Keywords

9.1 Introduction

In April 2013, the Arms Trade Treaty (ATT) was opened for signature after the adaptation by the United Nations General Assembly and entered into force in December 2014. Currently 110 countries have signed and ratified the ATT. Its roots can be traced back to the late 1980s and was a response to the growing concern on the unregulated nature of the global trade in conventional weapons in the preceding decades. Especially the rapid spread of arms in less democratic countries created a serious risk for human security in these countries. The aim of the ATT was to regulate the global arms transfers by establishing a minimal legal basis and improving transparency and cooperation among countries. It is not the first and will for sure not be the last international treaty to manage the international transfer of strategic goods. Currently, there are more than twenty international arms control and non-proliferation treaties in place that are open to all states to become a member. Some are used as ways to stop the spread of certain military technologies such as nuclear weaponry or missile technology (i.e., Non-Proliferation Treaty). Other arms control agreements are entered to limit the trade of conventional arms to state and non-state violent actors (i.e., Arms Trade Treaty).

One important broad question that still is largely unanswered is why some states join certain international treaties, but other states do not? This question is not only relevant from an academic but even more so from a political point of view when drafting new treaties. The typical answer to this question provided in the existing literature is that states join international agreements which are in accordance with their economic interests.Footnote 1 However, not all treaties provide obvious economic benefits to states. When there are no direct monetary gains from international cooperation, as it is the case in arms control treaties, there have to be other benefits of treaty ratification. An alternative motive to ratify arms control treaties builds on the argument that non-proliferation of conventional arms and WMD would bring substantial benefits in ending expensive arms races and redirect resources to more productive purposes.Footnote 2 Broadly speaking, these benefits can roughly be divided into two categories. First, signing an arms control treaty might provide some strategic benefits as state leaders benefit from peaceful international relations, increased gains from trade and from the ability to enforce their own policy goals in the international arena. Voters are likely to reward this strategic policy. This will, in turn, increase the likelihood that incumbent officials will be re-elected during the next elections.Footnote 3 Second, state leaders face costs of arms races and escalation of international conflicts. The ratification of arms control treaties reduces the risk of war for certain countries and therefore reduces the costs of war and arms races. Thus, the conclusion of arms control treaties increases international security and stability, because these agreements have an important signalling function. They provide information about peaceful intentions and the willingness to employ offensive capabilities because they require all treaty partners to reduce their offensive weapons arsenal or to limit the range of weapons used.Footnote 4 With such a signal, states can escape or slow down arms races and prevent conflicts from escalation to war.

Additionally, many studies examine the institutionalization of treaties through ratification.Footnote 5 A possible key element that affects the decision of whether or not to ratify a particular treaty is the legal tradition of a country. This issue is mainly neglected in the current literature. The world’s legal systems can roughly be divided between two major traditions: English common law and French civil law. Since treaties are legally binding agreements between two or more states, they cannot be adapted to local needs and circumstances. Treaties are therefore generally inconsistent with the gradual, organic evolution of law that is essential in the common-law system. As a result, common-law countries hold a distaste for treaties. In turn, treaties are a more comfortable fit with the civil-law tradition that neatly distinguishes between law and non-law. Consequently, civil-law countries are expected to ratify binding international obligations.

The aim of this chapter is to provide an insight into the relationship between the legal tradition of a country and the ratification of arms control treaties. For this purpose, an ordered logit model is estimated including 171 countries. The main findings of our study are in accordance with our expectations. Common-law countries ratify fewer arms control treaties compared to civil-law countries.

The remainder of the chapter is structured as follows. Section 9.2 reviews the literature relevant for explaining the relationship between arms control treaties ratification and legal origin. Section 9.3 describes the data and methodology used, while Sect. 9.4 shows our empirical results. Last, Sect. 9.5 offers a conclusions and discussion.

9.2 Legal Origin and Arms Control Treaties

The international transfer of sensitive and military-strategic goods, including nuclear weapons, conventional arms and dual-use goods, are subject to specific international treaties. This framework is designed to prevent weapons systems, technologies, knowledge and services, posing threats to international safety and security, from falling in the hands of violent state and non-state actors. International treaties are widely used as a common tool of global governance the last decades. A treaty is a legally binding agreement between two or more nations and or organization that is recognized and given effect under international law. One of the most important principles of treaty law is pacta sunt servanda (i.e., the pact must be respected), meaning that treaties are binding on the parties by consent and must be performed by them in good faith.Footnote 6

The existing literature shows that the ratification of a particular treaty is mainly determined by political and economic interests. One important issue in this debate that has not been explored so far is whether the decision to ratify international treaties is affected by the legal tradition of a country, as this will shape the incentives of policymakers. Juridical scholars typically classify the legal tradition according to: (i) historical background and development of the legal system; (ii) theories and hierarchies of sources of laws; (iii) the working methodology of jurists; (iv) the characteristics of the legal concepts; (v) the legal institutions of the system; and (vi) the divisions of law employed.Footnote 7 Using this framework, legal origin theory formalizes the different perspectives about law and its purpose and classify the legal origin of a country into two secular principal traditions: common law and civil law, and several sub-traditions—French, German, socialist, and Scandinavian—within the civil-law tradition. Generally, the two principal types of legal origins emerged from the different views of law developed in England and France centuries ago. These contrasting views yielded diverging ideas and strategies that are not only incorporated into specific legal rules and codes, but also into the organization of the legal system. Civil law encourages a centralized system where the government directly addresses market failures, whereas the more decentralized common-law approach favours contract and private litigation. The two principal legal traditions have been transplanted through colonization and conquests to the vast majority of the jurisdictions in the world by a group of European countries.Footnote 8

The common-law legal tradition was developed in England first and later spread across the colonies of the British empire, including the United States, Canada, Australia, India, South Africa. English common law developed because landed aristocrats and merchants wanted a system of law that would provide strong protections for property and contract rights, and limit the crown’s ability to interfere in markets.Footnote 9 The judge has a central role in the common-law system. The law is formed by appellate judges who establish binding precedents by resolving case-specific disputes. Dispute resolution tends to be adversarial rather than inquisitorial. Judicial independence from both the executive and legislature are central. The civil-law tradition is the oldest, the most influential, and the most widely distributed around the world, especially after so many transition economies after the end of the Cold War have returned to it. It originates from Roman law and uses statutes and comprehensive codes as a primary means of ordering legal material. Dispute resolution tends to be inquisitorial rather than adversarial. In the civil-law system statutes and comprehensive codes serve as the primary means of ordering legal material, with a key role for legal scholars who ascertain and formulate rules.

It has been widely documented in the political science and economics literature that legal origin significantly influences the political decisions on implementing and enforcing various kinds of laws and regulations. For instance, empirical analyses demonstrate that common-law states are more market-oriented by having more economic freedom, stronger investor protection, more private ownership, more flexible labour markets, less burden of firm entry regulations and more developed capital markets than states with civil law, Islamic law, or mixed legal traditions. In contrast, civil law is associated with a heavier hand of government ownership and state-desired allocations. In other words, civil law is “policy implementing”, while common law is “dispute resolving”.Footnote 10 These economic outcomes are not only explained by the content or application of law, but also by the organization of the law system in countries. Subsequent studies have found that common law is associated with a lower formalism of judicial procedures and a greater judicial independence than civil law. These results are associated with better contract enforcement and greater security of property rights.Footnote 11

The influence of legal traditions reaches beyond national boundaries into the realm of international commitments. A series of studies identify differences between civil-law and common-law countries in terms of their willingness to join treaties or accept the jurisdiction of international courts.Footnote 12 The main conclusion shared among these studies suggest that common-law countries are less likely to show such willingness compared to civil-law countries.

One essential element of common-law systems is their bottom-up evolution. Law is made by judges as a means to solve specific social problems. Legal rules evolve gradually and are sensitive to the social environment in which they operate and correspond with its values.Footnote 13 International treaties, however, are inconsistent with the notion of local, organic, and socially adaptive law. Foreign documents produced by international political deals are imposed top-down on the legal system and do not necessarily reflect its values. As a result, international treaties may not fit comfortably with its existing legal culture of rules and practices. These concerns lead common-law countries to greatly value the flexibility of nonbinding international rules and the liberty to modify or disregard provisions that are incompatible with domestic laws and policies. Additionally, given the power and independence of judges in common-law systems, governments feel uncertain about the consequences of treaty ratification and may find it difficult to escape treaty obligations.Footnote 14 To influence state behaviour, international agreements typically require incorporation into the domestic legal system and integration into domestic institutions. Implementation—the introduction of international rules and norms into formal legal and policy mechanisms within a state—is a key process in the translation of these rules and norms into changes in actual behaviour.Footnote 15 When incorporating a treaty into the domestic legal system, local law has to be brought into line with the treaty’s legal obligations. In a common-law system, assessing the conformity of local law with the treaty—and making necessary changes—presents a challenge since the common law is not found in a single major code. Rather, law exists as an amalgam of statutes and legal precedents. Combing through the numerous legal sources and adjusting them to the treaty could be time-consuming and difficult.

Whereas common-law systems are less comfortable with legally binding agreements, the reverse might be true for civil-law systems as the flexibility of the legal rule comes at the expense of its certainty—and it is the latter that civil law values more. In contrast, nonbinding agreements do not easily fit civil law’s emphasis on certainty, clarity, and formal legal sources, and its neat distinction between law and non-law. Civil law sees formal international rules as the preeminent means for governing interstate relations.Footnote 16

To summarize the discussion above, common-law systems are more comfortable with nonbinding agreements than with treaties as they are less flexible and are an uneasy fit with the common-law legal tradition. By contrast, civil law’s emphasis on certainty, the preference for formal, established sources and the separation of law and non-law will result in an inclination toward treaties and a distaste toward nonbinding commitments. Treaties fall neatly in the legal domain and are the international equivalent of the civil code that is a main pillar of the civil-law system.Footnote 17 Hence, civil-law systems feel more comfortable with treaties than with nonbinding agreements. Nonbinding international instruments are relegated to the non-law sphere and are not seen as an established source of international law. Overall, given civil-law’s affinity for binding agreements and common law’s aversion to them, we would expect a higher ratification rate of international arms control treaties among civil-law countries.

9.3 Data and Methodology

9.3.1 Treaties and Legal Origin Data

We have developed a database on the membership status of states in international treaties concerning weapons based on the information provided by the United Nations Office for Disarmament Affairs (UNODA). The analysis here focuses on those treaties including the additional protocols that are open for all states to become member of the treaty. Including all treaties would inflate ratification for some countries, compared to others which have not the option to become a member of those treaties. Following Brender protocols of the Convention on Certain Conventional Weapons which require individual ratification of members will be dealt with as if they are a treaty of their own. These protocols are, for instance, land mines, blinding lasers, booby traps, and explosives.Footnote 18 The reason is that the control of certain weapons is governed by these protocols. The nineteen arms control treaties dealt with in this chapter can be roughly divided into two groups. First, there are those treaties specifying the terms of peaceful use of certain resources and areas.Footnote 19 Second, there are treaties prohibiting the development, trade, stockpiling and use of specific weapons.Footnote 20

A country’s legal origin is measured by its respective tradition using dummy variables. This classification is based on the differences between the highest legal source of law, because this predominantly defines the main characteristics of legal systems. Initially, the legal origin of a country is either classified as common or civil law. The highest source of law for common law is case law, while for civil law this is codified standards. Within the civil-law tradition, we are able to identify three particular branches, the French code (or Napoleonic code, that dates back to the 1800s), the German code (enacted by Bismarck in the late 1800s) and the Scandinavian code (that dates back to the 1700s). The data is collected from La Porta, Lopez-de Silanes and Schleifer and Mitchell and Powell.Footnote 21 In Table 9.1, we report the distribution of the different legal systems across our global panel.

Table 9.1 Distribution of the legal origin

As a preliminary statistical test, we compute the number of arms control treaties for civil-law and common-law countries. On average, a common-law state has ratified about 6.3 treaties, while a civil-law state has ratified approximately 7.1 treaties. This difference is statistically significant at the ninety percent significance level. This finding implies that civil-law countries are associated with more arms control treaty ratification. However, this nonparametric test is only suggestive, as unobserved country heterogeneity, as well as other confounding variables, are not taken into account.

9.3.2 Empirical Model

To find out whether legal origin influences the ratification of arms control treaties, we employ an ordered logit model using a panel dataset including 171 countries over the period 1975–2016. Ordered logit estimation is appropriate when the dependent variable data is in an ordinal ordering. In this analysis, a higher number of treaties ratified correspond to a higher level of commitment intention than fewer treaties ratified.Footnote 22 However, one drawback of this approach is that we assume that all treaties are equally important for arms trade control. The model is given as follows.

$${treaty}_{it}={\alpha }_{i}+{\beta }^{k}{x}_{it-m}^{k}+\gamma { legal}_{i}+{\varepsilon }_{it}$$
(9.1)

The dependent variable treatyit is the cumulative number of treaties a country i has ratified at the end of year t. The vector xk contains k control variables, while the variable legali captures the legal origin of a country using a series of dummies indicating whether a nation has a common-law or civil-law origin and the various subdivisions. The parameter αi is a country-specific intercept, while εit is an error term.

The vector of control variables is based on earlier literature on the ratification and implementations of international treaties in general and arms control treaties more specific.Footnote 23 These variables are required to avoid an omitted variable bias. The decision of whether or not to ratify a particular arms control treaty is generally based on different considerations including economic, political and security concerns. Table 9.2 provides an overview of all control variables, their definition as well as their source. All explanatory variables are lagged to avoid simultaneity and endogeneity problems. The optimal number of lags m for each control variable is determined by using the Schwarz Bayesian Information Criterion.

Table 9.2 Data used

Before estimating the model, we have to solve two further estimation problems that are related with the panel setting. First, the maximum number of treaties that could be ratified by a country differs between the start and the end of our period. To control this issue, we add a variable taking the value that is equal to the total number of treaties that are opened for signing and ratification. Second, we have to choose between a fixed-effects model and a random-effects model when estimating the model. However, since our primary variable of interest—the indicator for the legal origin—is time-invariant at country level, we are constrained to use the random-effects estimator. Our model cannot be estimated using fixed-effects because the legal origin dummy would be collinear with the country-specific dummies.

9.4 Results

Table 9.3 presents the baseline results of the ordered logit model. To obtain robust standard errors, we apply the bootstrap estimator with 1,000 replicators and cluster them on country levels. Since it is difficult to directly interpret the standard coefficients of a logit model as they are in log-odds units, we report the marginal effects in percentage-points.Footnote 24 Table 9.3, column 1 includes all control variables suggested in the previous section. To control for the legal origin, we include a dummy variable taking the value one when a state has a civil-law history and zero otherwise. This means that we use common-law countries as our reference category. The results suggest that there is no significant difference in ratifying arms control treaties between civil-law and common-law states.

Table 9.3 Legal origin and arms trade control treaties

However, one problematic concern is that the used classification of the legal system is rather rough, making it less informative. As a result, it reduces variation among countries and the explanatory power of the legal origin indicator. In particular, there is no general consensus on how this legal origin division should be made exactly.Footnote 25 According to the existing literature, there is some significant heterogeneity among the countries currently classified as civil or common law. According to Mitchell and Powell some countries that are initially recorded as common-law ones, should actually be considered as Islamic or Sharia Law (such as Pakistan and Sudan) or have a mixed law system (such as Israel or South Africa).Footnote 26 Mixed law also includes numerous countries of Africa as it is partly based on tribal or customary law. Likewise, China’s system is largely civil mixed with principles of socialist law and traditional Confucian values.Footnote 27 Table 9.3, column 2 uses a broader classification. In more detail, Islamic law is based on religious writings, while mixed systems combine elements of two or more different legal systems including customary law.

The findings point out that civil-law countries are more likely to ratify a particular arms control treaty compared to common-law countries. This difference is statistically significant at the ninety percent confidence level. In turns out that civil-law countries ratify about nine percent more arms control treaties compared to countries with a common-law heritage. Additionally, the results also indicate that Islamic countries are less likely to ratify arms control treaties than common-law or civil-law countries, while the impact of mixed law is the same compared to common-law countries as this legal origin variable is statistically insignificant.

Due to reasons of data availability, using all suggested control variables in one specification reduces our dataset substantially thereby increasing the risk that the results are driven by a sample selection bias. To balance the omitted variable bias against a possible sample selection bias, Table 9.3, column 3 presents our set of control variables by applying the general-to-specific method. This method does not rely on economic theory, but is a widely-used method in applied econometrics to decide on the model specification.Footnote 28 We first estimate a model including all control variables as outlined in the previous section, but without including our legal origin dummies. Next, we drop the least significant variable and estimate the model again. This procedure is repeated until only variables that are significant at the ten percent level remain. The results in Table 9.3, column 3 are rather identical compared to the findings in Table 9.3, column 2. This indicates that the results are quite robust to the econometric specification chosen.

In Table 9.3 (columns 4 and 5), we split the sample of civil-law countries a little further into countries of German, French and Scandinavian origin. The results indicate that although countries that have a civil-law tradition are more likely to ratify an arms control treaty than common-law ones, there is any statistically significant difference within the group of civil-law countries. On a similar note, earlier empirical studies indicate that socialist legal systems should be considered as a separate category. A socialist system is driven by the administration implying that there is no role for private law, the country is governed by one dominant communistic party, the law is predominately used to realize a political agenda and court rulings hardly settle disputes in private relations and have a limited role in public law. The classification used so far does not distinguish the socialist tradition. Instead, former socialist countries are reclassified as either German or French according to the main historical influence on their new legal system. For example, Russia is classified as having French legal origin. Of the 24 former socialist countries in our sample, 11 have French and 13 have a German origin. In Table 9.3 (columns 6 and 7), we include countries with a socialist legal origin as a separate category. The results show that socialist regimes are rather different from the other civil-law countries as they ratify fewer arms control treaties. In particular, they even ratify fewer treaties than common-law countries as the coefficient is significantly negative at common confidence levels. Furthermore, in the econometric specification in Table 9.3 column 8, we include the number of treaties ratified in the previous year as an additional covariate. Although the magnitude and significance both drop slightly of the variables of interest, adding the dependent variable with a one-year lag does not dramatically affect our main conclusions as civil-law countries still ratify more arms control treaties compared to other systems.

Finally, leaders of democratic states face constraints autocrats do not have to take into account when making ratification decisions. According to the existing literature, regime differences play an essential role in treaty ratification.Footnote 29 One crucial assumption we made so far is that there is no difference between the de jure and de facto of the applied legal system in a country. The classification of legal systems is based on the source of law that is the highest in hierarchy including legal documents or written procedures. As a result, our indicator is not directly related with the execution or actual practice of law and legislation. For instance, in autocratic regimes laws and institutions are primarily built and shaped to promote the personal interests of the ruling elite, making the legal origin less important. This could for instance explain the negative effect found on socialist and Islamic legal origin as many countries with these legal systems can be classified as autocratic or at least democratic transition countries. Generally, autocratic regimes have ratified about six treaties, whereas democracies have ratified about ten treaties. To explore this issue some further, we split our data into democratic and autocratic countries based on the Polity IV score. Each country-year with a Polity IV score larger or equal to seven are recorded as democratic. As expected, the final columns of Table 9.2 indicate that the gap between common-law and civil-law countries is larger in democracies as in these countries the difference between de jure and de facto is less compared to autocratic states. This gap between common law and civil law is only weakly significant in autocratic countries as the legal origin is of less importance in these countries. Laws and policies are more shaped by the self-interest of the ruling elite than by the legal tradition.

9.5 Conclusion

The objective of this chapter is to explore whether the legal origin of a country influences the number of arms control treaties that are ratified. Given civil law’s affinity for binding agreements and common law’s aversion to them, we would expect a higher likelihood of ratification of international arms control treaties among civil-law countries. After testing for the robustness of the results, we can draw a number of conclusions based on the findings reported throughout this chapter. First, civil-law countries ratify more arms control treaties than common-law countries. In particular, civil-law countries ratify about nine percent more treaties. In practice, this comes down to about two arms control treaties. Second, within the broad civil-law category, we find no significant difference between countries with a French, German or Nordic legal heritage. Third, Islamic and socialist law countries ratify fewer arms control treaties compared to other legal traditions. Finally, the ratification gap between civil-law and common-law countries is larger for democracies than for autocracies. This can be explained by the fact that laws and policies in autocracies are shaped more by the self-interest of the ruling elite than by the legal tradition of a country.

These results imply that when drafting an international arms control treaty, politicians should take into account the legal tradition of a country. One way to make treaties more effective is by giving countries the opportunity to partly modify or disregard provisions on less important issues that are incompatible with domestic laws and policies.

Two major limitations regarding our study are, first, that we assume that all arms control treaties are equally important. This is not necessarily the case. Some treaties have a broader scope or are more stringent than others. So their implications differ as well as their importance differ. Second, we have only explored the incentives of ratifying an arms control treaty and have not looked at the implementation in the national law. Treaties often come with enforcement problems, raising considerable concerns about the actual implementation of treaty provisions. The existing literature has already shown there are serious concerns about arms control implementation and compliance.