Skip to main content
  • 475 Accesses

Abstract

A key issue, which emerged in the context of the theoretical framework in Chapter 2, concerns the institutional aspect of FDI competition between governments, and the need to analyze locational competition not just within the neoclassical framework of the “two-dimensional range of price theory, which examines only price and quantity”,374 but also to consider investment promotion as another area in which governments compete. To follow-up on this point, the underlying institutional governance structure of the competitive process, which involves national or local governments and Investment Promotion Agencies as their agents, will be examined.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 39.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 54.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Preview

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

References

  1. NORTH (1986), p. 230.

    Google Scholar 

  2. See MORISSET/ ANDREWS-JOHNSON (2004), p. 7.

    Google Scholar 

  3. See KASPER/ STREIT (1998), p. 67.

    Google Scholar 

  4. See NORTH (1990), p. 111.

    Google Scholar 

  5. See also MUDAMBI (1999), p. 69.

    Google Scholar 

  6. See STOPFORD/ TURNER (1985), cited by FRASER (1999), p. 4, for details on the composition of FDI in Britain during that period.

    Google Scholar 

  7. This also included the appointment of a private sector Chief Executive, Andrew Fraser, who started his work at IBB in 1994.

    Google Scholar 

  8. The UK’s FDI performance dramatically declined in 2002 (down 60 percent), and is said to have declined further in 2003 (down almost 50 percent). See UNCTAD (2003); OECD (2004).

    Google Scholar 

  9. See FDI data in UNCTAD (2003).

    Google Scholar 

  10. See SIEBERT (2002), p. 8.

    Google Scholar 

  11. See RAINES/ BROWN (1999), p. 21. Only recently has Germany received its fair share of M&A related FDI activities, with the Mannesman/ Vodafone merger marking a peak in 2000.

    Google Scholar 

  12. See FDI data in UNCTAD (2003). Inward FDI exceeded outward FDI in 2000 and 2002.

    Google Scholar 

  13. Although foreign investment played a role in the 1991–1994 privatization program administered by the Treuhand, contrary to popular belief, most of the acquisitions were undertaken by West-German companies, while foreign investment accounted only for ten percent (see UNCTAD, 2003, p. 42).

    Google Scholar 

  14. See IIC (2004).

    Google Scholar 

  15. See FAZ (2003), p. 11.

    Google Scholar 

  16. See FDI data in UNCTAD (2003), p. 249.

    Google Scholar 

  17. FAZ (2003), p. 11.

    Google Scholar 

  18. DW (2003).

    Google Scholar 

  19. See MORISSET/ ANDREWS-JOHNSON (2004) for details on issues pertaining to the effectiveness of promotion agencies in attracting foreign direct investment.

    Google Scholar 

  20. See UNCTAD (2002), p. 42.

    Google Scholar 

  21. Investors tend to be attracted to clusters due to availability of specialized labor, supplier, infrastructure and other resources, despite the higher costs they sometimes incur (see also Katseli’s “thick-market-externalities” argument in 2.3.3). Countries benefit in terms of higher quantity as well as, most importantly, higher quality of FDI flows (see KETELS, 2004).

    Google Scholar 

  22. See FAZ (2003), p. 11.

    Google Scholar 

  23. See UNCTAD (2003), p. 252.

    Google Scholar 

  24. See UNCTAD (2003), p. 61.

    Google Scholar 

  25. See UNCTAD (2003a), p. 17. Subsequently the share of FDI stock as percentage of GDP went up from 14.1 percent in 1995 to 54.8 percent in 2002.

    Google Scholar 

  26. See UNCTAD (2003), p. 61.

    Google Scholar 

  27. See UNCTAD (2003), p. 69.

    Google Scholar 

  28. The law governing the national incentive scheme is the Investment Incentive Act (72/2000 Coll.), which is officially called the “Act on Investment Incentives and Amendment of Certain Acts, as amended by Act No. 453/2001”. Subsequent amendments came into force on May 1, 2004 (see MALLYA/ KUKULKA/ JENSEN, 2004, p. 122; and CzechInvest Website).

    Google Scholar 

  29. See MALLYA/ KUKULKA/ JENSEN (2004), p. 121. In particular, the May 2004 amendment reduced the minimum level of investment as well as unified the tax relief provided to both new and established investors.

    Google Scholar 

  30. See MALLYA/ KUKULKA/ JENSEN (2004), p. 122; CzechInvest Website.

    Google Scholar 

  31. The net effect of the national incentive scheme appears mixed. MALLYA/ KUKULKA/ JENSEN (2004) conclude that only a small number of investors in the manufacturing sector (10 percent) were specifically attracted by incentives offered. Moreover, the most dramatic increase in FDI since 1998 occurred in the service sector, which is only partially covered by incentives. SEDMIHRADSKY/ KLAZAR (2002) suggest that the introduction of incentives in the Czech Republic diverted FDI flows from Hungary but had no effect on investment flows into Poland.

    Google Scholar 

  32. See MALLYA/ KUKULKA/ JENSEN (2002), p. 142.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2006 Deutscher Universitäts-Verlag | GWV Fachverlage GmbH, Wiesbaden

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

(2006). Governance Models for Investment Promotion in Europe. In: Locational Tournaments in the Context of the EU Competitive Environment. DUV. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-8350-9109-2_9

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics