Skip to main content

Dynamic Externalities: Theory and Empirical Analysis

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
A New Perspective on Agglomeration Economies in Japan

Part of the book series: New Frontiers in Regional Science: Asian Perspectives ((NFRSASIPER,volume 20))

  • 552 Accesses

Abstract

This chapter focuses on dynamic externalities that are a source of competitive advantages, and reviews the related empirical studies. Research on technical-knowledge spillover, the core of dynamic externalities, is being widely conducted, mainly in the field of industrial organization theory. However, there are few empirical studies that have considered technical-knowledge spillover from the viewpoint of industrial agglomeration. Some studies estimate the extent and type of dynamic externalities, and find evidence consistent with dynamic externalities. Despite the different data sources used, methodologies are similar. This chapter reviews the main methodologies of dynamic externalities, and discusses empirical analysis issues of previous studies.

This chapter is based on Otsuka (2004) “Dynamic externalities of industrial agglomeration: A survey,” published in Okayama Economic Review (Vol. 35, No. 4, pp. 27–50, in Japanese).

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

eBook
USD 16.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 119.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD 119.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    However, Krugman (1991) is an exception. Although he recognized the importance of technical-knowledge spillover, he argued that the effects of the labor market and the intermediate goods market are linked to the dynamic aspect of agglomeration economies.

  2. 2.

    Even as the shift to IT has progressed, it is known that face-to-face communication remains important (Gaspar and Glaeser 1998).

  3. 3.

    An industrial cluster has been defined as “geographic concentrations of interconnected companies, specialized suppliers, service providers, firms in related industries, and associated institutions (e.g., universities, standards agencies, trade associations) in a particular field that compete but also cooperate.” (Porter 1990).

  4. 4.

    It is important to note that the spatial clustering explained by Porter’s theory cannot be uniformly defined. In many cases, the industrial clusters do not have a uniform definition in terms of scope and are made up of industries that belong to different standard industry classifications. Strictly speaking, the definition of a cluster is determined by the strength of the linkage between industries, and it is considered that these are rarely consistent with the standard industry classifications. In the conventional classifications relating to manufacturing industries and service industries, the classifications are extremely vague when considering the linkages between industries, so it is difficult to accurately ascertain the linkages between them. Also, even if discussing only one industry, the linkages that exist between industries cannot be seen, so it is considered that the effects that clusters have on competition will not be considered (Porter 1990, 1998, 2000).

  5. 5.

    It is known that local areas’ historical production environment has important effects on industries’ locations (Rauch 1993b).

  6. 6.

    There are many studies that have verified the role played by technical-knowledge spillover in the locations of emerging industries (high-tech industries). For example, Jaffe et al. (1993) showed that in many cases, new patents will be created based on the existing patents in the surrounding area. Also, it is known that wages tend to be high in regions where human capital is accumulating (Rauch 1993a).

  7. 7.

    Refer to Greene (2017) for the problems in estimate values that are caused by omitting important variables.

  8. 8.

    Innovation includes “product innovation,” such as the development of products, and “process innovation,” such as improvements to manufacturing processes.

  9. 9.

    Strictly speaking, total factor productivity is not the same as the Solow residual (Hall 1990). Total factor productivity is the aggregate output divided by the aggregate input, and it does not assume either constant returns to scale from production technologies, producers’ profit maximization, or a perfectly competitive market. Therefore, growth in total factor productivity is not necessarily consistent with the rate of technological progress.

  10. 10.

    There are various indices beside the ones introduced here. This section introduces mainly indices which are used in typical empirical studies such as Glaeser et al. (1992).

  11. 11.

    Refer to the appendix for the derivation.

  12. 12.

    In addition, a point to be aware of with regards to the data is the measurement of inputs. There are various ways of measuring them, including those that take into consideration the quality of capital, the capital utilization rate, the quality of labor, and working hours.

  13. 13.

    Refer to the appendix for the derivation.

  14. 14.

    There is also the empirical study of Knarvik and Steen (1999). They measured the size of “pecuniary externalities” in a form that distinguished them from “technological externalities” to clarify the external effects between individual industries forming a marine industrial cluster in Norway. However, the analytical model they used lacked a theoretical basis, and measurement bias may have occurred in their measurements of external effects from the impact of the intermediate input goods’ factor distribution ratio.

References

  • Arrow KJ. The economic implications of learning by doing. Rev Econ Stud. 1962;29(3):155–73.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Barro RJ. Economic growth in a cross section of countries. Q J Econ. 1991;106:407–43.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bartelsman EJ, Caballero RJ, Lyons RK. Customer- and supplier-driven externalities. Am Econ Rev. 1994;84(4):1075–84.

    Google Scholar 

  • Basu S, Fernald JG. Are apparent productive spillovers a figment of specification error? J Monet Econ. 1995;36(1):165–88.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Basu S, Fernald JG. Returns to scale in U.S. production: Estimates and implications. J Polit Econ. 1997;105(2):249–83.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Basu S, Fernald JG. Aggregate productivity and aggregate technology. Eur Econ Rev. 2002;46(6):963–91.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Beeson PE. Total factor productivity growth and agglomeration economies in manufacturing, 1959–73. J Reg Sci. 1987;27(2):183–99.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Beeson PE. Sources of the decline of manufacturing in large metropolitan areas. J Urban Econ. 1990;28(1):71–86.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Benarroch M. Returns to scale in Canadian manufacturing: an interprovincial comparison. Can J Econ. 1997;30(4):1083–103.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Burnside C. Production function regressions, returns to scale, and externalities. J Monet Econ. 1996;37(2):177–201.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Caballero RJ, Lyons RK. Internal versus externalities in European industry. Eur Econ Rev. 1990;34(4):805–26.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Caballero RJ, Lyons RK. External effects in U.S. procyclical productivity. J Monet Econ. 1992;29(2):209–25.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Carlino G, Kerr WR. Agglomeration and innovation. In: Duranton JH, Strange W, editors. Handbook of regional and urban economics, volume 5A. Amsterdam: Elsevier; 2015. p. 349–403.

    Google Scholar 

  • Davis DR, Weinstein DE. Economic geography and regional production structure: an empirical investigation. Eur Econ Rev. 1999;43(2):379–407.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dekle R. Industrial concentration and regional growth: evidence from the prefectures. Rev Econ Stat. 2002;84(2):310–5.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Duranton G, Puga D. Micro-foundations of urban agglomeration economies. In: Henderson JV, Thisse JF, editors. Handbook of regional and urban economics, vol 4. Amsterdam: Elsevier; 2004.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fujita M, Thisse J. Economics of agglomeration. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press; 2002.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Fujita M, Krugman P, Venables A. The spatial economy: cities, regions, and international trade. Cambridge: MIT Press; 1999.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gaspar J, Glaeser EL. Information technology and the future of cities. J Urban Econ. 1998;43(1):136–56.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Glaeser EL, Kallal HD, Scheinkman JA, Shleifer A. Growth in cities. J Polit Econ. 1992;100(6):1126–52.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Greene WH. Econometric analysis. 8th ed. New York: NY Pearson; 2017.

    Google Scholar 

  • Griliches Z. The search for R&D spillovers. Scand J Econ. 1992;94(0):S29–47.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Grossman GM, Helpman E. Innovation and growth in the global economy. Cambridge MA: MIT Press; 1991.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hall RE. Invariance properties of Solow’s productivity residual. In: Diamond P, editor. Growth/productivity/unemployment: essays to celebrate bob Solow’s birthday. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press; 1990.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hanson GH. Regional adjustment to trade liberalization. Reg Sci Urban Econ. 1998;28(4):419–44.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Henderson JV. Externalities and industrial development. J Urban Econ. 1997;42(3):449–70.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Henderson JV. Marshall’s scale economies. J Urban Econ. 2003;53(1):1–28.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Henderson JV, Kuncoro A, Turner M. Industrial development of cities. J Polit Econ. 1995;103(5):1067–90.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hirschman JV. The strategy of economic development. New Haven: Yale University Press; 1958.

    Google Scholar 

  • Jacobs J. The economy of cities. New York: Vintage Books; 1969.

    Google Scholar 

  • Jaffe AB, Trajtenberg M, Henderson R. Geographic localization of knowledge spillovers as evidenced by patent citations. Q J Econ. 1993;108(3):577–98.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Knarvik KHM, Steen F. Self-reinforcing agglomerations? An empirical industry study. Scand J Econ. 1999;101(4):515–32.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Krugman P. Geography and trade. Cambridge, MA/London: MIT Press; 1991.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lucas RE. On the mechanics of economic development. J Monet Econ. 1988;22(1):3–42.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lucio JJ, Herce JA, Goicolea A. The effects of externalities on productivity growth in Spanish industry. Reg Sci Urban Econ. 2002;32(2):241–58.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mano Y, Otsuka K. Agglomeration economies and geographical concentration of industries: a case study of manufacturing sectors in postwar Japan. J Jpn Int Econ. 2000;14(3):189–203.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Marshall A. Principles of economics. London: Macmillan; 1890.

    Google Scholar 

  • McDonald JF. Fundamentals of urban economics. Upper Saddle River: Prentice Hall; 1997.

    Google Scholar 

  • Otsuka A. Dynamic externalities of industrial agglomeration: a survey. Okayama Econ Rev. 2004;35(4):27–50. (in Japanese)

    Google Scholar 

  • Oulton N. Increasing returns and externalities in UK manufacturing: myth or reality? J Ind Econ. 1996;44(1):99–113.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Porter ME. The competitive advantage of nations. New York: Free Press; 1990.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Porter ME. On competition. Boston: Harvard Business School Press; 1998.

    Google Scholar 

  • Porter ME. Location, competition, and economic development: local clusters in a global economy. Econ Dev Q. 2000;14(1):15–34.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rauch JE. Productivity gains from geographic concentration of human capital: evidence from the cities. J Urban Econ. 1993a;34(3):380–400.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rauch JE. Does history matter only when it matters little? The case of city-industry location. Q J Econ. 1993b;108(3):843–67.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Romer PM. Increasing returns and long-run growth. J Polit Econ. 1986;94(5):1002–37.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Romer PM. Endogenous technical change. J Polit Econ. 1990;98(5):71–102.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schumpeter JA. The theory of economic development. London: Oxford University Press; 1934.

    Google Scholar 

  • Solow RM. Technical change and the aggregate production function. Rev Econ Stat. 1957;39(3):312–20.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Appendix: Solow Residual Measurement Bias

Appendix: Solow Residual Measurement Bias

Two points are described in this appendix, as problems related to the measurement of the Solow residual discussed in this chapter: (1) the presence of measurement bias that occurs when assuming perfect competition and constant returns to scale, and (2) differences using value-added versus gross output as the output element.

  1. 1.

    The basic model

For simplicity, the Hicks neutral-type production function shall be assumed.

$$ V= AF\left(K,L\right), $$
(A.1)

where, V is the value added as the output element, and K and L are the capital input and the labor input. A represents the production technologies, and technological progress can be ascertained through the production function shift term.

Conducting a logarithmic total differential on (A.1), and dividing both sides by V, the formula becomes as follows.

$$ \frac{dV}{V}=\frac{dA}{A}+A\frac{\partial F}{\partial K}\frac{K}{V}\frac{dK}{K}+A\frac{\partial F}{\partial L}\frac{L}{V}\frac{dL}{L}. $$
(A.2)

Here, when taking x = log X for the arbitrary variable X, (A.2) can be rewritten as follows.

$$ dv= da+A\frac{\partial F}{\partial K}\frac{K}{V} dk+A\frac{\partial F}{\partial L}\frac{L}{V} dl. $$
(A.3)

Assuming perfect competition, (A.4) is established from the first-order condition for profit maximization.

$$ A\frac{\partial F}{\partial K}=\frac{P_K}{P},\kern0.30em A\frac{\partial F}{\partial L}=\frac{P_L}{P}, $$
(A.4)

where P is the output price, while P K and P L represent the capital and labor prices, respectively.

Further, assuming the condition of constant returns to scale, the following formula is established from Euler’s theorem.

$$ A\frac{\partial F}{\partial K}\frac{K}{V}+A\frac{\partial F}{\partial L}\frac{L}{V}=1. $$
(A.5)

From this relation between (A.4) and (A.5),

$$ PQ={P}_KK+{P}_LL $$
(A.6)

is established as “exhaustion of the total product theorem.” Therefore, when rewriting (A.3) from (A.4) and (A.5), the following formula is established.

$$ dv= da+\left(1-{s}_L^v\right) dk+{s}_L^v dl $$
(A.7)

where, \( {s}_L^v \) is labor share.

$$ {s}_L^v\equiv \frac{P_LL}{PV}. $$

Therefore, the value-added base Solow residual (SR v) becomes as follows,

$$ {SR}^v\equiv dv-\left[\left(1-{s}_L^v\right) dk+{s}_L^v dl\right]= da. $$
(A.8)

The Solow residual is consistent with the rate of technological progress.

  1. 2.

    Markup and economies of scale

Next, it is assumed that producers have “monopoly power” and do not set price equal to marginal cost. Then, from the first-order condition for profit maximization by producers with monopoly power, the formula becomes as follows.

$$ A\frac{\partial F}{\partial K}=\frac{P_K}{P}\mu, \kern0.30em A\frac{\partial F}{\partial L}=\frac{P_L}{P}\mu, $$
(A.9)

where, μ is the price markup and is defined as the ratio of price P and the marginal cost MC.

$$ \mu \equiv \frac{P}{MC}=\frac{\eta -1}{\eta }. $$

η is the price elasticity of demand.

Further, assuming increasing returns to scale,

$$ A\frac{\partial F}{\partial K}\frac{K}{V}+A\frac{\partial F}{\partial L}\frac{L}{V}=\gamma $$
(A.10)

is established. γ is the parameter indicating homogeneity.

From this relation between (A.9) and (A.10), the formula becomes as follows.

$$ PQ=\frac{\mu }{\gamma}\left[{P}_KK+{P}_LL\right]. $$
(A.11)

Therefore, if μ = γ is not established, exhaustion of the total product theorem is also not established.

On rewriting (A.3) from (A.9) and (A.10), the formula becomes as follows.

$$ dv= da+\left(\gamma -\mu {s}_L^v\right) dk+\mu {s}_L^v dl. $$
(A.12)

In other words,

$$ {\displaystyle \begin{array}{c}{SR}^v\equiv dv-\left[\left(1-{s}_L^v\right) dk+{s}_L^v dl\right]\\ {}= da+{s}_L^v\left(\mu -1\right)\left( dl- dk\right)+\left(\gamma -1\right) dk.\end{array}} $$
(A.13)

In the event of the existence of imperfect competition and economies of scale, μ > 1 and γ > 1. Under these conditions, the value-added based Solow residual is not consistent with technological progress, and measurement bias occurs according to the degree of imperfect competition and economies of scale. Therefore, measurement bias according to imperfect competition and economies of scale also occurs for the effects of industrial agglomerations that are measured as an element of the Solow residual.

  1. 3.

    Gross output and value-added as the output element

Finally, the Solow residual is different when gross output is used as the output element compared to when value-added is used.

With gross output as Y and intermediate input goods as M, the respective share for labor and intermediate input goods on a total output basis are as follows.

$$ {s}_L\equiv \frac{P_LL}{PY},{s}_M\equiv \frac{P_MM}{PY}. $$

According to Basu and Fernald (1997, 2002), the value-added growth rate dv is expressed as follows.

$$ dv=\frac{dV}{V}=\frac{PdY-{P}_M dM}{PY-{P}_MM}=\frac{dy-{s}_M dm}{1-{s}_M}. $$
(A.14)

Then, introducing (A.7) into (A.14) and arranging it based on (A.8),

$$ dy=\left(1-{s}_M\right)\left[{SR}^v+\left\{\left(1-{s}_L^v\right) dk+{s}_L^v dl\right\}\right]+{s}_M dm $$
(A.15)

is obtained.

Here, the gross-output based Solow residual (SR) is defined as follows.

$$ SR\equiv dy-\left[\left(1-{s}_L-{s}_M\right) dk+{s}_L dl+{s}_M dm\right]. $$
(A.16)

Therefore, arranging (A.15),

$$ {SR}^v=\frac{1}{1-{s}_M} SR $$
(A.17)

is established. This indicates that the Solow residual based on value-added is not independent of the variations in the share of intermediate input s M .

  1. 4.

    Summary

As was shown above, as perfect competition and constant returns to scale are assumed when measuring the Solow residual, if producers face imperfect competition and possess production technologies providing increasing returns to scale, measurement bias occurs for the Solow residual. Further, when using value-added to measure the Solow residual, the value-added based Solow residual is affected by variations in the share of intermediate input. Therefore, it is judged highly likely that systematic bias occurs in the dynamic externalities evaluated using the value-added based production function because of the influence of the share of intermediate goods.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2017 Springer Nature Singapore Pte Ltd.

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Otsuka, A. (2017). Dynamic Externalities: Theory and Empirical Analysis. In: A New Perspective on Agglomeration Economies in Japan. New Frontiers in Regional Science: Asian Perspectives, vol 20. Springer, Singapore. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-981-10-6490-6_5

Download citation

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/978-981-10-6490-6_5

  • Published:

  • Publisher Name: Springer, Singapore

  • Print ISBN: 978-981-10-6489-0

  • Online ISBN: 978-981-10-6490-6

  • eBook Packages: Economics and FinanceEconomics and Finance (R0)

Publish with us

Policies and ethics