Skip to main content

Part of the book series: New Economic Windows ((NEW,volume 1))

  • 1723 Accesses

Abstract

The illuminating prose of Friedrich von Hayek illustrates some of the main issues that are at the core of the bottom-up approach to macroeconomics we offer in this book. The inhabitants of the realistic economies we aim to model form expectations and take actions building on the asymmetric and incomplete information they acquire by exploring limited portions of space and time, while their dispersed market transactions generate aggregate outcomes whose welfare properties are unknowable in principle, at least if one pretends to measure them against some hypothetical Walrasian general equilibrium. The quotation has also a second value added in that it helps us to stress once again that this vision, though considered as heretical by the mainstream, does not represent anything particularly new from a theoretical viewpoint. On the contrary, it is part and parcel of a well-honored but guiltily disregarded tradition in the history of economic thought, one that considers the economic agent as a proper human being instead of a computer-like automaton. We argue that it is time not only to bring this tradition back to life, but also to revamp it by means of new insights from other behavioral sciences, like cognitive psychology and social biology.

Into the determination of … prices and wages there will enter the effects of particular information possessed by every one of the participants in the market process — a sum of facts which in their totality cannot be known to the scientific observer, or to any other single brain. It is indeed the source of the superiority of the market order … that in the resulting allocation of resources more of the knowledge of particular facts will be utilized which exists only dispersed among uncounted persons, than any one person can possess. But because we … can thus never know all the determinants of such an order, and in consequence also cannot know at which particular structure of prices and wages demand would everywhere equal supply, we also cannot measure the deviations from that order. Friedrich A. von Hayek The Pretence of Knowledge, p. 12

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 39.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 54.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD 54.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    The authors of this book have all learnt to drive a car in a continental European country. The outcome would be dramatically different if at least one of the two drivers in our example would come from the UK

  2. 2.

    This is of course the simplest conceivable setting in the simplest case of a closed economy without public sector. Also in this setting, there are richer models which consider also other classes of agents, such as banks, investors on financial markets, etc. In any case, a relatively small (very small) number of classes are considered. Usually, the number and type of classes is a prior of the modeler.

  3. 3.

    See McFazdean and Tesfatsion (1999) for an introduction to object-oriented programming into economics, and an application to the endogenous formation of trading networks.

  4. 4.

    Of course there can be many agents in any generation, but they are ultimately uniform. Each young (old) is a clone of any other young (old). Therefore, despite the appearance of a very large number of agent, the model boils down to only two of them.

  5. 5.

    In what follows, underscores denote vectors.

  6. 6.

    For a complete analysis of these issues, see Evans and Honkapoija (2004).

  7. 7.

    Notice that on this particular modeling choice the Keynesian and Neoclassical frames of thought are indistinguishable. The differences are the laws supposed to underlie the behavior of the means: in fact, according to Keynesians it is sufficient to study a “working” relationship between, for example, aggregate consumption and aggregate income; while, according to the Neoclassical reductionist approach, the mean outcomes have to be derived as if they were the optimal responses by a representative consumer or firm.

  8. 8.

    One must be honest: the self-averaging property is only a sufficient condition in order to rely upon mean values and, consequently, non-self-averaging does not imply their discard. However, non-self-averaging is sufficient to strongly distrust the neoclassical justification for the use of mean values and to open the path to AB models.

  9. 9.

    By within and between class interactions we always mean non-mean-field, one-to-one interactions.

  10. 10.

    Notice, however, that more sophisticated techniques for the choice of parameter values are also available (Bianchi et al., 2008).

  11. 11.

    Validation of ABMs is becoming one of the major points in the agenda of agent-based researchers. In her website, Leigh Tesfatsion maintains an entire section dedicated to this topic (http://www.econ.iastate.edu/tesfatsi/empvalid.htm).

  12. 12.

    12 On these points, see Kleijnen (1998), Troitzsch (2004), Richiardi et al. (2006) and Fagiolo et al. (2007).

  13. 13.

    See footnote 10.

  14. 14.

    Admittedly, the logical order between the validation and the calibration stages we propose is not universally accepted among the agent-based community. Richiardi et al. (2006), for instance, argue for putting calibration before validation, as they consider validation as the final step of a well-calibrated simulation model.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2011 Springer-Verlag Italia

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Delli Gatti, D., Desiderio, S., Gaffeo, E., Cirillo, P., Gallegati, M. (2011). The Making of the BAM Model. In: Macroeconomics from the Bottom-up. New Economic Windows, vol 1. Springer, Milano. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-88-470-1971-3_2

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics