Skip to main content

Forest Management and Landowners’ Discount Rates in the Southern United States

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
Post-Faustmann Forest Resource Economics

Part of the book series: Sustainability, Economics, and Natural Resources ((SENR,volume 4))

Abstract

In theory, decisions with long-term pay-offs, such as whether to invest in forest management, are influenced by time preferences. However, this relationship is difficult to test empirically and time preferences are often assumed constant across individuals. We examine the relationship between forest management behavior and personal discount rates by modeling forest management choices as a function of individual discount rates elicited through binary choice questions. We focus on “limited resource woodland owners” in the Southern United States, including landowners who are traditionally underserved by public institutions (i.e., minorities and women) and who face financial, social and natural resource constraints that limit their forest management options. We found that the probability of harvesting timber is positively related with personal discount rates, as predicted by theory. However, discount rates are not significantly related to stand improvements or contact with a professional forester, suggesting that lack of investment in forest management is not a result of landowner impatience. Rather, these behaviors are driven by characteristics such as size of property, proximity of residence to woodlands, and tenureship characteristics including whether the woodlands are inherited.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 129.00
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 169.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD 169.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    We refer to this group as “woodland” owners rather than “forestland” owners, because they generally recognize and refer to their properties as having “woods” rather than “forest”, which can have connotations of industrial timber management.

  2. 2.

    The model can be expanded to consider bequest factors, which in turn would be influenced by tenure status (e.g., with uncertainty about future benefits introduced by heir property status).

  3. 3.

    The complete first order conditions are displayed in Appendix A.1.

  4. 4.

    The survey instrument was pretested and reviewed by woodland owners, forestry faculty at NCSU, and forestry extension agents to ensure that the questions were easy to understand yet presented forestry concepts accurately. Information about the survey was published in local newsletters a month before the survey took place. Landowners selected for the survey were sent postcards to inform them they were being requested to participate. This mailing was followed by a survey packet that included a cover letter, survey booklet, request for survey results, pre-addressed postage paid envelope, and small gifts (e.g. a refrigerator magnet with the study logo, $1 bill, mini cd-rom with forestry information). A month afterwards, landowners who had not replied were sent follow-up postcard reminders.

  5. 5.

    More details on the study are available from www.ncsu.edu/woodland.

  6. 6.

    There were several ways that landowners with more than 100 acres could have been included in our sampling frame. Most often, this happened because they own land outside the seven study counties. In some cases, they owned land under different names (e.g., as heir property) that were not linked in our sampling frame.

  7. 7.

    The discount rate is assumed to follow a log-normal distribution for two reasons: (1) estimates from this distribution were within observed discount rate ranges for 70 % of the respondents, which is a higher proportion compared to results based on normal or Weibull (extreme value) distributions; and (2) the log-normal distribution limits the estimates to be non-negative, which is supported by the time preference literature (e.g. Olson and Bailey 1981).

  8. 8.

    Environmental preferences are potentially correlated with time preferences and a determinant of forest management behavior, and therefore could potentially also introduce multi-collinearity into models of forest management as a function of time preferences. This is confirmed by a positive and statistically significant (P-value: 0.025) correlation between the estimated discount rate and respondents who put high importance on protecting nature. However, this variable does not have a statistically significant impact on any of the behaviors in multivariate models.

References

  • Agee M, Crocker T (1996) Parents’ discount rates for child quality. South Econ J 63(1):36–50

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Alig RJ, Lee KJ, Moulton RJ (1990) Likelihood of timber management on nonindustrial private forests: evidence from research studies, p 17

    Google Scholar 

  • Atmadja SS (2008). Discount Rate Estimation and the Role of Time Preference in Rural Household Behavior: Disease Prevention in India and Forest Management in the US. PhD Dissertation. North Carolina State University, Raleigh, NC.

    Google Scholar 

  • Amacher GS, Koskela E, Ollikainen M, Conway MC (2002b) Bequest intentions of forest landowners: theory and empirical evidence. Am J Agric Econ 84(4):1103–1114

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Barton DN, Mourato S (2003) Transferring the benefits of avoided health effects from water pollution between Portugal and Costa Rica. Environ Dev Econ 8:351–371

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Becker GS, Mulligan CB (1997) The endogenous determination of time preference. Quart J Econ 112(3):729–758

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Binswanger HP, Sillers DA (1983) Risk aversion and credit constraints in farmers’ decision-Making: a reinterpretation. J Dev Stud 20(1):5–21

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bliss JC, Grassl MJ (1987) Predicting timber harvests on private forests in southwest Wisconsin. Northern J Appl Forestry 4(3):152–154

    Google Scholar 

  • Bliss JC, Martin AJ (1988) Identity and private forest management. Soc Nat Res 1(4):365–376

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bliss JC, Sisock ML, Birch TW (1998) Ownership matters: forestland concentration in rural Alabama. Soc Nat Res 11(4):401–410

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bolkesjø TF, Solberg B (2003) A panel data analysis of nonindustrial private roundwood supply with emphasis on the price elasticity. For Sci 49(4):530–538

    Google Scholar 

  • Bullard SH, Gunter JE, Doolittle ML, Arano KG (2002) Discount rates for nonindustrial private forest landowners in Mississippi: how high a hurdle? South J Appl Forestry 26(1):26–32

    Google Scholar 

  • Butler BJ (2008) Family forest owners of the United States, 2006. Gen. Tech. Rep. NRS-27. U.S. Department of agriculture, forest service, northern research station, Newtown Square, p 72

    Google Scholar 

  • Butler BJ, Leatherberry EC (2004) America’s family forest owners. J Forest 102(7):4–14

    Google Scholar 

  • Cameron TA (1988) A new paradigm for valuing non-market goods using referendum data: maximum likelihood estimation by censored logistic regression. J Environ Econ Manage 15:355–379

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cleaves DA, Bennett M (1995) Timber harvesting by nonindustrial private forest landowners in western Oregon. Western J Appl Forestry 10(2):66–71

    Google Scholar 

  • Conway MC, Amacher GS, Sullivan J, Wear D (2003) Decisions nonindustrial forest landowners make: an empirical examination. J For Econ 9(5):181–203

    Google Scholar 

  • Cubbage FW (1982) Economies of forest tract size in southern pine harvesting. Research Paper SO-184. USDA Forest Service, Southern Forest Experiment Station. New Orleans, LA, p 27

    Google Scholar 

  • Cubbage FW, Harris TG (1986) Tract size and forest management practices: Issues, literature, and implications. Georgia Agricultural Experiment Station, Research Report No. 551, p 29

    Google Scholar 

  • De Coster L (1998) The boom in forest owners—a bust for forestry? J Forest 96(5):25–28

    Google Scholar 

  • Deaton BJ, Baxter J, Bratt CS (2009) Examining the consequences and character of “heir property”. Ecol Econ 68(8–9):2344–2353

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ernst CT Jr, Marsinko A (1983) Participation in the forestry incentives program in berkeley and orangeburg counties in South Carolina. Forest Research Series No.38. Department of Forestry, Clemson University, ii + p 30

    Google Scholar 

  • Faustmann M (1849) Berechnung des Wertes welchen Waldboden, sowie noch nicht haubare Holzbestäande für die Waldwirtschaft besitzen. Allgemeine Forst- und Jagd-Zeitung 25:441–455

    Google Scholar 

  • Gan JB, Kebede E (2005) Multivariate probit modeling of decisions on timber harvesting and request for assistance by African-American forestland owners. South J Appl Forestry 29(3):135–142

    Google Scholar 

  • Harrison GW, Lau MI, Williams MB (2002) Estimating individual discount rates in Denmark: a field experiment. Am Econ Rev 92(5):1606–1617

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hartman R (1976) The harvesting decision when a standing forest has value. Econ Inq 14(1):52–58

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hensyl CH (2005) Impacts of land and ownership characteristics on the stumpage prices for Virginia’s nonindustrial forests. MS Thesis. Department of Forestry, Virginia Tech, Blacksburg, p 115

    Google Scholar 

  • Hickman CA (1984) Socio-economic characteristics of prospective nonindustrial private timber sellers in East Texas. Research Note SO-308. USDA forest service, southern forest experiment station, p 4

    Google Scholar 

  • Hubbard WG, Abt RC (1989) The effect of timber sale assistance on returns to landowners. Res Manage Optim 6(3):225–234

    Google Scholar 

  • Kant S (1999). Endogenous rate of time preference, traditional communities, and sustainable forest management. J Soc Econ Dev 2(1):65–87

    Google Scholar 

  • Kirby KN, Marakovic NN (1995) Modeling myopic decisions: evidence for hyperbolic delay-discounting within subjects and amounts. Organ Behav Hum Decis Process 64(1):22–30

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kirby KN, Petry NM (2004) Heroin and cocaine abusers have higher discount rates for delayed rewards than alcoholics or non-drug-using controls. Addiction 99(4):461–471

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kline JD, Alig RJ, Johnson RL (2000) Fostering the production of nontimber services among forest owners with heterogeneous objectives. For Sci 46(2):302–311

    Google Scholar 

  • Kronrad GD, De Steiguer JE (1983) Relationships between discount rates and investment lengths among nonindustrial private landowners. Research Notes Series No.19. Small Woodlot R&D Program, North Carolina State University. Raleigh, p 19

    Google Scholar 

  • Kuuluvainen J, Tahvonen O (1999) Testing the forest rotation model: evidence from panel data. For Sci 45(4):539–551

    Google Scholar 

  • Land Loss Prevention Project (2008) Estate planning and heir property. Available from: http://www.landloss.org/heirproperty.php. Accessed on 26 May 2008

  • Lawrance EC (1991) Poverty and the rate of time preference: evidence from panel data. J Political Economy 99(1):54–77

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Londo AJ, Grebner DL (2004) Economies of scale and forest management in Mississippi. Gen. Tech. Rep. SRS–71. U.S. department of agriculture, forest service, southern research station. Asheville, p 91

    Google Scholar 

  • Loewenstein G, Prelec D (1992) Anomalies in intertemporal choice: evidence and an interpretation. Quart J Econ 107(2):573–597

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mance K, Warren S, Sills EO (2004) Outreach to limited resource forest landowners: extension innovation for low literacy audiences. In: Proceedings of human dimensions of family, farm, and community forestry international symposium, 29 Mar–1 April, 2004, Washington State University. D. M. Baumgartner. Pullman, WA: Washington State University Extension

    Google Scholar 

  • Measells MK, Grado SC, Hughes HG, Dunn MA, Idassi J, Zielinske B (2005) NIPF landowner charateristics and use of forestry services in four southern states: results from a 2002–2003 mail survey. South J Appl Forestry 29(4):194–199

    Google Scholar 

  • Melfi FM, Straka TJ, Marsinko AP, Baumann JL (1997) Landowner attitudes toward South Carolina’s forest stewardship program. South J Appl Forestry 21(4):158–163

    Google Scholar 

  • Mitchell TW (2001) From reconstruction to deconstruction: undermining black landownership, political independence, and community through partition sales of tenancies in common. Northwest Univ Law Rev 95(2):505–580

    Google Scholar 

  • Moseley WG (2001) African evidence on the relation of poverty, time preference and the environment. Ecol Econ 38(3):317–326

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Munn IA, Rucker RR (1994) The value of information services in a market for factors of production with multiple attributes: The role of consultants in private timber sales. For Sci 40(3):474–496

    Google Scholar 

  • Nagubadi V, McNamara KT, Hoover WL, Mills WLJ (1996) Program participation behavior of nonindustrial forest landowners: a probit analysis. J Agric Appl Econ 28(2):323–336

    Google Scholar 

  • Newman DH, Wear DN (1993) Production economics of private forestry: a comparison of industrial and nonindustrial forest owners. Am J Agric Econ 75(3):674–684

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Olson M, Bailey MJ (1981) Positive time preference. J Political Economy 89(1):1–25

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pender JL (1996). Discount rates and credit markets: Theory and evidence from rural India. Journal of Dev Econ 50(2): 257–296

    Google Scholar 

  • Poulos C, Whittington D (2000) Time preferences for life-saving programs: Evidence from six less developed countries. Environ Sci Technol 34:1445–1455

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Prestemon JP, Wear DN (2000) Linking harvest choices to timber supply. For Sci 46(3):377–389

    Google Scholar 

  • Rogers AR (1994) Evolution of time preference by natural selection. Am Econ Rev 84(3):460–481

    Google Scholar 

  • Sills EO, Warren S (2002) Proposal: sustaining ecological and eonomic diversity among limited resource landholders by expanding opportunities for management of productive woodlands. Available from: http://www.ncsu.edu/woodlands/project.html. Accessed on 17 Oct 2005

  • Straka TJ, Wisdom HW, Moak JE (1984) Size of forest holding and investment behaviour of nonindustrial private owners. J Forest 82(8):495–496

    Google Scholar 

  • Thomas M, Pennick J, Gray H (2004) What is African-American land ownership? Available from: http://www.federationsoutherncoop.com/aalandown04.htm. Accessed on 31 Dec 2006

  • Thompson RP, Jones JG (1981) Classifying nonindustrial private forestland by tract size. J Forest 79(5):288–291

    Google Scholar 

  • Trostel PA, Taylor GA (2001) A theory of time preference. Econ Inq 39(3):379–395

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Uniform Law Commission (2011) Partition of heirs property act. Available from: http://www.nccusl.org/Act.aspx?title=Partition%20of%20Heirs%20Property%20Act. Accessed on 26 Jan 2012

  • US Census Bureau (2004) Educational attainment in the United States: 2004. Available from: http://www.census.gov/population/www/socdemo/education/cps2004.html. Accessed on 27 Jan 2006

  • US Census Bureau (2001a) Summary File 1 (SF1). 2006. Available from: http://www.census.gov/support/cen2000_sf1data.html . Accessed 26 Jan 2012

  • Census Bureau US (2001b) Summary File 1 (SF3). 2006. Available from: http://www.census.gov/support/cen2000_sf3ascii.html . Accessed 26 Jan 2012

  • USDA-NASS (2002) 2002 Census of agriculture—volume 1 geographic area series census, US—State Data. Available from: http://www.nass.usda.gov/Census/Create_Census_US_CNTY.jsp#top. Accessed on 13 Oct 2007

  • USDA Forest Service (2000) USDA Forest service interim strategic public outreach plan. FS-665. USDA forest service, p 64

    Google Scholar 

  • Vokoun M, Amacher GS, Wear DN (2006) Scale of harvesting by non-industrial private forest landowners. J For Econ 11(4):223–244

    Google Scholar 

  • Vuchinich RE, Simpson CA (1998) Hyperbolic temporal discounting in social drinkers and problem drinkers. Exp Clin Psychopharmacology 6(3):292–305

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Webster HH, Stoltenberg CH (1959) What ownership characteristics are useful in predicting response to forestry programs. Land Econ 35(3):292–295

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zhang D (1996) Assistance foresters in nonindustrial private forest management: Alabama landowners perspectives. Highlights Agric Res 43(4):10–12

    Google Scholar 

  • Zhang DW, Mehmood SR (2001) Predicting nonindustrial private forest landowners’ choices of a forester for harvesting and tree planting assistance in Alabama. Southern J Appl Forestry 25(3):101–107

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Stibniati S. Atmadja .

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

Appendices

Appendix

First Order Conditions

Re-stating the Lagrangean function (from Eq. 5.3)

$$ \begin{aligned} L \,=\, & U_{1} [C_{1} ,N_{1} ;Z] + \lambda_{N1} (N_{1} - N_{1} (K - X_{1} ,E_{1} )) + \lambda_{C1} (C_{1} - P \,\cdot \,H(X_{1} ,E_{1} ) + O_{1} (E_{1} ) + S - M_{1} ) \\ & + \frac{1}{1 + r} \,\cdot \,\left( {U_{2} [C_{2} ,N_{2} ;Z] + \lambda_{N2} (N_{2} - N_{2} (Q_{2} ,E_{2} ))} \right) \\ & + \left( {\frac{1}{1 + r}} \right) \,\cdot\, \lambda_{C2} \left( {C_{2} - P \,\cdot \,H(K - X_{1} - Q_{2} ,E_{2} ) + O_{2} (E_{2} ) - (1 + R)S - M} \right) \\ \end{aligned} $$
(A.1)

Maximize Eq. A.1 with respect to C1, C2, N1, N2, X1, E1, E2, S, and Q2

$$ \frac{\partial L}{{\partial C_{1} }} = \frac{{\partial U_{1} }}{{\partial C_{1} }} + \lambda_{C1} = 0 \to \lambda_{C1} = - \frac{{\partial U_{1} }}{{\partial C_{1} }} $$
$$ \frac{\partial L}{{\partial C_{2} }} = \frac{{\partial U_{2} }}{{\partial C_{2} }} + \lambda_{C2} = 0 \to \lambda_{C2} = - \frac{{\partial U_{2} }}{{\partial C_{2} }} $$
$$ \frac{\partial L}{{\partial N_{1} }} = \frac{{\partial U_{1} }}{{\partial N_{1} }} + \lambda_{N1} = 0 \to \lambda_{N1} = - \frac{{\partial U_{1} }}{{\partial N_{1} }} $$
(A.2)
$$ \frac{\partial L}{{\partial N_{2} }} = \frac{{\partial U_{2} }}{{\partial N_{2} }} + \lambda_{N2} = 0 \to \lambda_{N2} = - \frac{{\partial U_{2} }}{{\partial N_{2} }} $$
(A.3)
$$ \frac{\partial L}{\partial S} = \lambda_{C1} - \lambda_{C2} \frac{(1 + R)}{(1 + r)} = 0 \to \lambda_{C2} = \frac{(1 + r)}{(1 + R)} \,\cdot \,\lambda_{C1} $$
(A.4)
$$ \begin{array}{*{20}l} {\frac{{\partial L}}{{\partial X_{1} }} = \lambda _{{N1}} \frac{{\partial N_{1} }}{{\partial X_{1} }} - \lambda _{{C1}} P\frac{{\partial H}}{{\partial X_{1} }} + \lambda _{{C2}} \left( {\frac{1}{{1 + r}}} \right)P\frac{{\partial H}}{{\partial X_{1} }} = 0} \hfill \\ { \to \lambda _{{N1}} \frac{{\partial N_{1} }}{{\partial X_{1} }} + \lambda _{{C2}} \left( {\frac{1}{{1 + r}}} \right)P\frac{{\partial H}}{{\partial X_{1} }} = \lambda _{{C1}} P\frac{{\partial H}}{{\partial X_{1} }}} \hfill \\ \end{array}$$
$$ \frac{\partial L}{{\partial E_{1} }} = \lambda_{C1} \left( {\frac{{\partial O_{1} }}{{\partial E_{1} }} - P \,\cdot\, \frac{\partial H}{{\partial E_{1} }}} \right) - \lambda_{N1} \left( {\frac{{\partial N_{1} }}{{\partial E_{1} }}} \right) = 0 $$
(A.5)
$$ \frac{\partial L}{{\partial E_{2} }} = \lambda_{C2} \left( {\frac{{\partial O_{2} }}{{\partial E_{2} }} - P\frac{\partial H}{{\partial E_{2} }}} \right) - \lambda_{N2} \frac{{\partial N_{2} }}{{\partial E_{2} }} = 0 $$
$$ \frac{\partial L}{{\partial Q_{2} }} = - \frac{{\partial N_{2} }}{{\partial Q_{2} }}\lambda_{N2} + P \,\cdot \,\frac{\partial H}{{\partial Q_{2} }} \,\cdot \,\lambda_{C2} = 0 \to \lambda_{C2} = \lambda_{N2} \frac{{{{\partial N_{2} } \mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {{\partial N_{2} } {\partial Q_{2} }}} \right. \kern-0pt} {\partial Q_{2} }}}}{{{{P \,\cdot \,\partial H} \mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {{P \,\cdot \,\partial H} {\partial Q_{2} }}} \right. \kern-0pt} {\partial Q_{2} }} \,}} $$
(A.6)

Setting Eq. A.6 equal to Eq. A.4, we get:

$$ \lambda_{N2} \frac{{{{\partial N_{2} } \mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {{\partial N_{2} } {\partial Q_{2} }}} \right. \kern-0pt} {\partial Q_{2} }}}}{{{{P \,\cdot \,\partial H} \mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {{P \,\cdot\, \partial H} {\partial Q_{2} }}} \right. \kern-0pt} {\partial Q_{2} }}}} = \lambda_{C1} \frac{(1 + r)}{\alpha (1 + R)} \to \lambda_{C1} = \lambda_{N2} \frac{(1 + R)}{(1 + r)}\frac{{{{\partial N_{2} } \mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {{\partial N_{2} } {\partial Q_{2} }}} \right. \kern-0pt} {\partial Q_{2} }}}}{{{{P \,\cdot \,\partial H} \mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {{P \,\cdot\, \partial H} {\partial Q_{2} }}} \right. \kern-0pt} {\partial Q_{2} }}}} $$
(A.7)

Substitute Eq. A.7 into Eq. A.5:

$$ \lambda_{N2} \frac{(1 + R)}{(1 + r)}\frac{{{{\partial N_{2} } \mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {{\partial N_{2} } {\partial Q_{2} }}} \right. \kern-0pt} {\partial Q_{2} }}}}{{{{P \cdot \partial H} \mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {{P \cdot \partial H} {\partial Q_{2} }}} \right. \kern-0pt} {\partial Q_{2} }}}}\left( {\frac{\partial O}{{\partial E_{1} }} - P \cdot \frac{\partial H}{{\partial E_{1} }}} \right) = \lambda_{N1} \left( {\frac{{\partial N_{1} }}{{\partial E_{1} }}} \right) $$
(A.8)

Substitute Eqs. A.2 and A.3 into Eq. A.8 and rearranging terms:

$$ \frac{{\partial U_{1} }}{{\partial N_{1} }} \cdot \frac{{\partial N_{1} }}{{\partial E_{1} }} = \left( {\frac{\partial O}{{\partial E_{1} }} - P \cdot \frac{\partial H}{{\partial E_{1} }}} \right)\frac{{\left( {\frac{{\partial U_{2} }}{{\partial N_{2} }} \cdot \frac{{\partial N_{2} }}{{\partial Q_{2} }}} \right)}}{{{{P \cdot \partial H} \mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {{P \cdot \partial H} {\partial Q_{2} }}} \right. \kern-0pt} {\partial Q_{2} }}}}\frac{(1 + R)}{(1 + r)} $$
(A.9)

Survey Module for Eliciting Personal Discount Rates

Suppose that you are given 50 acres of woodland about a mile away from your house. This woodland has a mixture of pines and hardwoods and a mixture of different size trees. A forester takes a look at this woodland and gives you two choices: Choice A or Choice B.

(1)

Choice A

Choice B

You cut and sell all of the trees now and replant with pine seedlings. You earn $(P321) per acre. Every 32 years, you cut and replant all of your trees and earn $(P321) per acre. Your earnings already include all cost

You cut and sell some of the trees now and let them grow back on their own. You earn $(P8 1) per acre. Every 8 years you cut some more trees and earn $(P8 1) per acre. Your earnings already include all costs

This choice gives you more money each time you sell, but you wait longer between harvests

This choice gives you less money each time you sell, but you don’t wait as long between harvests

Which would you pick?

  • □1 Choice A

  • □2 Choice B

  • □3 Neither

Now suppose that you end up with a different piece of woodland and the forester gives you the following two new choices: Choice A or Choice B.

(2)

Choice A

Choice B

You cut and sell all of the trees now and replant with pine seedlings. You earn $(P321) per acre. Every 32 years, you cut and replant all of your trees and earn $(P321) per acre. Your earnings already include all costs

You cut and sell some of the trees now and let them grow back on their own. You earn $(P8 1) per acre. Every 8 years you cut some more trees and earn per $(P8 1) acre. Your earnings already include all costs

This choice gives you more money each time you sell, but you wait longer between harvests

This choice gives you less money each time you sell, but you don’t wait as long between harvests

Which would you pick?

  • □1 Choice A

  • □2 Choice B

  • □3 Neither

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2013 Springer Science+Business Media Dordrecht

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Atmadja, S.S., Sills, E.O. (2013). Forest Management and Landowners’ Discount Rates in the Southern United States. In: Kant, S. (eds) Post-Faustmann Forest Resource Economics. Sustainability, Economics, and Natural Resources, vol 4. Springer, Dordrecht. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-94-007-5778-3_5

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics