Skip to main content

Building Trust to Solve Commons Dilemmas: Taking Small Steps to Test an Evolving Theory of Collective Action

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
Games, Groups, and the Global Good

Part of the book series: Springer Series in Game Theory ((SSGT))

Abstract

Extensive field research has found that when users of a resource do gain good feedback about the effect of their actions on a resource and can build norms of reciprocity and trustworthiness, they are frequently able to craft new institutions to solve puzzling dilemmas. We need to ask: How do different kinds of institutions support or undermine norms of reciprocity and trustworthiness? The finding from many field studies throughout the world that monitoring and graduated sanctions are close to universal in all robust common-pool resource (CPR) institutions is important as it tells us that without some external support of such institutions it is unlikely that reciprocity alone will allow individuals to solve CPR problems over time. On the other hand, the sanctions are graduated rather than initially severe. The current theory of crime deterrence – based on strict expected value theory – does not explain the graduated nature of these sanctions. But if people can learn to value trust and reciprocity and use them as fundamental norms for organizing their lives, they can agree on a set of rules that they agree to follow. Then graduated sanctions are a way of informing those, who have made an error or faced some emergency temptation, that others are watching and, if someone else were to break a rule, they would likely be observed. Thus, continuing to follow a positive norm of reciprocity is reasonable and it is then feasible to build trust over the long term.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 129.00
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 169.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD 169.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    See the special feature of PNAS of September 2007, where fourteen scholars from multiple fields took a major initiative to move “Beyond Panaceas” and to help develop a framework for diagnosing problems of social-ecological systems and reduce the tendency to think that there are optimal solutions for all kinds of commons problems characterized by huge diversity in their attributes, history, productivity, and scale.

  2. 2.

    These three broad clusters of variables are core elements used in the Institutional Analysis and Development (IAD) framework that has evolved from more than three decades of field research conducted by scholars associated with the Workshop in Political Theory and Policy Analysis at Indiana University. For an extended explanation of the IAD framework see Ostrom (2005).

  3. 3.

    For an in-depth discussion of the problems of recommending panaceas, see the Special Feature of PNAS mentioned in note 1 above.

  4. 4.

    One of the more successful efforts to create a private property-rights system for inshore fisheries has been developed over time in British Columbia after some initial efforts to create rules to limit fishing rights were not successful (Clark 2006). One of the costly but important attributes of the newer system of rules that has been evolved is that there is a monitor on every boat that is recording where the boat goes, the amount of fish harvested, any by-catch that is thrown over the side of the boat, and the amount of fish sold. The monitoring system is costly, but it does appear that over time fishers have begun to see the logic of the rule system that has been developed, agree to reduce their overharvesting, and know that others are being held to follow the rule.

References

  • Acheson J (2003) Capturing the commons: devising institutions to manage the Maine lobster industry. University Press of New England, Hanover, NH

    Google Scholar 

  • Adger N, Jordon A (eds) (2008) Governing sustainability. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Agrawal A (2000) Small is beautiful, but is larger better? Forest-management institutions in the Kumaon Himalaya, India. In: Gibson C, McKean M, Ostrom E (eds) People and forests: communities, institutions, and governance. MIT, Cambridge, MA, pp 57–85

    Google Scholar 

  • Agrawal A, Goyal S (2001) Group size and collective action: third-party monitoring in common-pool resources. Comp Polit Stud 34(1):63–93

    Google Scholar 

  • Ahn TK, Ostrom E (2008) Social capital and collective action. In Castiglione D, van Deth J, Wolleb G (eds) The handbook of social capital. Oxford University Press, Oxford, pp 70–100

    Google Scholar 

  • Alchian AA (1950) Uncertainty, evolution, and economic theory. J Polit Econ 58(3):211–21

    Google Scholar 

  • Alcock JE, Mansell D (1977) Predisposition and behaviour in a collective dilemma. J Conflict Resolut 21(3):443–57

    Google Scholar 

  • Axelrod R (1984) The evolution of cooperation. Basic Books, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Axelrod R (1986) An evolutionary approach to norms. Am Polit Sci Rev 80(4):1095–1111

    Google Scholar 

  • Axelrod R (1997) The complexity of cooperation: agent-based models of competition and collaboration. Princeton University Press, Princeton, NJ

    Google Scholar 

  • Axelrod R, Cohen MD (2000) Harnessing complexity. Free Press, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Baland J-M, Platteau J-P (1996) Halting degradation of natural resources: is there a role for rural communities? Clarendon, Oxford

    Google Scholar 

  • Baland J-M, Platteau J-P (1999) The ambiguous impact of inequality on local resource management. World Dev 27:773–788

    Google Scholar 

  • Berg J, Dickhaut J, McCabe K (1995) Trust, reciprocity, and social history. Games Econ Behav 10(1):122–142

    Google Scholar 

  • Berkes F, et al (2006) Globalization, roving bandits, and marine resources. Science 311:1557–1558

    Google Scholar 

  • Bicchieri C (2002) Covenants without swords: group identify, norms, and communication in social dilemmas. Rationality and Society 14(2):192–228

    Google Scholar 

  • Blomquist W (1992) Dividing the waters: governing groundwater in Southern California. ICS, San Francisco, CA

    Google Scholar 

  • Boero R, Bravo G, Castellani M, Squazzoni F (2008) Reputational cues in repeated trust games. Brescia, Italy: Università di Brescia, DSS Papers SOC 01–08

    Google Scholar 

  • Bohnet I, Frey BS (1999) The sound of silence in prisoner’s dilemma and dictator games. J Econ Behav Organ 38(1):43–58

    Google Scholar 

  • Bolton GE, Ockenfels A (2000) A theory of equity, reciprocity and competition. Am Econ Rev 90:166–193

    Google Scholar 

  • Bowles S (2008) Policies designed for self-interested citizens may undermine the moral sentiments: evidence from economic experiments. Science 320 (June 20):1605–1609

    Google Scholar 

  • Boyd R, Richerson PJ (1985) Culture and the evolutionary process. University of Chicago Press, Chicago

    Google Scholar 

  • Boyd R, Gintis H, Bowles S, Richerson PJ (2003) The evolution of altruistic punishment. PNAS 100:3531–3535

    Google Scholar 

  • Burnham TC (2003) Engineering altruism: a theoretical and experimental investigation of anonymity and gift giving. J Econ Behav Organ 50(1):133–144

    Google Scholar 

  • Camerer CF (2003) Behavioral game theory: experiments in strategic interaction. Princeton University Press, Princeton, NJ

    Google Scholar 

  • Camerer CF, Fehr E (2006) When does economic man dominate social behavior? Science 311 (January 6):47–52

    Google Scholar 

  • Cárdenas J-C, Stranlund JK, Willis CE (2000) Local environmental control and institutional crowding-out. World Dev 28(10):1719–1733

    Google Scholar 

  • Cárdenas J-C, Janssen M, Bousquet F Forthcoming Dynamics of rules and resources: three new field experiments on water, forests and fisheries. In: List J, Price M (eds) Handbook on experimental economics and the environment. Edward Elgar, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Clark CW (2006) The worldwide crisis in fisheries: economic models and human behavior. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Cole DH, Grossman PZ (fourthcoming) Institutions matter! why the herder problem is not a prisoner’s dilemma. Theoryy and Decision

    Google Scholar 

  • Coleman E, Steed B (2009) Monitoring and sanctioning in the commons: an application to forestry. Ecol Econ 68(7):2106–2113

    Google Scholar 

  • Cosmides L (1989) The logic of social exchange: has natural selection shaped how humans reason? studies with the Watson selection task. Cognition 31:187–276

    Google Scholar 

  • Cox J (2004) How to identify trust and reciprocity. Games Econ Behav 46:260–281

    Google Scholar 

  • Cox J, Deck CA (2005) On the nature of reciprocal motives. Econ Inq 43(3):623–636

    Google Scholar 

  • Cox J, Friedman D, Gjerstad S (2007) A tractable model of reciprocity and fairness. Games Econ Behav 59(1):17–45

    Google Scholar 

  • Cox J, Ostrom E, Walker J, Castillo J, Coleman E, Holahan R, Schoon M, Steed B (2009) Trust in private and common property experiments. South Econ J 75(4):957–975

    Google Scholar 

  • Crawford SES, Ostrom E (1995) A grammar of institutions. Am Polit Sci Rev 89(3) (September):582–600. Now revised as chapter 5 in Elinor Ostrom, Understanding Institutional Diversity (Princeton University Press, Princeton, NJ, 2005)

    Google Scholar 

  • de Quervain Dominique DJ-F, Fischbacher U, et al (2004) The neural basis of altruistic punishment. Science 305 (August 27):1254–1258

    Google Scholar 

  • Diekmann A (1986) Volunteer’s dilemma: a social trap without a dominant strategy and some empirical results. In: Diekmann A, Mitter P (eds) Paradoxical effects of social behavior: essays in honor of Anatol Rapoport. Physica, Vienna, pp 188–197

    Google Scholar 

  • Dietz T, Ostrom E, Stern P (2003) The struggle to govern the commons. Science 302(5652):1907–1912

    Google Scholar 

  • Dolšak N, Ostrom E (eds) (2003) The commons in the new millennium. MIT, Cambridge, MA

    Google Scholar 

  • Ebenhöh E, Pahl-Wostl C (2008) Agent behavior between maximization and cooperation. Rationality and Society 20(2):227–252

    Google Scholar 

  • Eckel CC, Grossman P (1996) Altruism in anonymous dictator games. Games Econ Behav 16(2):181–191

    Google Scholar 

  • Ehrlich PR, Levin SA (2005) The evolution of norms. PLoS Biol 3(6):e194

    Google Scholar 

  • Falk A, Fehr F, Fischbacher U (2005) Driving forces behind informal sanctions. Econometrica 73(6):2017–2030

    Google Scholar 

  • Faysse N (2005) Coping with the tragedy of the commons: game structure and design of rules. J Econ Surv 19(2):239–261

    Google Scholar 

  • Fehr E, Fischbacher U, Kosfeld M (2005) Neuroeconomic foundations of trust and social preferences: initial evidence. Am Econ Rev 95(2):346–351

    Google Scholar 

  • Fehr E, Gintis H (2007) Human motivation and social cooperation: experimental and analytical foundations. Annu Rev Sociol 33:43–64

    Google Scholar 

  • Fehr E, Schmidt K (1999) A theory of fairness, competition, and cooperation. Q J Econ 114: 817–851

    Google Scholar 

  • Folke C, Hahn T, Olsson P, Norberg J (2005) Adaptive governance of social-ecological systems. Annu Rev Environ Resour 30:441–473

    Google Scholar 

  • Frey BS (1994) How intrinsic motivation is crowded out and in. Rationality and Society 6(3): 334–352

    Google Scholar 

  • Frey BS (1997) A constitution for knaves crowds out civic virtue. Econ J 107:1043–1053

    Google Scholar 

  • Frohlich N, Oppenheimer J (1992) Choosing justice: an experimental approach to ethical theory. California University of California Press, Berkeley

    Google Scholar 

  • Frohlich N, Oppenheimer J (2000) How people reason about ethics and the role of experiments: content and methods of discovery. In: Lupia A, McCubbins MD, Popkin SL (eds) Elements of political reason: cognition, choice, and the bounds of rationality. Cambridge University Press, New York, pp 85–107

    Google Scholar 

  • Frohlich N, Oppenheimer J, Moore BJ (2001) Some doubts about measuring self-interest using dictator experiments: the costs of anonymity. J Econ Behav Organ 46(3):271–290

    Google Scholar 

  • Gardner R, Ostrom E (1991) Rules and games. Public Choice 70(2):121–149

    Google Scholar 

  • Ghate R, Jodha N, Mukhopadhyay P (eds) (2008) Promise, trust, and evolution: managing the commons of South Asia. Oxford University Press, Oxford

    Google Scholar 

  • Ghate R, Nagendra H (2005) The role of monitoring in institutional performance: forest management in Maharashtra, India. Conserv Soc 3(2):509–532

    Google Scholar 

  • Gibson C, Williams J, Ostrom E (2005) Local enforcement and better forests. World Dev 33(2):273–284

    Google Scholar 

  • Gintis H (2000) Game theory evolving: a problem-centered introduction to modeling strategic interaction. Princeton University Press, Princeton, NJ

    Google Scholar 

  • Goetze D (2008) Public goods, sharing genes, and the formation of large groups. Politics Life Sci 26(2):7–25

    Google Scholar 

  • Gordon HS (1954) The economic theory of a common property resource: the fishery. J Polit Econ 62 (April):124–142

    Google Scholar 

  • Gunderson LH, Pritchard L Jr (eds) (2002) Resilience and the behavior of large-scale systems. Island Press, Washington, DC

    Google Scholar 

  • Güth W, Huck S (1997) From ultimatum bargaining to dictatorship – an experimental study of four games varying in veto power. Metroeconomica 48(3):262–299

    Google Scholar 

  • Hardin G (1968) The tragedy of the commons. Science 162:1243–1248

    Google Scholar 

  • Hayashi N, Yosano A (2005) Trust and belief about others: focusing on judgment accuracy of others’ trustworthiness. Sociol Theory Methods 37:59–80

    Google Scholar 

  • Hayes T (2006) Parks, people, and forest protection: an institutional assessment of the effectiveness of protected areas. World Dev 34(12):2064–2075

    Google Scholar 

  • Henrich J, et al (2006) Costly punishment across human societies. Science. 312 (June 23):1767–1770

    Google Scholar 

  • Hoffman E, McCabe K, Shachat K, Smith VL (1994) Preferences, property rights, and anonymity in bargaining games. Games Econ Behav 7:346–380

    Google Scholar 

  • Hoffman E, McCabe K, Smith VL (1996) Social distance and other-regarding behavior in dictator games. Am Econ Rev 86(3):653–660

    Google Scholar 

  • Isaac RM, Walker JM (1998) Nash as an organizing principle in the voluntary provision of public goods: experimental evidence. Exp Econ 1:191–206

    Google Scholar 

  • Isaac RM, Walker JM, Williams A (1994) Group size and the voluntary provision of public goods: experimental evidence utilizing large groups. J Public Econ 54(1) (May):1–36

    Google Scholar 

  • Janssen M (2008) Evolution of cooperation in a one-shot prisoner’s dilemma based on recognition of trustworthy and untrustworthy agents. J Econ Behav Organ 65:458–471

    Google Scholar 

  • Janssen M, Goldstone R, Menczer F, Ostrom E (2008) Effect of rule choice in dynamic interactive spatial commons. Int J Commons 2(2):288–312

    Google Scholar 

  • Janssen M, Ostrom E (2006) Adoption of a new regulation for the governance of common-pool resources by a heterogeneous population. In: Baland J-M, Bardhan P, Bowles S (eds) Inequality, cooperation, and environmental sustainability. Princeton University Press, Princeton, pp 60–96

    Google Scholar 

  • Janssen M, Ostrom E (2008) TURFS in the lab: institutional innovation in real-time dynamic spatial commons. Rationality and Society 20(4):371–397

    Google Scholar 

  • Kaimowitz D, Angelsen A (1998) Economic models of tropical deforestation: a review. Center for International Forestry Research, Bogor, Indonesia

    Google Scholar 

  • Keser C (2003) Experimental games for the design of reputation management systems. IBM Syst J 42:498–506

    Google Scholar 

  • Kikuchi M, Watanabe Y, Yamagishi T (1996) Accuracy in the prediction of others trustworthiness and general trust: an experimental study. Jpn J Exp Soc Psychol 37(1):23–36

    Google Scholar 

  • Lave LB (1965) Factors affecting cooperation in the prisoner’s dilemma. Behav Sci 10:26–35

    Google Scholar 

  • Levin SA (1999) Fragile dominion: complexity and the commons. Perseus Books, Reading, MA

    Google Scholar 

  • Macy MW, Skvoretz J (1998) The evolution of trust and cooperation between strangers: a computational model. Am Sociol Rev 63:638–660

    Google Scholar 

  • Masters RD (2008) Historical change and evolutionary theory. Politics Life Sci 26(1):46–74

    Google Scholar 

  • Maynard Smith J (1982) Evolution and the theory of games. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Maynard Smith J, Szathmáry E (1997) The major transitions in evolution. Oxford University Press, Oxford

    Google Scholar 

  • McCabe K, Smith V (2001) Goodwill accounting in economic exchange. In: Gigerenzer G, Selten R (eds) Bounded rationality: the adaptive tool box. MIT, Cambridge, MA, 319–342

    Google Scholar 

  • McCay BJ, Acheson JM (1987) The question of the commons: the culture and ecology of communal resources. University of Arizona Press, Tucson

    Google Scholar 

  • Moran E, Ostrom E (2005) Seeing the forest and the trees. MIT, Cambridge, MA

    Google Scholar 

  • Mwangi E (2007) Socioeconomic change and land use in Africa: the transformation of property rights in Maasailand. Palgrave Macmillan, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Myers RA, Worm B (2003) Rapid worldwide depletion of predatory fish communities. Nature 423 (May 15):280–283

    Google Scholar 

  • NRC (National Research Council) (1986) Proceedings of the conference on common property resource management. National Academy Press, Washington, DC

    Google Scholar 

  • NRC (National Research Council) (2002) The drama of the commons. In: Ostrom E, Dietz T, Dolšak N, Stern P, Stonich S, Weber E (eds) Committee on the human dimensions of global change. National Academy Press, Washington, DC

    Google Scholar 

  • Ostrom E (1990) Governing the commons: the evolution of institutions for collective action. Cambridge University Press, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Ostrom E (1998) A behavioral approach to the rational choice theory of collective action. Am Polit Sci Rev 92(1):1–22

    Google Scholar 

  • Ostrom E (2003) Toward a behavioral theory linking trust, reciprocity, and reputation. In: Ostrom E, Walker J (eds) Trust and reciprocity: interdisciplinary lessons from experimental research. Russell Sage Foundation, New York, 19–79

    Google Scholar 

  • Ostrom E (2005) Understanding institutional diversity. Princeton University Press, Princeton, NJ

    Google Scholar 

  • Ostrom E (2007) A diagnostic approach for going beyond panaceas. PNAS 104(39):15181–15187

    Google Scholar 

  • Ostrom E (2008) The challenge of common-pool resources. Environment 50(4) (July/August):8–20

    Google Scholar 

  • Ostrom E, Gardner R, Walker J (1994) Rules, games, and common-pool resources. University of Michigan Press, Ann Arbor

    Google Scholar 

  • Ostrom E, Nagendra H (2006) Insights on linking forests, trees, and people from the air, on the ground, and in the laboratory. PNAS 103(51):19224–19231

    Google Scholar 

  • Ostrom E, Walker J (1991) Communication in a commons: cooperation without external enforcement. In: Palfrey TR (ed) Laboratory research in political economy. University of Michigan Press, Ann Arbor, 287–322

    Google Scholar 

  • Ostrom E, Walker J, Gardner R (1992) Covenants with and without a sword: self-governance is possible. Am Polit Sci Rev 86(2):404–417

    Google Scholar 

  • Pauly D, et al (2002) Toward sustainability in world fisheries. Nature 418:689–695

    Google Scholar 

  • Poteete A, Ostrom E (2004) Heterogeneity, group size and collective action: the role of institutions in forest management. Dev Change 35(3):435–461

    Google Scholar 

  • Rapoport A, Chummah AM (1965) Prisoners’ dilemma: a study of conflict and cooperation. University of Michigan Press, Ann Arbor

    Google Scholar 

  • Richards D (2001). Reciprocity and shared knowledge structures in a prisoner’s dilemma game. J Conflict Resol 45:621–635

    Google Scholar 

  • Richards K, Andersson K (2001) The leaky sink: persistent obstacles to a forest carbon sequestration program based on individual projects. Clim Policy 1:41–54

    Google Scholar 

  • Rilling JK, Gutman DA, Zeh TR, Pagnoni G, Berns GS, Kilts CD (2002). A neural basis for social cooperation. Neuron 35(2):395–405

    Google Scholar 

  • Rodriguez-Sickert C, Guzmán RA, Cárdenas JC (2008) Institutions influence preferences: evidence from a common-pool resource experiment. J Econ Behav Organ 67:215–227

    Google Scholar 

  • Rudel TK (2005) Tropical forests: regional paths of destruction and regeneration in the late twentieth century. Colombia University Press, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Sally D (1995) Conversation and cooperation in social dilemmas: a meta-analysis of experiments from 1958 to 1992. Rationality and Society 7:58–92

    Google Scholar 

  • Satz D, Ferejohn J (1994) Rational choice and social theory. J Philos 91(2):71–87

    Google Scholar 

  • Schlager E, Ostrom E (1992) Property-rights regimes and natural resources: a conceptual analysis. Land Econ 68(3):249–262

    Google Scholar 

  • Shivakumar S (2005) The constitution of development: crafting capabilities for self-governance. Palgrave Macmillan, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Simon A, Schwab D (2006) Say the magic word: effective communication in social dilemmas. Working Paper. Indiana University, Workshop in Political Theory and Policy Analysis, Bloomington

    Google Scholar 

  • Skyrms B (1997) Chaos and the explanatory significance of equilibrium: strange attractors in evolutionary game dynamics. In: Bicchieri C, Jeffrey R, Skyrms B (eds) The dynamics of norms. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, pp 199–222

    Google Scholar 

  • Xepapadeas A (2005) Regulation and evolution of compliance in common pool resources. Scand J Econ 107(3):583–599

    Google Scholar 

  • Yamagishi T, Kosugi M (1999) Character detection in social exchange. Cogn Stud 6(2): 179–190

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgment

An earlier version was presented at the symposium on “Games, Groups, God(s), and the Global Good” held at Princeton University, October 4–6, 2007, and for the Tanner Lecture at the University of Michigan, November 2, 2007. The support of the MacArthur Foundation and the National Science Foundation is gratefully acknowledged. I deeply appreciate the wonderfully helpful comments by Giangiacomo Bravo, Marco Janssen, Simon Levin, Tun Myint, Claudia Pahl-Wostl, and James Walker, and the excellent editing of Patty Lezotte.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2009 Springer-Verlag Berlin Heidelberg

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Ostrom, E. (2009). Building Trust to Solve Commons Dilemmas: Taking Small Steps to Test an Evolving Theory of Collective Action. In: Levin, S. (eds) Games, Groups, and the Global Good. Springer Series in Game Theory. Springer, Berlin, Heidelberg. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-540-85436-4_13

Download citation

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-540-85436-4_13

  • Published:

  • Publisher Name: Springer, Berlin, Heidelberg

  • Print ISBN: 978-3-540-85435-7

  • Online ISBN: 978-3-540-85436-4

  • eBook Packages: Business and EconomicsEconomics and Finance (R0)

Publish with us

Policies and ethics