Skip to main content

A Sustainable Future for Corporate Governance Theory and Practice

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
Corporate Governance

Abstract

This chapter shows how the natural “science of control and communications in the animal and the machine” identified by Wiener in 1948 can be applied to social organizations to establish a science of governance. The science of governance provides a sustainable future for corporate governance theory and practice. Good governance is defined as the ability of organizations in the private, public and non-profit sectors to achieve their purpose in the most efficacious manner while minimizing the need for laws, regulations, regulators, courts or codes of so called “best practices” to protect and further the interests of their stakeholders and society. Evidence is provided that current best practices: (a) did not prevent firms failing to create the 2008 financial crisis; (b) are not based on theory or conclusive empirical evidence; and (c) are inconsistent with common sense. Systemic problems arising from organizations governed by a single board are identified. These include the absolute power of directors to manage their own conflicts of interest to allow the corruption of themselves and the organization. Examples of organizations with over a hundred boards show how network governance provides: (a) division of powers; (b) checks and balances; (c) distributed intelligence; (d) decomposition in decision making labor; (e) cross checking communication and control channels from stakeholder engagement; (f) integration of management and governance to further self-regulation and self-governance with: (g) operating advantage and sustainability. The examples illustrate how an ecological form of network governance could reduce the size, scope, cost and intrusiveness of government and their regulators while improving economic efficiency, resiliency and enriching democracy with widespread citizen stakeholder engagement.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 84.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 109.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD 109.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    The complexity of the MCC is parsimoniously summed up in the four columns and five rows of “Table 6.1, Holon typology of Mondragón” on page 221 of Turnbull (2001b). Table 6.1 allows the complexity of the MCC to be revealed as a consistent continuum of how the complexity of life is created and the universe emerges as shown in “Table 3.8, Holarchy: Hierarchy of Holons” on page 130. Table 6.1 also illustrates the point made by Simon (1962, p. 479): “the task of science is to make use of the world’s redundancy to describe that world simply.”

  2. 2.

    2nd Cambridge University Conference on ‘Regulation, Inspection & Improvement, Judge Business School Centre for Business Research, 12 September 2007.

References

  • Analytica. (1992). Board directors and corporate Governance: Trends in the G7 countries over the next 10 years. Oxford: Oxford Analytica Ltd.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ashby, W. R. (1956). An introduction to cybernetics. London: Chapman & Hall.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Baldwin, C.Y., & Clark, K.B. (2006). Where do transactions come from? A network design perspective on the theory of the firm. Harvard NOM Working Paper No. 06–12.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bazerman, M. H., Morgan, K. P., & Loewenstein, G. F. (1997). The impossibility of auditor independence. Sloan Management Review, 38(4), 89–94.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bazerman, M. H., Loewenstein, G., & Moore, D. A. (2002). Why good accountants do bad audits? Harvard Business Review, 80(11), 95–98.

    Google Scholar 

  • Beer, S. (1985). Diagnosing the system for organization. New York: Wiley.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bhagat, S., & Black, B. S. (2002). The non-correlation between board independence and long-term firm performance. Journal of Corporation Law, 27(2), 231–273.

    Google Scholar 

  • Braithwaite, J. (1997). On speaking softly and carrying big sticks: Neglected dimensions of a republication separation of powers. University of Toronto Law Journal, 47, 305–361.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Clarke, D. C. (2006). Setting the record straight: Three concepts of the independent director. GWU Legal Studies Research Paper No. 199, George Washington University Law School.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cochrane, P. (1997). Private e-mail communication to the author dated December 21 when head of British telecom research laboratories, UK.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cochrane, P. (2000). Hard drive: Bandwidth and brandwidth. 6 April, London: Telegraph.

    Google Scholar 

  • Craven, D. W., Piercy, N. F., & Shipp, S. H. (1996). New organizational forms for competing in highly dynamic environments: The network paradigm. British Journal of Management, 7(3), 203–218.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dallas, L. L. (1997). Proposals for reform of corporate boards of directors: The dual board and ombudsperson. Washington and Lee Law Review, 54(3), 92–146.

    Google Scholar 

  • Davis, J. H., Schoorman, F. D., & Donaldson, L. (1997). Towards a stewardship theory of management. Academy of Management Review, 22(1), 20–47.

    Google Scholar 

  • De Vany, A. (1998). How much information is there in an economic organization and why can’t large ones be optimal? Brazilian Electronic Journal of Economics, 1(1).

    Google Scholar 

  • Demb, A., & Neubauer, F. F. (1992). The corporate board: Confronting the paradoxes. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Demsetz, H. (1991). The theory of the firm revisited. In O. E. Williamson & S. G. Winter (Eds.), The nature of the firm: Origins, evolution and development (pp. 159–178). New York: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dunbar, R. I. M. (1993). Co-evolution of neocortical size, group size and language in humans. Behavioral and Brain Science, 16, 681–735.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fuller, B. R. (1961). Tensegrity. Portfolio and Art News Annual, No. 4.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gitins, M. M. (2002). Letter of 10 December to securities and exchange commission, Washington D.C. Re: Conflict with Russian Law under Section 301 of the Sarbanes-Oxley Act of 2002.

    Google Scholar 

  • Givens, B. (1991). Citizens’ utility boards: Because utilities bear watching. San Diego: Centre for Public Interest Law, University of San Diego School of Law.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gore, A. (1996). The technology challenge: What is the role of science in American society? Prepared remarks delivered to American association for the advancement of science. 12 February. Baltimore, Washington, DC: Office of the Vice President.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hatherly, D. J. (1995). The case for the shareholder panel. European Accounting Review, 4(3), 535–553.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hippel, E. V. (1994). Sources of Innovation. New York: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hayward, J. (2003). Thinking not ticking: Bringing competition to the public interest audit. London: Centre for the Study of Financial Innovation (CSFI).

    Google Scholar 

  • Hock, D. W. (1995). The chaordic organization: Out of control and into order. World Business Academy Perspective, 9(1), 4.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hock, D. W. (1999). Birth of the chaordic age. San Francisco: Berrett-Koehler Publishers.

    Google Scholar 

  • Howson, N. C. (2009). When “Good” corporate governance makes “Bad” (Financial) firms: The global crisis and the limits of private law. Michigan Law Review, 108, 44. First Impressions.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ingber, D. E. (1998). The architecture of life. Scientific American, 278, 30–39. January.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jackson, R. (2007). Are regulators and stock exchanges irresponsible?’ Posted by Robert Jackson managing editor (Ed), Harvard law school forum on corporate governance and financial regulation. Thursday 8 November 12:45 pm. Available at: http://blogs.law.harvard.edu/corpgov/2007/11/08/are-regulators-and-stock-exchanges-irresponsible/. Accessed 8 Nov.

  • Jensen, M. C. (1993). The modern industrial revolution: Exit and the failure of control systems. Journal of Finance, 48(3), 831–880.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jensen, M. C. (2009). Integrity: Without it nothing works. Rotman Magazine: The Magazine of the Rotman School of Management, 16–32.

    Google Scholar 

  • Jensen, M. C., & Meckling, W. H. (1976). Theory of the firm: Managerial behavior: Agency costs and ownership structure. Journal of Financial Economics, 3, 305–360.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jones, C., Hesterly, W. S., & Borgatti, S. P. (1997). A general theory of network governance: Exchange conditions and social mechanisms. Academy of Management Review, 22, 911–945.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kay, J. (1996). Regulating private utilities: The customer corporation. Journal of Co-operative Studies, 29(2), 28–46.

    Google Scholar 

  • Koestler, A. (1967). The ghost in the machine. London: Hutchinson.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kurzweil, R. (1999). The age of spiritual machines: When computers exceed human intelligence. New York: Viking.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lempert, M. (2003). Corporate governance at Matav. Paper presented to 6th international conference on corporate governance and board leadership, Henley, 7 Oct.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mathews, J. (1996). Holonic organizational architectures. Human Systems Management, 15, 27–54.

    Google Scholar 

  • Neumann, John von, (1947). Theory of Games and Economic Behaviour, New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Melis, A. (2004). On the role of the board of statutory auditors in Italian listed companies. Corporate Governance: An International Review, 12(1), 74–384.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • O’Connor, S. M. (2004). Be careful what you wish for: How accountants and Congress created the problem of auditor independence. Boston College Law Review, 45(5), 741–828.

    Google Scholar 

  • Page, A. (2009). Unconscious bias and the limits of director independence. University of Illinois Law Review, 2009(1), 237–294.

    Google Scholar 

  • Pirson, M., & Turnbull, S. (2011). Corporate governance, risk management, and the financial crisis – an information processing view. Corporate Governance: An International Review, 19(5), 459–470. September.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Porter, M. E. (1992). Capital choices: Changing the way America invests in business. Boston: Harvard Business School.

    Google Scholar 

  • Radner, R. (1992). Hierarchy: The economics of managing. Journal of Economic Literature, 30(3), 1382–1415.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rodrigues, U. (2007). The fetishization of independence. The UGA legal studies research paper No. 07–007, University of Georgia Law School, March.

    Google Scholar 

  • Romano, R. (2004). The Sarbanes-Oxley act and the making of quack corporate governance. Yale ICF Working paper 04–37, ECGI, Finance. Available at: http://ssrn.com/abstract=596101.

  • Shannon, C. E. (1948). The mathematical theory of communications. The Bell System Technical Journal, 27, 379/623–423/656.

    Google Scholar 

  • Shapiro, A. (2005). Who pays the auditor calls the tune? Auditing regulation and client’s incentives. Seton Hall Law Review, 35(3):1029–1095.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sharpe, N. F. (2010). Rethinking board function in the wake of the 2008 financial crisis. Journal of Technology and Business Law, 5(1)99–111.

    Google Scholar 

  • Simon, H. (1962). The architecture of complexity. Proceedings of the American Philosophical Society, 106, 467–482.

    Google Scholar 

  • Simon, H. (1984). On the behavioral and rational foundations of economic dynamics. Journal of Economic behavior and Organization, 5, 35–56. March.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sun, W., Stewart, J., & Pollard, D. (Eds.). (2011). Corporate governance and the global financial crisis-international perspectives (pp. 50–74). Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tomasic, R., & Akinbami, F. (2011). Towards a new corporate governance after the global financial crisis. International Company and Commercial Law Review, 8, 237–249.

    Google Scholar 

  • Turnbull, S. (1995). Best practice in the governance of GBEs. In J. Guthrie (Ed.), The Australian public sector: Pathways to change in the 1990s’ (pp. 99–109). Sydney: IIR Pty. Limited.

    Google Scholar 

  • Turnbull, S. (1997). Stakeholder Co-operation. Journal of Co-operative Studies, 29(3), 18–52. no.88.

    Google Scholar 

  • Turnbull, S. (2000a). Corporate charters with competitive advantages. St. Johns Law Review, 74(44), 101–159.

    Google Scholar 

  • Turnbull, S. (2000b). Stakeholder governance: A cybernetic and property rights analysis. In R. I. Tricker (Ed.), Corporate governance: The history of management thought (pp. 401–413). London: Ashgate Publishing.

    Google Scholar 

  • Turnbull, S. (2001a). The competitive advantage of stakeholder mutuals. In J. Birchall (Ed.), The new mutualism in public policy, chapter 9 (pp. 171–201). London: Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Turnbull, S. (2001b). The governance of firms controlled by more than one board: Theory development and examples. Sydney, Australia: Macquarie University PhD dissertation. Available at: http://ssrn.com/abstract=858244.

  • Turnbull, S. (2002a). A new way to govern: Organisations and society after Enron. London: The New Economics Foundation.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Turnbull, S. (2002b). The science of corporate governance. Corporate Governance: An International Review, 10, 256–272.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Turnbull, S. (2002c). Watchdog Boards: Past, present and future? Working Paper, February. Available at: http://papers.ssrn.com/abstract_id=608244.

  • Turnbull, S. (2008a). Muddled auditing practices. In C. Padmavathi & A. Bellur (Eds.), Audit committees: An insight (pp. 36–46). Hyderabad: The ICFAI University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Turnbull, S. (2008b). The science of governance: A blind spot of risk managers and corporate governance reform. Journal of Risk Management in Financial Institutions, 1(4), 360–368. July-September.

    Google Scholar 

  • Turnbull, S. (2008c). The theory and practice of government De-regulation. In J. Choi & S. Dow-Anvari (Eds.), International finance review: Institutional approach to global corporate governance (Vol. 9, pp. 117–139). Bingley: Emerald Publishing.

    Google Scholar 

  • Turnbull, S. (2009). Mitigating the exposure of corporate boards to risk and unethical conflicts. In R. W. Kolbe & D. Schwartz (Eds.), Corporate boards: Managers of risk, sources of risk, chapter 7 (pp. 143–74). Oxford: Blackwell.

    Google Scholar 

  • Turnbull, S. (2010). What’s wrong with corporate governance “Best” practices? In H. K. Baker & R. Anderson (Eds.), Corporate governance: A synthesis of theory research and practice (pp. 79–96). Hoboken: Wiley.

    Google Scholar 

  • Turnbull, S. (2011). Why “Best” corporate governance practices are unethical and less competitive? In L. Hartman & J. DesJardins (Eds.), Business ethics for personal integrity and social responsibility (2nd ed., pp. 576–583). Burr Ridge: McGraw-Hill.

    Google Scholar 

  • Turnbull, S. (2012). The limitations in corporate governance best practices. In T. Clarke & D. Branson (Eds.), Handbook of corporate governance, chapter 25. London/Thousand Oaks: Sage.

    Google Scholar 

  • Turnbull, S., & Pirson, M. (2012). Could the 2008 US financial crisis been avoided with network governance? International Journal of Disclosure and Governance, Special Issue on Financial Crises and Regulatory Responses, 9(1), 1–27.

    Google Scholar 

  • Vasudev, P. M., & Watson, S. M. (2012). Corporate governance after the financial crisis. In P. M. Vasudev & W. Susan Mary (Eds.), Corporate governance after the financial crisis. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.

    Google Scholar 

  • von Hippel, E. (1986). Lead users: A source of novel product concepts. Management Science, 32(7), 791–805.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • von Neuman, J. (1947). Theory of games and economic behavior. New Haven: Yale University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Weiner, N. (1948). Cybernetics: Control and communication in the animal and the machine. New York: Wiley.

    Google Scholar 

  • Williamson, O. E. (1975). Markets and hierarchies: Analysis and anti–trust implications. New York: Free Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Williamson, O. E. (1979). Transaction cost economics: The governance of transactional relations. Journal of Law and Economics, 22, 233–261.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Williamson, O. E. (1985). The economic institutions of capitalism. New York: Free Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Williamson, O. E. (1990). Industrial organization. London: Gower House.

    Google Scholar 

  • Zingales L. (2000). In search of new foundations. CRSP Working paper, 515.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Shann Turnbull .

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2012 Springer-Verlag Berlin Heidelberg

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Turnbull, S. (2012). A Sustainable Future for Corporate Governance Theory and Practice. In: Boubaker, S., Nguyen, B., Nguyen, D. (eds) Corporate Governance. Springer, Berlin, Heidelberg. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-642-31579-4_15

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics