Skip to main content

A Child Garden of Concrete Giffen Utility Functions: A Theoretical Review

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
New Insights into the Theory of Giffen Goods

Part of the book series: Lecture Notes in Economics and Mathematical Systems ((LNE,volume 655))

Abstract

We present a theoretical review of the literature on concrete utility functions for Giffen and inferior goods within the context of the utility maximisation problem under a budget restriction and provide new functional forms. The presentation is organised around the specific properties such utility functions have. These properties include strict increasingness, quasi-concavity, and the applicability of Gossen’s second law.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 84.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 109.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    An exception is homogeneity.

  2. 2.

    For example in the labour-leisure-model with a Leontief utility function u(l, x) = min(l, x) and budget restriction wl + px ≤ wT, the demand function for leisure is strictly increasing.

  3. 3.

    See the contribution [14] in this book for a specific problem for the case of n goods.

  4. 4.

    In the case the domain is a subset of \({\mathbb{R}}_{+}^{2}\) it is easier to provide Giffen utility functions with reasonable properties. (Also see [3].)

  5. 5.

    Doi et al. [2] is reprinted in this book.

  6. 6.

    Also we mention here [17] dealing with a Giffen utility function on \({\mathbb{R}}_{++} \times {\mathbb{R}}_{+}\) (for which there does not exist an ‘obvious counterpart’ on \({\mathbb{R}}_{+}^{2}\)). Also [17] did not seem to be aware of [19].

  7. 7.

    Also see the contribution [5] in this book for other relationships for Giffen goods.

  8. 8.

    In doing so we correct in particular fallacies in [615].

  9. 9.

    The interpretation of (4) is as follows: it only is present for \(({x}_{1},{x}_{2}) \in {\mathbb{R}}_{++}^{2}\) in which u is partially differentiable.

  10. 10.

    See for example [1].

  11. 11.

    In this context, one could wish to add here ‘and that this system easily can be solved by hand’, because if it is difficult to solve the system of equations, the utility function is not really appropriate for text book purposes.

  12. 12.

    Note that for small m a maximiser may be not unique, as can be seen from Fig. 1 by looking to its south west corner.

  13. 13.

    In all our figures the x 1 is on the abscissa and x 2 on the ordinate.

  14. 14.

    Please note the scaling-down on the abscissa.

  15. 15.

    Therefore in [15] also a ‘repaired’ version of u 1 T was used to improve the properties of the indifference sets. The repair consisted on modifying u 1 T for x 1 > 50. But this only improved these properties a little bit (the modified function still is not quasi-concave) and lead to a piece-wise definition, which made this function more complicated and thereby destroyed the partially differentiability of the utility function (on \({\mathbb{R}}_{++}^{2}\)).

  16. 16.

    Even if it can with other parameter values, then it is correct to say that this problem first was solved in [15].

  17. 17.

    But not necessarily interior for positive budget.

  18. 18.

    Even demand functions that are not log-convex seem to be rare.

  19. 19.

    But not smooth.

  20. 20.

    Furthermore it may be worthwhile to note that in Example 2 the maximisers are in the good region D (as the proof of the example shows).

  21. 21.

    In fact in [6] the correctness of the claim that the utility function is inferior is not proved. There just is referred to a book with a not correct analysis: it is stated that the formula for \(\hat{\mathbf{x}}(m)\) in Example 8 for the case \(m > 2{p}_{2}\sqrt{\alpha }\) and t(m) > 0 also is correct in case t(m) ≤ 0. However, for \(\alpha = \frac{1} {10},\;{p}_{1} = 1,\;{p}_{2} = 1,\;m = \frac{21} {10}{p}_{2}\sqrt{a}\), one has t(m) < 0 which (now referring to our proof in the appendix) implies \(U(m/{p}_{1}) > U({y}_{-}(m)/{p}_{1})\) from which it follows that (0, m ∕ p 1) is the unique maximiser instead of \(({y}_{-}(m)/{p}_{1},{y}_{+}(m)/{p}_{2})\).

  22. 22.

    Here is a proof: let f be the function \({c}_{1}^{-}- {c}_{2}\). Suppose m is a zero of f. Then \({(\alpha /(m + 1) - \alpha /2)}^{2} ={ (\sqrt{{\alpha }^{2 } /{(m + 1)}^{2 } - 2} -\sqrt{({\alpha }^{2 } - 8m)/2}\;)}^{2}\). Evaluating this equation, next simplifying and then squaring the result after appropriate rearranging, leads to \(2{m}^{4} - ({\alpha }^{2} + 4){m}^{2} + 2m{\alpha }^{2} - {\alpha }^{2} + 2 = 0\). Because \(2{m}^{4} - ({\alpha }^{2} + 4){m}^{2} + 2m{\alpha }^{2} - {\alpha }^{2} + 2 = 2{(m - 1)}^{2}(m - \alpha /\sqrt{2} - 1)(m + \alpha /\sqrt{2} + 1)\), we can conclude that the zeros of f are 1 and \(\alpha /\sqrt{2} - 1\). Noting that \( f\prime (1) = (\sqrt{{\alpha }^{2 } - 8} - a) < 0\) and that f is continuous, it follows that f < 0 on the interval \((1,\alpha /\sqrt{2} - 1)\), as desired.

    It would be interesting to understand the deeper meaning why the inequality c 1  − (m) < c 2(m), that in fact came up in a natural way, holds.

  23. 23.

    A straightforward calculation shows that

    $$t\prime \,=\,\frac{1} {4} \frac{\left (\sqrt{{m}^{2 } \,-\, 4{p}_{2 }^{2 }\alpha }\left (m\,+\,\sqrt{{m}^{2 } \,-\, 4{p}_{2 }^{2 }\alpha }\right )\right ){e}^{\frac{{\left (m+\sqrt{{m}^{2 } -4{p}_{2 }^{2 }\alpha }\right )}^{2}} {8{p}_{2}^{2}} } \left (m\,+\,\sqrt{{m}^{2 } \,-\, 4{p}_{2 }^{2 }\alpha }\right ){\left (\frac{m-\sqrt{{m}^{2 } -4{p}_{2 }^{2 }\alpha }} {2m} \right )}^{\alpha }} {m{p}_{2}^{2}\sqrt{{m}^{2 } - 4{p}_{2 }^{2 }\alpha }}.$$

    This implies that t′ > 0 and thus that t is strictly increasing. Therefore for m 0 even each \({m}_{0} > 2{p}_{2}\sqrt{\alpha }\) with t(m 0) > 0 can be taken.

References

  1. E. Balder. Exact and useful optimization methods for microeconomics. 655:19–35, 2011.

    Google Scholar 

  2. J. Doi, K. Iwasa, and K. Shimomura. Giffen behavior independent of the wealth level. Economic Theory, 41:247–267, 2009 and 655:99–118, 2011.

    Google Scholar 

  3. R. Haagsma. Notes on some theories of giffen behaviour. 655:5–18, 2011.

    Google Scholar 

  4. K. De Jaegher. Asymmetric substitutability: Theory and some applications. Economic Inquiry, 47(4):838-855, 2009.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  5. K. de Jaegher. Giffen behaviour and strong assymmetric gross substitutability. 655:51–34, 2011.

    Google Scholar 

  6. H. Liebhafsky. New thoughts about inferior goods. American Economic Review, 59: 931–934, 1969.

    Google Scholar 

  7. R. Lipsey and G. Rosenbluth. A contribution to the new theory of demand: a rehabilitation of the Giffen good. Revue canadienne d’Economique, IV(2):131–163, 1971.

    Google Scholar 

  8. A. Mas-Colell, M. D. Whinston, and J. R. Green. Microeconomic Theory. Oxford University Press, New York, 1995.

    Google Scholar 

  9. P. Moffatt. Is Giffen behaviour compatible with the axioms of consumer theory? Journal of Mathematical Economics, 37:259–267, 2002.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  10. P. Moffatt. A Class of Indirect Utility Functions Predicting Giffen Behaviour. 655: 119–129 2011.

    Google Scholar 

  11. P. H. M. von Mouche and W. Pijnappel. On the definitions of Giffen and inferior goods. 655:60–103, 2011.

    Google Scholar 

  12. P. G. Moffatt, P. H. M. von Mouche, and E. Smits. On concrete Giffen utility functions with very nice theoretical properties. In preparation, 2011.

    Google Scholar 

  13. P. Sørenson. Simple utility functions with Giffen demand. Economic Theory, 31:367–70, 2006.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  14. P. Sørenson. Giffen demand for several goods. 655:97–104, 2011.

    Google Scholar 

  15. U. Spiegel. The case of a ‘Giffen good’. Journal of Economic Education, 25:137–147, 1994.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  16. E. Silberberg and D. Walker. A modern analysis of Giffen’s paradox. International Economic Review, 25(3):687–694, 1984.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  17. D. Vandermeulen. Upward sloping demand curves without the Giffen paradox. American Economic Review, 2:453–458, 1972.

    Google Scholar 

  18. C. Weber. The case of a Giffen good: Comment. Journal of Economic Education, 28:36–44, 1997.

    Google Scholar 

  19. H. Wold. On Giffen’s paradox. Nordisk Tidsskrift for Teknisk Økonomi, 12:283–290, 1948.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Wim Heijman .

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2012 Springer Berlin Heidelberg

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Heijman, W., von Mouche, P. (2012). A Child Garden of Concrete Giffen Utility Functions: A Theoretical Review. In: Heijman, W., von Mouche, P. (eds) New Insights into the Theory of Giffen Goods. Lecture Notes in Economics and Mathematical Systems, vol 655. Springer, Berlin, Heidelberg. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-642-21777-7_6

Download citation

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-642-21777-7_6

  • Published:

  • Publisher Name: Springer, Berlin, Heidelberg

  • Print ISBN: 978-3-642-21776-0

  • Online ISBN: 978-3-642-21777-7

  • eBook Packages: Business and EconomicsEconomics and Finance (R0)

Publish with us

Policies and ethics