Skip to main content

Empirical Secondary Data Analysis

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
Price Regulation and Risk

Part of the book series: Lecture Notes in Economics and Mathematical Systems ((LNE,volume 641))

  • 745 Accesses

Abstract

Chapter 4 examines whether decisions from regulatory agencies on future regulation parameters, contingent on the applied regulatory system (ROR-regulation or RPI-X regulation), have significant differences. Each decision to be reached by the regulatory agency or the complexity of the calculation is defined as the regulation parameter. The economic consequences for price-regulated companies resulting from these decisions by the regulatory agency are identified as regulatory risk. Regulatory risk is a component of unsystematic risk. Unsystematic risk is primarily of significance only for investors that are not completely diversified. For investors that are completely diversified, the systematic risk component is not relevant for business valuation.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 39.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 54.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    cf. Robinson and Taylor (1998), p. 337.

  2. 2.

    cf. Baecker et al. (2007), p. 276.

  3. 3.

    cf. Mandl and Rabel (1997), p. 290.

  4. 4.

    cf. Sect. 2.2.1.4.2 of this work.

  5. 5.

    This statement assumes that regulatory risk is the decisive factor for the amount of unsystematic risk and that the remaining non-systematic risk factors exert no decisive influence.

  6. 6.

    cf. Ballwieser (2002), p. 739; Mandl and Rabel (1997), p. 306; Purtscher (2006), p. 111; Ulschmid (1994), p. 210; on the relevance of considering industry peculiarities for business valuation cf. Drukarczyk and Ernst (2007): “… Industry peculiarities in valuation is thus not an academic game, but rather of decisive, practical relevance. Its meaning is, we presume at least, much higher than the value relevance from the so-called tax shields, which are hardly discussed in the scientific literature at length, although their value influence shrivels with increasing knowledge of interdependency. …,” Drukarczyk and Ernst (2007), p. VIII.

  7. 7.

    Stigler (1971), p. 3.

  8. 8.

    cf. Peltzman (1976), p. 214.

  9. 9.

    cf. Peltzman (1976), p. 212.

  10. 10.

    cf. Peltzman (1976), p. 213.

  11. 11.

    cf. Peltzman (1976), p. 230.

  12. 12.

    Binder and Norton (1999) characterize this as follows: “Unlike the earlier capture (Gray 1940) or public interest theories (Bernstein 1955), the Peltzman model predicts that the regulator will not choose a corner solution (maximize the wealth of one group) unless the other group is completely politically powerless.” Binder and Norton (1999), p. 250.

  13. 13.

    cf. Binder (1998), p. 111.

  14. 14.

    Bowman (1983) cites applications in other areas: the definition of equilibrium models and their improvement by identifying variables that explain the market behavior; cf. Bowman (1983), p. 562.

  15. 15.

    cf. Cox and Portes (1998), p. 282.

  16. 16.

    cf. MacKinlay (1997), p. 13 f.

  17. 17.

    cf. Cox and Portes (1998), p. 286 f.

  18. 18.

    Moreover, other procedural steps are to be established; presenting them would exceed the limits of this work. Reference is made here to Bowman (1983).

  19. 19.

    cf. MacKinlay (1997), p. 19 f.

  20. 20.

    cf. Brown and Warner (1980), p. 207 ff.

  21. 21.

    cf. Binder (1998), p. 117 ff.

  22. 22.

    cf. Cable and Holland (1999), p. 339.

  23. 23.

    cf. MacKinlay (1997), p. 21.

  24. 24.

    cf. Binder (1998), p. 113; MacKinlay (1997), p. 24.

  25. 25.

    cf. Binder (1998), p. 113; MacKinlay (1997), p. 24.

  26. 26.

    cf. Binder (1998), p. 123 f; Teets (1992), p. 278.

  27. 27.

    cf. Binder (1998), p. 124.

  28. 28.

    cf. The groundbreaking work on this by Binder (1985a).

  29. 29.

    cf. Dewan and Ren (2007), p. 9.

  30. 30.

    cf. Dewan and Ren (2007), p. 9.

  31. 31.

    Besides the study results presented here in a compressed, qualitative form, which are not integrated into the quantitative analysis of this work, reference is made to works listed in Appendix 2 that are also not included in the database of this work, in order to give the reader an overview of the current literature related to the set of questions thematized here. The claim to completeness is not made. Special notice should be given to the works of Norton (1985), Davidson et al. (1997), Morana and Sawkins (2000) and Buckland and Fraser (2002).

  32. 32.

    cf. Norton (1988), p. 224; Sect. 3.3 of the present work.

  33. 33.

    Norton (1988), p. 232.

  34. 34.

    cf. Dnes et al. (1998), p. 219.

  35. 35.

    Dnes et al. (1998), p. 221.

  36. 36.

    cf. Borrmann and Finsinger (1999), p. 343; Swoboda (1996), p. 377.

  37. 37.

    cf. Borrmann and Finsinger (1999), p. 415.

  38. 38.

    cf. on this Mandl and Rabel (1997) “… Market value-defining quantities are thus the expected cash flow […] on one hand and the return requirements from the investor operating in the capital market on the other. …,” Mandl and Rabel (1997), p. 18 f.

  39. 39.

    The simplifying assumption of constant cash flow, a constant, risk-free interest rate, a constant market premium and \( \alpha = {{\hbox{R}}_{\rm{f}}} \) are at the basis of the formalization. Furthermore, constant, unreal, complete self-financing is assumed. “Flow to equity” is to be slated as “cashflow”. Reference is made to Mandl and Rabel (1997), p. 367 ff. for a detailed presentation of the “equity approach.”

  40. 40.

    In this work, the 2-sided T-test is generally used to validate hypotheses by mean values or the Levene Test is used to validate hypotheses by spread measures. For forming hypotheses cf. Bortz (1999), Chap. 4. To validate various hypotheses, interrelated hypotheses and for the introduction in variance-analytical methods cf. Bortz (1999), Chaps. 5 and 6 as well as part II. Reference is made to Backhaus et al. (2000), p. 1–69 for detailed explanations on conducting regression analyzes.

  41. 41.

    cf. Fischer (2002), p. 102.

  42. 42.

    cf. among others, Binder and Norton (1999), Buckland and Fraser (2001) and Grout and Zalewska (2006).

  43. 43.

    Grout and Zalewska (2006) investigated the change announced from the RPI-X system into a “profit sharing system” in the electricity network industry in Great Britain in the 1990s. This type of system is identified by the feature that a company shares possible profits or losses from an RPI-X regulation with the consumers. It hence can be identified as a form combining a profitability regulation and an RPI-X regulation. While implementing the CAPM and the Fama French 3-factor model, Grout and Zalewska determined that the announced change led to a significant reduction in systematic risk, stating that: “… Taking the single-factor and three-factor evidence together, the paper shows that the impact on risk of regulatory changes specifically designed to impact on risk is both significant and consistent with theory,” Grout and Zalewska (2006), p. 180.

  44. 44.

    cf. Schwert (1981).

  45. 45.

    cf. Binder (1985b), p. 167 f.

  46. 46.

    Reference is made to Appendix 1 of this work for a detailed presentation of the events examined in the primary studies.

  47. 47.

    The results from the primary studies were integrated in this work in a balanced manner.

  48. 48.

    In this work, logarithmized returns are not computed analogously as done methodologically in the primary studies. cf. Strong (1992), p. 535 for applying logarithmized returns.

References

  • Baecker, Ph, Gleißner, W., Hommel, U.: Unternehmensbewertung – Grundlage rationaler M&A-Entscheidungen? Eine Auswahl zwölf wesentlicher Fehlerquellen aus praktischer Sicht. M&A Rev. 6, 270–277 (2007)

    Google Scholar 

  • Backhaus, K., Erichson, B., Plinke, W., Weiber, R.: Multivariate Analysemethoden – Eine anwendungsorientierte Einführung, 8. Auflage. Springer Verlag, Berlin, Heidelberg, New York (2000)

    Google Scholar 

  • Ballwieser, W.: Der Kalkulationszinsfuß in der Unternehmensbewertung: Komponenten und Ermittlungsprobleme. Die Wirtschafsprüfung 14, 736–743 (2002)

    Google Scholar 

  • Binder, J.J.: On the use of the multivariate regression model in event studies. J. Account. Res. 23, 370–383 (1985a)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Binder, J.J.: Measuring the effects of regulation with stock price data. RAND J. Econ. 16, 167–183 (1985b)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Binder, J.J.: The event study methodology since 1969. Rev. Quant. Finance Account. 11, 111–137 (1998)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Binder, J.J., Norton, P.W.: Regulation, profit variability and beta. J. Regul. Econ. 15, 249–265 (1999)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bortz, J.: Statistik für Sozialwissenschaftler, 5th edn. Springer Verlag, Berlin, Heidelberg, New York, Barcelona, Hongkong, London, Mailand, Paris, Singapur (1999)

    Google Scholar 

  • Borrmann, J., Finsinger, J.: Markt und Regulierung. Verlag Franz Vahlen, München (1999)

    Google Scholar 

  • Bowman, R.: Understanding and conducting event studies. J. Bus. Finance Account. 10, 561–583 (1983)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Buckland, R., Fraser, P.: Political and regulatory risk: beta sensitivity in U.K. Electricity distribution. J. Regul. Econ. 19, 5–25 (2001)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cable, J., Holland, K.: Modelling normal returns in event studies: a model-selection approach and pilot study. Eur. J. Finance 5, 331–341 (1999)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Davidson, W., Rangan, N., Rosenstein, P.: Regulation and systematic risk in the electric utility industry: a test of the buffering hypothesis. Financ. Rev. 32(1), 163–184 (1997)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dnes, A., Kodwani, D., Seaton, J., Wood, D.: The regulation of the United Kingdom electricity industry: an event study of price-capping measures. J. Regul. Econ. 13, 207–225 (1998)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Drukarczyk, J., Ernst, D. (eds.): Branchenorientierte Unternehmensbewertung, 2nd edn. Vahlen, München (2007)

    Google Scholar 

  • Fischer, E.O.: Finanzwirtschaft für Fortgeschrittene, 3rd edn. Oldenbourg Auflage, München/Wien (2002)

    Google Scholar 

  • Grout, P.A., Zalewska, A.: The impact of regulation on market risk. J. Financ. Econ. 80, 149–184 (2006)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Izan, H.Y.: “An empirical analysis of the economic effects of mandatory government audit requirements”. Dissertation, University of Chicago (1978)

    Google Scholar 

  • Mandl, G., Rabel, K.: Unternehmensbewertung – eine praxisorientierte Einführung. Ueberreuter Verlag, Wien/Frankfurt a.M. (1997)

    Google Scholar 

  • MacKinlay, C.A.: Event studies in economics and finance. J. Econ. Lit. 35, 13–39 (1997)

    Google Scholar 

  • Morana, C., Sawkins, J.W.: Regulatory uncertainty and share price volatility: the English and Welsh water industry’s periodic review. J. Regul. Econ. 17, 87–100 (2000)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Norton, P.W.: Regulation, the OPEC oil supply shock, and wealth effects for electric utilities. Econ. Inq. 26, 223–238 (1988)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Norton, P.W.: Regulation and systematic risk: the case of electric utilities. J. Law Econ. 28(3), 671–686 (1985)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Paleari, P., Redondi, R.: Regulation effects on company beta components. Bull. Econ. Res. 57(4), 317–346 (2005)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Peltzman, P.: Toward a more general theory of regulation. J. Law Econ. 29(2), 211–248 (1976)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Purtscher, V.: Komponenten des Kapitalisierungszinssatzes – Ein praxisorientierter Leitfaden zur Ableitung des Kapitalisierungszinssatzes nach CAPM. RWZ 4, 108–112 (2006)

    Google Scholar 

  • Robinson, T.A., Taylor, M.P.: The Effects of regulation and regulatory risk in the UK electricity distribution industry”. Ann. Publ. Cooper. Econ. 69(3), 331–346 (1998)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stigler, G.J.: The Theory of Regulation. Bell J. Econ. Manag. Sci. 3, 3–21 (1971)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Strong, N.: Modelling abnormal returns: a review article. J. Bus. Finance Account. 4, 533–553 (1992)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Swoboda, P.: Zur Anschaffungswertorientierung administrierter Preise (speziell in der Elektrizitätswirtschaft). Betriebswirtschaftliche Forschung und Praxis 48, 364–381 (1996)

    Google Scholar 

  • Fama, E. et al: The adjustment of stock prices to new information. International Economic Review, 10, 1969

    Google Scholar 

  • Ball, R.J. and Brown, P.: An empirical evaluation of accounting income numbers. Journal of Accounting Research, 6, 159–178, 1968

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Michael Hierzenberger .

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2010 Springer-Verlag Berlin Heidelberg

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Hierzenberger, M. (2010). Empirical Secondary Data Analysis. In: Price Regulation and Risk. Lecture Notes in Economics and Mathematical Systems, vol 641. Springer, Berlin, Heidelberg. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-642-12047-3_4

Download citation

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-642-12047-3_4

  • Published:

  • Publisher Name: Springer, Berlin, Heidelberg

  • Print ISBN: 978-3-642-12046-6

  • Online ISBN: 978-3-642-12047-3

  • eBook Packages: Business and EconomicsEconomics and Finance (R0)

Publish with us

Policies and ethics