Skip to main content

The Distinct Political Economies of Trade and Migration Policy: Through the Window of Endogenous Policy Models, with a Focus on North America

  • Conference paper
Labor Mobility and the World Economy

Abstract

The domestic politics of international trade seem to differ in fundamental ways from the domestic politics of immigration, but it is difficult to say exactly how and, more importantly, why. This paper uses a common frame of reference, simple endogenous policy models, as a way into this issue. These models capture the essential insight underlying much political economy analysis that material interests drive policy preferences. Part of the claim made in this paper is that trade politics appear to be essentially about material interest, while immigration politics are not. Related to this claim, however, is the complementary claim that the politics of these two seemingly similar issues are also organized in fundamentally different ways. The argument proceeds in five parts. The first part describes the general structure of endogenous policy models; the second provides a brief overview of theoretical and empirical work on trade; the third provides a similar overview of contemporary research on immigration politics; the fourth compares the political structures of the politics in these two domains; the fifth part concludes.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 129.00
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 169.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD 169.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Preview

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

Bibliography

  • Alt, J., J. Frieden, M. Gilligan, D. Rodrik, and R. Rogowski (1996). The Politics of International Trade: Enduring Puzzles and an Agenda for Inquiry. Comparative Political Studies 29(6): 689–717.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Alvarez, R.M., and T. Butterfield (2000). The Resurgence of Nativism in California? The Case of Prop. 187 and Illegal Immigration. Social Science Quarterly 81(1): 167–179.

    Google Scholar 

  • Amegashi, J.A. (forthcoming). A Political Economy of Immigration Quotas. Economics of Governance.

    Google Scholar 

  • Anderson, J., and M. Zanardi (2004). Political Pressure Deflection. Center Discussion Paper 2004-21. University of Tilburg, The Netherlands.

    Google Scholar 

  • Anderson, K., and R. Baldwin (1987). The Political Market for Protection in Industrial Countries. In A.M. El-Agraa (ed.), Protection, Cooperation, Integration and Development. New York: Macmillan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Austen-Smith, D. (1997). Interest Groups: Money, Information, and Influence. In D. Mueller (ed.), Perspectives on Public Choice: A Handbook. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Baack, C., and E.J. Ray (1973/1974). Tariff Policy and Income Distribution: The Case of the United States, 1830-1860. Explorations in Economic History 11(2): 103–121.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bailey, M., J. Goldstein, and B. Weingast (1997). The Institutional Roots of American Trade Policy: Politics, Coalitions, and International Trade. World Politics 49(3): 309–338.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baldwin, R. (1989). The Political Economy of Trade Policy. Journal of Economic Perspectives 3(4): 119–135.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baldwin, R. (1996). The Political Economy of Trade Policy: Integrating the Perspectives of Economists and Political Scientists. In R. Feenstra, G. Grossman, and D. Irwin (eds.), The Political Economy of Trade Policy. Cambridge: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Baldwin, R., and C. Magee (2000). Is Trade Policy for Sale? Congressional Voting on Recent Trade Bills. Public Choice 105(1/2): 79–101.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Balistreri, E. (1997). The Performance of the Heckscher-Ohlin-Vanek Model in Predicting Endogenous Trade Policy Forces at the Individual Level. Canadian Journal of Economics 30(1): 1–17.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bandyopadhyay, U., and K. Gawande (2000). Is Protection for Sale? Evidence on the Grossman-Helpman Theory of Endogenous Protection. Review of Economics and Statistics 82(1): 139–152.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bauer, R., I. de Sola Pool, and L.A. Dexter (1963). American Business and Public Policy: The Politics of Foreign Trade. Chicago: Aldine Publishing Company.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bean, C. (1995). Determinants of Attitudes towards Questions of Border Maintenance in Australia. People and Places 3(3): 32–39.

    Google Scholar 

  • Beaulieu, E. (2002a). Factor or Industry Cleavages in Trade Policy: An Empirical Analysis of the Stolper-Samuelson Theorem. Economics & Politics 14(2): 99–131.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Beaulieu, E. (2002b). The Stolper-Samuelson Theorem Faces Congress. Review of International Economics 10(2): 343–360.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Beaulieu, E., and C. Magee (2004). Four Simple Tests of Campaign Contributions and Trade Policy Preferences. Economics & Politics 16(2): 163–187.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Becker, G. (1983). A Theory of Competition Among Pressure Groups for Political Influence. Quarterly Journal of Economics 98(3): 371–400.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bellettini, G., and C, Berti Ceroni (2004). A Positive Analysis of Immigration Policy. Manuscript. Università di Bologna.

    Google Scholar 

  • Benhabib, J. (1996). On the Political Economy of Immigration. European Economic Review 40(9): 1737–1743.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bernheim, B.D., and M. Whinston (1986). Menu Auctions, Resource Allocation, and Economic Influence. Quarterly Journal of Economics 101(1): 1–31.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Betts, K. (1996). Immigration and Public Opinion in Australia. People and Place 4(3): 9–20.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bilal, S., J.-M. Grether, and J. de Melo (2003). Attitudes towards Immigration: A Trade-Theoretic Approach. Review of International Economics 11(2): 253–267.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bond, E. and T.-J. Chen (1987). The Welfare Effects of Illegal Immigration. Journal of International Economics 23(3/4): 315–328.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Borjas, G. (1995). Immigration and Welfare, 1970-1990. Research in Labor Economics 14(1): 251–280.

    Google Scholar 

  • Borjas, G. (1999a). Heaven’s Door: Immigration Policy and the American Economy. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Borjas, G. (1999b). The Economic Analysis of Immigration. In O. Ashenfelter and D. Card (eds.), Handbook of Labor Economics, Vol. 3A. Amsterdam: North Holland.

    Google Scholar 

  • Borjas, G. (2003). The Labor Demand Curve Is Downward Sloping: Reexamining the Impact of Immigration on the Labor Market. Quarterly Journal of Economics 118(4): 1335–1374.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Burns, P., and J. Gimpel (2000). Economic Insecurity, Prejudicial Stereotypes, and Public Opinion on Immigration Policy. Political Science Quarterly 115(2): 201–225.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Calavita, K. (1989). The Contradictions of Immigration Lawmaking: The Immigration and Reform Act of 1986. Law and Policy 11(1): 17–47.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Calavita, K. (1996). The New Politics of Immigration: “Balanced Budget Conservatism” and the Symbolism of Prop. 187. Social Problems 43(3): 284–305.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Canova, F., and M. Ravn (1998). Crossing the Rio Grande: Migrations, Business Cycles and the Welfare State. CEPR Discussion Paper 2040. London.

    Google Scholar 

  • Card, D. (2001). Immigrant Inflows, Native Outflows, and the Local Labor Market Impacts of Higher Immigration. Journal of Labor Economics 19(1): 22–64.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Citrin, J., D.P. Green, C. Muste, and C. Wong (1997). Public Opinion toward Immigration Reform: The Role of Economic Motivations. Journal of Politics 59(3): 858–881.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Coleman, J. (1998). Bipartisan Order and Partisan Disorder in Postwar Trade Policy. Manuscript. Political Science Department, University of Wisconsin.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cremer, H., V. Fourgeaud, M. Leite-Monteiro, M. Marchand, and P. Pestieau (1996). Mobility and Redistribution: A Survey. Public Finance 51(3): 325–352.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cremer, H., and P. Pestieau (1998). Social Insurance, Majority Voting and Labor Mobility. Journal of Public Economics 68(3): 397–420.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cukierman, A., Z. Hercowitz, and D. Pines (1994). The Political Economy of Immigration. Foerder Institute for Economic Research Working Paper 17/93. Tel Aviv.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dávila, A., J. Pagán, and M.V. Grau (1999). Immigration Reform, the INS, and the Distribution of Interior and Border Enforcement. Public Choice 99(3/4): 327–345.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Deardorff, A., and R. Stem (1998). An Overview of the Modeling of the Choices and Consequences of U.S. Trade Policies. In A. Deardorff and R. Stern (eds.), Constituent Interests and U.S. Trade Policies. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dixit, A. (1998). The Making of Economic Policy: A Transaction Cost Politics Perspective. Cambridge: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Drazen, A. (2000). Political Economy in Macroeconomics. Cambridge: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dustmann, C, and I. Preston (2001). Racial and Economic Factors in Attitudes to Immigration. CEPR Discussion Paper 2542. London.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dutt, P., and D. Mitra (2002). Endogenous Trade Policy through Majority Voting: An Empirical Investigation. Journal of International Economics 58(1): 107–133.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Epple, D., and T. Romer (1991). Mobility and Redistribution. Journal of Political Economy 99(4): 828–858.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Epple, D., T. Romer, and H. Sieg (2001). Interjurisdictional Sorting and Majority Rule. Econometrica 69(6): 1437–1465.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Epstein, D., and S. O’Halloran (1996). Divided Government and the Design of Administrative Procedures. Journal of Politics 58(2): 373–398.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Epstein, G., and S. Nitzan (2004). The Struggle Over Migration Policy. Manuscript. BarIlan University. Ramat Gan, Israel.

    Google Scholar 

  • Espenshade, T. (1998). U.S. Immigration and the New Welfare State. In D. Jacobson (ed.), The Immigration Reader: America in a Multidisciplinary Perspective. Oxford: Blackwell.

    Google Scholar 

  • Espenshade, T., and C. Calhoun (1993). An Analysis of Public Opinion toward Undocumented Immigration. Population Research and Policy Review 12: 189–124.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Espenshade, T., and K. Hempstead (1996). Contemporary American Attitudes toward U.S. Immigration. International Migration Review 30(2): 535–570.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ethier, W. (1986). Illegal Immigration. American Economic Review 76(1):56–71.

    Google Scholar 

  • Facchini, G., and G. Willmann (2001). The Political Economy of International Factor Mobility. Stanford Institute for Economic Policy Research 00–20.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fetzer, J. (2000). Public Attitudes toward Immigration in the United States, France, and Germany. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Findlay, R., and S. Wellisz (1982). Endogenous Tariffs, the Political Economy of Trade Restrictions and Welfare. In J. Bhagwati (ed.), Import Competition and Response. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Flores, O. (1997). The Political Economy of Immigration Quotas. Atlantic Economic Journal 25(1): 50–59.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Frieden, J., and R. Rogowski (1996). The Impact of the International Economy on National Policies: An Analytical Overview. In R. Keohane and H. Milner (eds.), Internationalization and Domestic Politics. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gang, I., F. Rivera-Batiz, and M.-S. Yun (2002). Economic Strain, Ethnic Concentration and Attitudes Towards Foreigners in the European Union. IZA Discussion Paper 578. Bonn.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gaston, N., and D. Nelson (2000). Immigration and Labour-Market Outcomes in the United States: A Political-Economy Puzzle. Oxford Review of Economic Policy 16(3): 104–114.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gaston, N., and D. Nelson (2002). The Wage and Employment Effects of Immigration: Trade and Labour Economics Perspectives. In D. Greenaway, R. Upward, and K. Wakelin (eds.), Trade, Investment, Migration and Labour Market Adjustment. Basingstoke: Palgrave-Macmillan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gawande, K., and P. Krishna (2003). The Political Economy of Trade Policy: Empirical Approaches. In E.K. Choi and J. Harrigan (eds.), Handbook of International Trade. Oxford: Blackwell.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gimpel, J., and J. Edwards (1999). The Congressional Politics of Immigration Reform. Boston: Allyn and Bacon.

    Google Scholar 

  • Goldberg, P., and G. Maggi (1999). Protection for Sale: An Empirical Investigation. American Economic Review 89(5): 1135–1155.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Goldin, C. (1994). The Political Economy of Immigration Restriction in the United States, 1890–1921. In C. Goldin and G. Libecap (eds.), The Regulated Economy: A Historical Approach to Political Economy. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Grether, J.M., J. de Melo, and T. Muller (2001). The Political Economy of Migration in a Ricardo-Viner Model. In S. Djajic (ed.), International Migration: Trends, Policy, Impact. London: Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Grossman, G., and E. Helpman (1994). Protection for Sale. American Economic Review 84(4): 833–850.

    Google Scholar 

  • Grossman, G., and E. Helpman (2001). Special Interest Politics. Cambridge: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Grossman, G., and J. Levinsohn (1989). Import Competition and Stock Market Return to Capital. American Economic Review 79(5): 1065–1087.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hall, H.K., and D. Nelson (1989). Institutional Structure and Time Horizon in a Simple Political-Economy Model: The Lowi Effect. International Spectator 24(3/4): 153–173.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hall, H.K., and D. Nelson (1992). Institutional Structure in the Political Economy of Protection: Legislated versus Administered Protection. Economics & Politics 4(1): 61–77.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hall, H.K., C. Kao, and D. Nelson (1998). Women and Tariffs: Testing Gender Gap in a Downs-Mayer Model. Economic Inquiry 36(2): 320–332.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hammermesh, D. (1993). Labor Demand. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hanson, G.H., and A. Spilimbergo (2001). Political Economy, Sectoral Schocks and Border Enforcement. Working Paper 44. CCIS, University of California, San Diego.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hatton, T., and J. Williamson (1998). The Age of Mass Migration: Causes and Economic Impact. New York: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Haupt, A., and W. Peters (1998). Public Pensions and Voting on Immigration. Public Choice 95(3/4): 403–413.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Helpman, E. (1995). Politics and Trade Policy. In D. Kreps and K. Wallis (eds.), Advances in Economics and Econometrics: Theory and Applications. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hill, J., and J. Mendez (1983). Factor Mobility in the General Equilibrium Model of Production. Journal of International Economics 15(1/2): 19–25.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hillman, A.L. (1988). The Political Economy of Protection. Chur: Harwood Academic Publishers.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hillman, A.L., and A. Weiss (1999). A Theory of Permissible Illegal Immigration. European Journal of Political Economy 14(4): 585–604.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hiscox, M. (1999). The Magic Bullet? The RTAA, Institutional Reform, and Trade Liberalization. International Organization 53(4): 669–698.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hiscox, M. (2001). The Magee Test Revisited: Industry Lobbying Patterns and the Stolper-Samuelson Theorem. Manuscript. Harvard University, Cambridge, Mass.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hood, M., and I. Morris (2000). Brother, Can You Spare a Dime? Racial/Ethnic Context and the Anglo Vote on Proposition 187. Social Science Quarterly 81(1): 194–206.

    Google Scholar 

  • Huber, G., and T. Espenshade (1997). Neo-Isolationism, Balanced Budget Conservatism, and the Fiscal Impacts of Immigrants. International Migration Review 31(4): 1031–1053.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Irwin, D. (1994). The Political Economy of Free Trade: Voting in the British General Election of 1906. Journal of Law and Economics 37(1): 75–108.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Irwin, D. (1996). Industry or Class Cleavages over Trade Policy? Evidence from the British General Election of 1923. In R. Feenstra, G. Grossman, and D. Irwin (eds.), The Political Economy of Trade Policy. Cambridge: MIT.

    Google Scholar 

  • James, J. (1978). The Welfare Effects of the Antebellum Tariff: A General Equilibrium Analysis. Explorations in Economic History 15(3): 231–256.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Johnson, G. (1998). The Impact of Immigration on Income Distribution Among Minorities. In D. Hammermesh and F. Bean (eds.), Help or Hindrance? The Economic Implications of Immigration for African Americans. New York: Russell Sage Foundation.

    Google Scholar 

  • Johnston, R., and M. Percy (1980). Reciprocity, Imperial Sentiment, and Party Politics in the 1911 Election. Canadian Journal of Political Science 13(4): 711–729.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jones, M.A. (1992). American Immigration. 2nd Edition. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Jones, R. (1965). The Structure of Simple General Equilibrium Models. Journal of Political Economy 73(6): 557–572.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jones, R. (1971). A Three-Factor Model in Theory, Trade and History. In J. Bhagwati et al. (eds.), Trade, Balance of Payments and Growth. Amsterdam: North-Holland.

    Google Scholar 

  • Jones, R., and J. Scheinkman (1977). The Relevance of the Two-Sector Production Model in Trade Theory. Journal of Political Economy 85(5): 909–935.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Karol, D. (2000). Divided Government and U.S. Trade Policy: Much Ado about Nothing? International Organization 54(4): 825–844.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kessler, A. (2001). Immigration, Insecurity, and the “Ambivalent” American Public. Manuscript. Department of Government, University of Texas, Austin.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kinder, D., and W. Mebane (1983). Politics and Economics in Everyday Life. In K. Monroe (ed.), The Political Process and Economic Change. New York: Agathon Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Laffont, J.-J. (2000). Incentives and Political Economy. Oxford: Clarendon Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lahav, G. (1997). Ideological and Party Constraints on Immigration Attitudes in Europe. Journal of Common Market Studies 35(3): 377–406.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Learner, E. (1995). The Heckscher-Ohlin Model in Theory and Practice. Princeton Studies in International Finance 77. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lejour, A., and H. Verbon (1994). Labour Mobility and Decision Making on Social Insurance in an Integrated Market. Public Choice 79(1/2): 161–185.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lohmann, S., and S. O’Halloran (1994). Divided Government and U.S. Trade Policy: Theory and Evidence. International Organization 48(4): 595–632.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lowell, B.L., F. Bean, and R. de la Garza (1986). Undocumented Immigration: An Analysis of the 1984 Simpson-Mazzoli Vote. Social Science Quarterly 67(1): 118–127.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lowi, T. (1964). American Business, Public Policy, Case Studies, and Political Theory. World Politics 16(4): 676–715.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • MacDonald, K., and B. Cain (1997). Nativism, Partisanship and Immigration: An Analysis of Prop. 187. In M. Preston, B. Cain, and S. Bass (eds.), Racial and Ethnic Politics in California. Berkeley: Institute for Governmental Studies.

    Google Scholar 

  • Magee, S. (1978). Three Simple Tests of the Stolper-Samuelson Theorem. In P. Oppenheimer (ed.), Issues in International Economics. Stocksfield: Oriel Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mayda, A.M. (2004). Who Is against Immigration? A Cross-Country Investigation of Individual Attitudes toward Immigrants. Manuscript. Georgetown University, Washington, D.C.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mayda, A.M., and D. Rodrik (2005). Why Are Some People (and Countries) More Protectionist Than Others? European Economic Review 49(6): 1393–1430.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mayer, W. (1984). Endogenous Tariff Formation. American Economic Review 74(5): 970–985.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mazza, I., and F. van Winden (1996). A Political Economic Analysis of Labor Migration and Income Redistribution. Public Choice 88(2): 333–363.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Michel, P., P. Pestieau, and J.-P. Vidal (1998). Labor Migration and Redistribution with Alternative Assimilation Policies: The Small Economy Case. Regional Science and Urban Economics 28(3): 363–377.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Milner, H. (1999). The Political Economy of International Trade. Annual Review of Political Science 2: (2): 91–114.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Milner, H., and B.P. Rosendorff (1997). Democratic Politics and International Trade Negotiations: Elections and Divided Government as Constraints on Trade Liberalization. Journal of Conflict Resolution 41(1): 117–146.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Moehring, H.B. (1988). Symbol versus Substance in Legislative Activity: The Case of Illegal Immigration. Public Choice 57(3): 287–294.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mussa, M. (1974). Tariffs and the Distribution of Income: The Importance of Specificity, Substitutability, and Intensity in the Short and Long Run. Journal of Political Economy 82(5): 1191–1203.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nelson, D. (1988). Endogenous Tariff Theory: A Critical Survey. American Journal of Political Science 32(3): 796–837.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nelson, D. (1989). Domestic Political Preconditions of US Trade Policy: Liberal Structure and Protectionist Dynamics. Journal of Public Policy 9(1): 83–108.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nelson, D. (1999). Problems in the Political Economy of Trade Policy Reform. Journal of International Trade and Economic Development 8(1): 3–26.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nelson, D., and Y. Xu (2001). The Political Economy of Illegal Migration. Manuscript. Tulane University and Georgia State University, New Orleans and Atlanta.

    Google Scholar 

  • Newton, L. (2000). Why Some Latinos Supported Proposition 187: Testing Economic Threat and Cultural Identity Hypotheses. Social Science Quarterly 81(1): 180–193.

    Google Scholar 

  • O’Halloran, S. (1994). Politics, Process, and American Trade Policy. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Olzak, S. (1992). The Dynamics of Ethnic Competition and Conflict. Stanford: Stanford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • O’Rourke, K., and R. Sinnott (2002). The Determinants of Individual Trade Policy Preferences: International Survey Evidence. Brookings Trade Policy Forum 2001, 157–196.

    Google Scholar 

  • Peltzman, S. (1976). Toward a More General Theory of Regulation. Journal of Law and Economics 19(2): 211–240.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Persson, T., and G. Tabellini (2000). Political Economics: Explaining Economic Policy. Cambridge: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Pincus, J.J. (1977). Pressure Groups and Politics in Ante-Bellum Tariffs. New York: Columbia University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Pope, C. (1972). The Impact of the Ante-Bellum Tariff on Income Distribution. Explorations in Economic History 9(4): 375–421.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ramey, V., and M. Shapiro (1998). Costly Capital Reallocation and the Effects of Government Spending. Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy 48: 145–194.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ramey, V., and M. Shapiro (2000). Displaced Capital: A Study of Aerospace Plant Closings. Journal of Political Economy 109(5): 958–992.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ray, E. (1987). Changing Patterns of Protectionism: The Fall in Tariffs and the Rise in Non-Tariff Barriers. Northwestern Journal of International Law and Business 8(2): 285–327.

    Google Scholar 

  • Razin, A., E. Sadka, and P. Swagel (1998). Tax Burden and Migration: A Political-Economy Theory and Evidence. Journal of Public Economics 85(2): 167–190.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Riezman, R., and J. Wilson (1995). Politics and Trade Policy. In J. Banks and E. Hanushek (eds.), Modern Political Economy. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rodrik, D. (1995). Political Economy of Trade Policy. In G. Grossman and K. Rogoff (eds.), Handbook of International Economics. Volume III. Amsterdam: North-Holland.

    Google Scholar 

  • Roemer, J. (2001a). Political Competition: Theory and Application. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Roemer, J. (2001b). The Non-Parochial Welfare Economics of Immigration. Manuscript. Yale University, New Haven, Conn.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rose-Ackerman, S. (1983). Beyond Tiebout: Modeling the Political Economy of Local Government. In G. Zodrow (ed.), Local Provision of Public Services: The Tiebout Model After Twenty-five Years. New York: Academic Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rosenfeld, M., and M. Tienda (1999). Mexican Immigration, Occupational Niches, and Labor Market Competition: Evidence from Los Angeles, Chicago, and Atlanta, 1970 to 1990. In F. Bean and S. Bell-Rose (eds.), Immigration and Opportunity. New York: Russell Sage Foundation.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ross, S., and J. Yinger (1999). Sorting and Voting: A Review of the Literature on Urban Public Finance. In P. Cheshire and E.S. Mills (eds.), Handbook of Urban and Regional Economics. Vol. 3 (Applied Urban Economics). Amsterdam: North-Holland.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rothstein, P. (1994). Learning the Preferences of Governments and Voters from Proposed Spending and Voting in School Budget Referenda. Journal of Public Economics 54(3): 361–389.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Salvanto, A. (1998). Initiatives as Running Mates: The Impact of a Candidate-Centered Initiative Campaign. Research monograph series paper, Center for the Study of Democracy, UC Irvine.

    Google Scholar 

  • Schattschneider, E.E. (1935). Politics, Pressure, and the Tariff. Englewood Cliffs: Prentice-Hall.

    Google Scholar 

  • Schattschneider, E.E. (1960). Semi-Sovereign People: A Realist View of Democracy in America. New York: Holt-Rinehart.

    Google Scholar 

  • Scheve, K., and M. Slaughter (2001a). What Determines Individual Trade Policy Preferences. Journal of International Economics 54(2): 267–292.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Scheve, K., and M. Slaughter (2001b). Labor Market Competition and Individual Preferences over Immigration Policy. Review of Economics and Statistics 83(1): 133–145.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Scholten, U., and M. Thum (1996). Public Pensions and Immigration Policy in a Democracy. Public Choice 87(3/4): 347–361.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schuck, P. (1992). The Politics of Rapid Legal Change: Immigration Policy in the 1980s. Studies in American Political Development 6(2): 37–92.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shughart, W., R. Tollison, and M. Kimenyi (1986). The Political Economy of Immigration Restriction. Yale Journal on Regulation 4(1): 79–97.

    Google Scholar 

  • Simon, J. (1996). Public Expenditures on Immigrants to the United States, Past and Present. Population and Development Review 22(1): 99–109.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Simon, R., and J. Lynch (1999). A Comparative Assessment of Public Opinion Toward Immigrants and Immigration Policies. International Migration Review 33(2): 455–467.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Smith, J., and B. Edmonston (1997). The New Americans: Economic, Demographic, and Fiscal Effects of Immigration. Washington, D.C.: National Academy Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sollner, F. (1999). A Note on the Political Economy of Immigration. Public Choice 100(3/4): 245–251.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stolper, W., and P. Samuelson (1941). Protection and Real Wages. Review of Economic Studies 9(1): 58–73.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Taussig, F. (1931). The Tariff History of the United States. 8th Edition. New York: G.P. Putnam’s Sons.

    Google Scholar 

  • Thompson, A. (1993). The Anticipated Sectoral Adjustment to the Canada-United States Free Trade Agreement: An Event Study Analysis. Canadian Journal of Economics 26(2): 253–271.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Thompson, A. (1994). Trade Liberalization, Comparative Advantage, and Scale Economies: Stock Market Evidence from Canada. Journal of International Economics 37(1/2): 1–27.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Timmer, A., and J. Williamson (1998). Immigration Policy Prior to the 1930s: Labor Markets, Policy Interactions, and Globalization Backlash. Population and Development Review 24(4): 739–771.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tolbert, C, and R. Hero (1996). Race/Ethnicity and Direct Democracy: An Analysis of California’s Illegal Immigration Initiative. Journal of Politics 58(3): 806–818.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Topel, R. (1994a). Regional Labor Markets and the Determinants of Wage Inequality. American Economic Review 84(2): 17–22.

    Google Scholar 

  • Topel, R. (1994b). Wage Inequality and Regional Labour Market Performance in the US. In T. Tachibanaki (ed.), Labour Market and Economic Performance: Europe, Japan and the USA. New York: St. Martin’s Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • VanHook, J., J. Glick, and F. Bean (1999). Public Assistance Receipt among Immigrants and Natives: How the Unit of Analysis Affects Research Findings. Demography 36(1): 111–120.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Waldinger, R. (1996a). Black/Immigrant Competition Reassessed: New Evidence from Los Angeles. Sociological Perspectives 40(3): 365–386.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Waldinger, R. (1996b). Who Makes the Beds? Who Does the Dishes? Black/Immigrant Competition Reassessed. In H. Duleep and P. Wunnava (eds.), Immigrants and Immigration Policy: Individual Skills, Family Ties, and Group Identities. Greenwich, Conn.: JAI Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Weck-Hannemann, H. (1990). Protectionism in Direct Democracy. Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics 146(3): 389–418.

    Google Scholar 

  • Yinger, J. (1985). Inefficiency and the Median Voter: Property Taxes, Capitalization, Heterogeneity, and the Theory of the Second Best. Perspectives on Local Public Finance and Public Policy 2(3): 3–30.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2006 Springer-Verlag · Berlin-Heidelberg

About this paper

Cite this paper

Greenaway, D., Nelson, D.R. (2006). The Distinct Political Economies of Trade and Migration Policy: Through the Window of Endogenous Policy Models, with a Focus on North America. In: Langhammer, R.J., Foders, F. (eds) Labor Mobility and the World Economy. Springer, Berlin, Heidelberg. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-540-31045-7_20

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics