial x_{i}}-{C}^{\prime \prime }\left(Q_{2}^{*}(x_{1},x_{2})\right)\cdot \frac{\partial Q_{2}^{*}(x_{1},x_{2})}{\partial x_{i}}\\&= \frac{\!-\!t\left[2t\!+\!{C}^{\prime \prime }(Q_{2}^{\!*\!})\right]}{6t\!+\!{C}^{\prime \prime }(Q_{1}^{\!*\!}) \!+\!{C}^{\prime \prime }(Q_{2}^{\!*\!})}\!-\!{C}^{\prime \prime } \left(Q_{2}^{\!*\!}(x_{1},x_{2})\right)\cdot \frac{\!-\!t}{6t\!+\!{C}^{\prime \prime } (Q_{1}^{*})\!+\!{C}^{\prime \prime }(Q_{2}^{\!*\!})}\\&= \frac{-2t^{2}}{6t+{C}^{\prime \prime }(Q_{1}^{*}) +{C}^{\prime \prime }(Q_{2}^{*})}<0. \end{aligned}$$

It follows that the function \(m_{2}(x_{1},x_{2})\) reaches its minimum at \((x_{1}=1/2,x_{2}=1)\) and reaches its maximum at \((x_{1}=0,x_{2}=1/2)\):

$$\begin{aligned}&m_{2}(x_{1}=1/2,x_{2}=1)\nonumber \\&\quad \quad \quad \quad =\frac{5t}{6}+\frac{{C}^{\prime }\left(Q_{1}^{*}(x_{1}=1/2,x_{2}=1)\right)}{3} -\frac{{C}^{\prime }\left(Q_{2}^{*}(x_{1}=1/2,x_{2}=1)\right)}{3}\nonumber \\&\quad \quad \quad \quad \ge \frac{5t}{6}+\frac{{C}^{\prime }(Q_{1}^{*}=1/2)}{3}-\frac{{C} ^{\prime }(Q_{2}^{*}=1/2)}{3}=\frac{5t}{6}>0, \end{aligned}$$
(18)
$$\begin{aligned}&m_{2}(x_{1} =0,x_{2}=1/2)\nonumber \\&\quad \quad \quad \quad =\frac{7t}{6}+\frac{{C}^{\prime }\left(Q_{1} ^{*}(x_{1}=0,x_{2}=1/2)\right)}{3}-\frac{{C}^{\prime } \left(Q_{2}^{*}(x_{1}=0,x_{2}=1/2)\right)}{3}\nonumber \\&\quad \quad \quad \quad \le \frac{7t}{6}+\frac{{C}^{\prime }(Q_{1}^{*}=1/2)}{3}-\frac{{C} ^{\prime }(Q_{2}^{*}=1/2)}{3}=\frac{7t}{6}<2t, \end{aligned}$$
(19)

where the first inequalities in Eqs. (18) and (19) are derived from the assumption of a convex production cost function (\({C}^{\prime \prime } (Q_{i})\ge 0)\). It follows that \(0<m_{2}(x_{1},x_{2})<2t\) for all \(x_{1} \in [0,1/2]\) and \(x_{2}\in [1/2,1]\).

We next show that a corner solution, \(Q_{i}=0\) for \(i\in \{1,2\}\), will never be an equilibrium outcome in the price subgame.

We shall assume that this is not so, and then \(\bar{Q}_{j}=1\) is a candidate equilibrium demand only if firm \(j\) quotes a price \(\bar{p}_{j}\ge C(1)\). Given such a price strategy of firm \(j\), firm \(i\) can always get positive demand by quoting the same price (i.e., \(p_{i}=\bar{p}_{j})\) and get a profit:

$$\begin{aligned} \pi _{i}&= \bar{p}_{j}{\cdot }Q_{i}-C(Q_{i})\ge \left[ {C(1)\cdot Q_{i}}\right] -C(Q_{i})\nonumber \\&= \left[ {Q_{i}\cdot C(1)+(1-Q_{i})\cdot C(0)}\right] -C(Q_{i} \cdot 1+(1-Q_{i})\cdot 0)\ge 0, \end{aligned}$$
(20)

for \(i,j\in \{1,2\}\) and \(i\ne j, \forall 0<Q_{i}<1\), where the last inequality in Eq. (20) is derived from the definition of a convex function, and equality is satisfied only if production cost is linear. It follows that for a strictly convex production cost (\({C}^{\prime \prime } (Q_{i})>0)\), firm \(i\) can always guarantee a positive profit by mimicking its opponent’s strategy. Now, combine the fact that for a linear production cost (\({C}^{\prime \prime }(Q_{i})=0)\), firm \(i\) can guarantee positive demand and profit by quoting a slightly higher price than marginal cost. We thus conclude that a corner solution \(Q_{i}=0\) is never an equilibrium outcome for a convex production cost function (\({C}^{\prime \prime }(Q_{i})\ge 0)\). \(\square \)

Proof of Corollary 2

The derivations of a linear production cost function \(C(Q_{i})=c\cdot Q_{i}\) are omitted. With a quadratic (square) production cost function \(C(Q_{i})=c\cdot Q_{i}^{2}\), routine manipulation yields the results in the price subgame:

$$\begin{aligned} \begin{aligned} p_{1}^{*}&=\frac{t(cx_{1}+tx_{1}+cx_{2}+tx_{2}+4c+2t)+2c^{2}}{3t+2c},\\ p_{2}^{*}&=\frac{t(-cx_{1}-tx_{1} -cx_{2}-tx_{2}+6c+4t)+2c^{2}}{3t+2c}. \end{aligned} \end{aligned}$$
(21)
$$\begin{aligned} \begin{aligned} Q_{1}^{*}&=\frac{(tx_{1}+tx_{2}+2c+2t)}{2(3t+2c)},\\ Q_{2}^{*}&=1-Q_{1}^{*}=\frac{(-tx_{1}-tx_{2}+2c+4t)}{2(3t+2c)}. \end{aligned} \end{aligned}$$
(22)

The equilibrium profits of the duopoly firms are calculated as:Footnote 11

$$\begin{aligned} \begin{aligned} \pi _{1}^{*}&=\frac{(tx_{1}+tx_{2}+2c+2t)^{2}(2t+c)}{4(3t+2c)^{2} }>0,\\ \pi _{2}^{*}&=\frac{(tx_{1}+tx_{2}-2c-4t)^{2}(2t+c)}{4(3t+2c)^{2}}>0. \end{aligned} \end{aligned}$$
(23)

The price-cost margin of firm 1 is calculated as:

$$\begin{aligned} p_{1}^{*}-{C}^{\prime }(Q_{1}^{*})=\frac{t(2c+2t+tx_{1} +tx_{2} )}{3t+2c}. \end{aligned}$$

Differentiating \(p_{1}^{*}-{C}^{\prime }(Q_{1}^{*})\) with respect to \(x_{i} \), for \(i=1,2\), yields:

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial \left[p_{1}^{*}-{C}^{\prime }(Q_{1}^{*})\right]}{\partial x_{i} }=\frac{t^{2}}{3t+2c}>0, \end{aligned}$$

which is unambiguously positive. Substituting \((x_{1} =0,x_{2} =1/2)\) into \(p_{1}^{*}-{C}^{\prime }(Q_{1}^{*})\) yields:

$$\begin{aligned} p_{1}^{*}(x_{1} =0,x_{2} =1/2)-{C}^{\prime }\left(Q_{1}^{*}(x_{1} =0,x_{2} =1/2)\right)=\frac{t(5t+4c)}{2(3t+2c)}>0. \end{aligned}$$

Substituting \((x_{1} =1/2,x_{2} =1)\) into \(p_{1}^{*}-{C}^{\prime } (Q_{1}^{*})-2t\) yields:

$$\begin{aligned} p_{1}^{*}(x_{1} =1/2,x_{2} =1)-{C}^{\prime }\left(Q_{1}^{*}(x_{1} =1/2,x_{2} =1)\right)-2t=-\frac{t(5t+4c)}{2(3t+2c)}<0. \end{aligned}$$

It follows that \(0<p_{1}^{*}-{C}^{\prime }(Q_{1}^{*})<2t\) for all separated location pairs.

The price-cost margin of firm 2 is calculated as:

$$\begin{aligned} p_{2}^{*}-{C}^{\prime }(Q_{2}^{*})=\frac{t(2c+4t-tx_{1} -tx_{2} )}{3t+2c}. \end{aligned}$$

Differentiating \(p_{2}^{*}-{C}^{\prime }(Q_{2}^{*})\) with respect to \(x_{i} \), for \(i=1,2\), yields:

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial \left[p_{2}^{*}-{C}^{\prime }(Q_{2}^{*})\right]}{\partial x_{i} }=-\frac{t^{2}}{3t+2c}<0, \end{aligned}$$

which is unambiguously negative. Substituting \((x_{1} =1/2,x_{2} =1)\) into \(p_{2}^{*}-{C}^{\prime }(Q_{2}^{*})\) yields:

$$\begin{aligned} p_{2}^{*}(x_{1} =1/2,x_{2} =1)-{C}^{\prime }\left(Q_{2}^{*}(x_{1} =1/2,x_{2} =1)\right)=\frac{t(5t+4c)}{2(3t+2c)}>0. \end{aligned}$$

Substituting \((x_{1} =0,x_{2} =1/2)\) into \(p_{2}^{*}-{C}^{\prime } (Q_{2}^{*})-2t\) yields:

$$\begin{aligned} p_{2}^{*}(x_{1} =0,x_{2} =1/2)-{C}^{\prime }\left(Q_{2}^{*}(x_{1} =0,x_{2} =1/2)\right)-2t=-\frac{t(5t+4c)}{2(3t+2c)}<0. \end{aligned}$$

It follows that \(0<p_{2}^{*}-{C}^{\prime }(Q_{2}^{*})<2t\) for all separated location pairs.

We next define two new functions \(f(x_{1},x_{2})\) and \(g(x_{1},x_{2})\) as:

$$\begin{aligned} f(x_{1},x_{2})&= Q_{1}^{*}-x_{1}.\\ g(x_{1},x_{2})&= x_{2}-Q_{1}^{*}. \end{aligned}$$

The first-order derivatives of \(f(x_{1},x_{2})\) and \(g(x_{1},x_{2})\) with respect to \(x_{2}\) are, respectively, calculated as:

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial f(x_{1},x_{2})}{\partial x_{2}}&= \frac{t}{2(3t+2c)}>0.\\ \frac{\partial g(x_{1},x_{2})}{\partial x_{2}}&= \frac{5t+4c}{2(3t+2c)}>0. \end{aligned}$$

Substituting \(x_{2}=1/2\) into \(f(x_{1},x_{2})\) and \(g(x_{1},x_{2})\), respectively, yields:

$$\begin{aligned} f(x_{1},x_{2} =1/2)&= \frac{(1-2x_{1})(5t+4c)}{4(3t+2c)}>0,\quad \forall x_{1}\in [0,1/2).\\ g(x_{1},x_{2}=1/2)&= \frac{t(1-2x_{1})}{4(3t+2c)}>0,\quad \forall x_{1}\in [0,1/2). \end{aligned}$$

It follows that \(f(x_{1},x_{2})>0\) and \(g(x_{1},x_{2})>0\), that is, \(x_{1}<Q_{1}^{*}<x_{2}\) (and thus \(0<Q_{1}^{*},Q_{2}^{*}<1)\) for all separated location pairs.

The first-order derivative of each firm’s equilibrium profit with respect to its own location is, respectively, calculated as:

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial \pi _{1}^{*}}{\partial x_{1}}&= \frac{t(2t+2c+tx_{1} +tx_{2})(2t+c)}{2(3t+2c)^{2}}>0,\\ \frac{\partial \pi _{2}^{*}}{\partial x_{2}}&= \frac{-t(4t+2c-tx_{1} -tx_{2})(2t+c)}{2(3t+2c)^{2}}<0, \end{aligned}$$

for all separated location pairs. The optimal undercutting profit of firm 1 is:

$$\begin{aligned} \pi _{1}^{u}(x_{1},x_{2})=p_{2}^{*}- t(x_{2}-x_{1})-c=\frac{t(4t+3c+cx_{1} +2tx_{1}-3cx_{2}-4tx_{2})}{3t+2c}. \end{aligned}$$

Differentiating the profit difference \(\pi _{1}^{*}(x_{1},x_{2})-\pi _{1} ^{u}(x_{1},x_{2})\) with respect to \(x_{1}\) and \(x_{2}\), respectively, we yield:

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial (\pi _{1}^{*}-\pi _{1}^{u})}{\partial x_{1}}&= \frac{-t(4t+2c-tx_{1}-tx_{2})(2t+c)}{2(3t+2c)^{2}}<0,\\ \frac{\partial (\pi _{1}^{*}-\pi _{1}^{u})}{\partial x_{2}}&= \frac{t\left[t(40c+28t+cx_{1}+2tx_{1}+cx_{2}+2tx_{2})+14c^{2}\right]}{2(3t+2c)^{2}}>0, \end{aligned}$$

for all separated location pairs.

The profit difference \(\pi _{1}^{*}(x_{1},x_{2})-\pi _{1}^{u}(x_{1},x_{2})\) of a limit as both firms approach the market center is calculated as:

$$\begin{aligned} \mathop {\lim }\limits _{x_{1}\rightarrow 1/2^{-} }\left[ {\pi _{1}^{*}(x_{2}\!=\!1/2)\!-\!\pi _{1}^{u}(x_{2}\!=\!1/2)}\right]&= \mathop {\lim }\limits _{x_{2}\rightarrow 1/2^{+} }\left[ {\pi _{1}^{*}(x_{1}=1/2)\!-\!\pi _{1}^{u}(x_{1}\!=\!1/2)}\right] \\&= \!-\!t/2\!+\!c/4>0,\;\text{ if}\;c>2t. \end{aligned}$$

It follows that if \(c>2t\), then duopoly firms agglomerating at the center, \((x_{1}=1/2,x_{2}=1/2)\), and choosing the same price, \((p_{1}=3c/2,p_{2} =3c/2)\), are the unique PCPNE outcome. \(\square \)

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Sun, CH., Lai, FC. Hotelling was right with decreasing returns to scale and a coalition-proof refinement. Ann Reg Sci 50, 953–971 (2013). https://doi.org/10.1007/s00168-012-0528-y

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s00168-012-0528-y

JEL Classification

Navigation