Skip to main content

A Prototype Model of European Integration: The Case of Austria

  • Chapter
Dynamic Approaches to Global Economic Challenges
  • 420 Accesses

Abstract

As an EU member state since 1995, Austria has taken part in all subsequent European integration steps: the deepening of EU integration via the single market and Economic and Monetary Union (EMU) with the introduction of the euro, and the enlargement of the EU, in particular the grand enlargements of the EU since 2004. There have been and will be several anniversaries for Austria to celebrate around the years 2014 and 2015: 25 years since the fall of the Iron Curtain and hence the expansion of new market opportunities through the opening up of Eastern Europe; 20 years of EU membership and 15 years of EMU (euro) membership; 10 years since the start of the major EU enlargement towards Eastern Europe. With the Croatian accession in 2013, the EU now counts 28 members. To capture the effects of the last 25 years of Austria’s integration into Europe, an integration model is estimated. This is able to reproduce the main integration effects theoretically expected from the regime changes since 1989. In this respect, the Austrian integration model could also serve as a prototype for other EU member states. Overall, the participation in all integration steps since 1989 has added approximately 1 % to Austria’s real GDP per year.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

eBook
USD 16.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 109.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD 109.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. 1.

    In a comprehensive ex ante study Breuss et al. (1994) estimated the potential macroeconomic and sectoral effects of Austria’s EU accession with the WIFO macro cum input–output model. Keuschnigg and Kohler (1996) estimated, also ex ante, the possible Austrian integration effects of EU accession with a single-country dynamic general equilibrium model (sectoral and macroeconomic results).

  2. 2.

    A detailed overview of integration theories applicable for the several steps of European integration can be found in Badinger and Breuss (2011) and in Breuss (2014).

  3. 3.

    To estimate ex post the integration effects of Austria’s EU membership, on earlier occasions a similar small country macro model approach has been applied (Breuss 2010a, 2013c). In the case of a comparison of the integration performance of Austria, Finland, and Sweden in the EU (Breuss 2003b), and for the evaluation of the EU accession of Bulgaria and Romania (Breuss 2010b), small macro-integration models of a similar type as the present integration model were estimated to simulate the specific integration features of these countries.

  4. 4.

    The literature treats ‘regime changes’ in the context of ‘regime switching models’ using Markov chain econometrics (e.g., see Hamilton 2008). Generally, many economic time series occasionally exhibit dramatic breaks in their behaviour, associated with events such as financial or other crises. In our case, the breaks occurred due to four integration shocks (1989, 1995, 1999, and 2004/07) of European integration.

  5. 5.

    Badinger and Breuss (2005) analyzed the sectoral change of mark-up pricing after EU accession in Austria. The results were mixed. Some sectors had pronounced mark-up reductions (mining and quarrying, wholesale and retail trade, financial services and real estate), whereas in other sectors no notable mark-up change was found.

  6. 6.

    Prior to EU accession, candidate countries of the 2004 and 2007 enlargements had already abolished trade tariffs with the old EU member states in the context of the asymmetric liberalization process of the Europe agreements (EAs): The EU eliminated tariffs and NTBs on imports from the CEECS in 1997, and the CEECs did so by 2002. After EU accession, the new member states entered the customs union of the EU and participated in the EU’s single market program. That meant, on the one hand, adjustments of the national external tariff to EU’s CET and the abolition of border controls. Hence, the remaining trade costs were eliminated.

  7. 7.

    Levchenko and Zhang (2012) estimate welfare gains due to European trade integration since 2000 in the West (average +0.14 %; Austria, with +0.39 %, is the biggest winner) and in the East (+7.94 %). The biggest winners are Estonia (+17.25 %), Latvia (+11.93 %), and Bulgaria (+10.57); the welfare gains of the other CEES are below 10 %.

  8. 8.

    The detailed results for the four scenarios, and also the overall results, are quite similar to those of the earlier study, which covered the period 1989–2011 (see Breuss 2012, 2013c).

References

  • Badinger H, Breuss F (2005) Has Austria’s accession to the EU triggered an increase in competition? A sectoral markup study. Empirica 32(2):145–180

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Badinger H, Breuss F (2011) The quantitative effects of European post-war economic integration. In: Jovanovic MN (ed) International handbook on the economics of integration: factor mobility, agriculture, environment and quantitative studies, vol III. Edward Elgar, Cheltenham, pp 285–315

    Google Scholar 

  • Baldwin R, Venables AJ (1995) Regional economic integration. In: Grossman GM, Rogoff K (eds) Handbook of international economics, vol III. Elsevier Science B.V., Amsterdam, pp 1597–1644

    Google Scholar 

  • Breuss F (2002) Benefits and dangers of EU enlargement. Empirica 29(3):245–274

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Breuss F (2003a) Reale Außenwirtschaft und Europäische Integration. Peter Lang – Europäischer Verlag der Wissenschaften, Frankfurt am Main

    Google Scholar 

  • Breuss F (2003b) Austria, Finland and Sweden in the European Union: economic effects. Austrian Econ Q 4:131–158

    Google Scholar 

  • Breuss F (2006) Monetäre außenwirtschaft und Europäische integration. Peter Lang – Europäischer Verlag der Wissenschaften, Frankfurt am Main

    Google Scholar 

  • Breuss F (2010a) 15 years of Austrian EU membership. Austrian Econ Q 15:165–183

    Google Scholar 

  • Breuss F (2010b) An evaluation of the EU’s fifth enlargement: with special focus on Bulgaria and Romania. In: Szekeley I, Keereman F (eds) Five years of an enlarged EU – a positive sum game. Springer, Berlin, pp 221–248

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Breuss F (2010c) Globalisation, EU enlargement and income distribution. Int J Public Policy 6(1–2):16–34

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Breuss F (2012) EU-Mitgliedschaft Österreichs. Eine Evaluierung in Zeiten der Krise. WIFO, Vienna, October 2012. Available from: http://www.wifo.ac.at/wwa/pubid/45578

  • Breuss F (2013a) Towards a new EMU. WIFO Working Papers, Nr. 447, March 2013

    Google Scholar 

  • Breuss F (2013b) Towards United States of Europe. In: Visions for economic policy coordination in Europe. Federal Ministry of Economy, Family and Youth, Vienna, pp 27–47

    Google Scholar 

  • Breuss F (2013c) Effects of Austria’s EU membership. WIFO Austrian Econ Q 18:103–114, Available from: http://www.wifo.ac.at/jart/prj3/wifo/main.jart

    Google Scholar 

  • Breuss F (2014) A prototype model of European integration: the case of Austria. WIFO Working Papers, No. 465, March 2014

    Google Scholar 

  • Breuss F, Kratena K, Schebeck F (1994) Effekte eines EU-Beitritts für die Gesamtwirtschaft und für die einzelnen Sektoren, Sonderheft der WIFO-Monatsberichte Österreich in der Europäischen Union: Anforderungen und Chance für die Wirtschaft, Wien

    Google Scholar 

  • Breuss F, Roeger W, Veld J (2015) The stabilising properties of a European Banking Union in case of financial shocks in the euro area. European Economy, Economic Papers, No. 550, European Commission, Brussels, June 2015

    Google Scholar 

  • Felbermayr G, Larch M, Krüger F, Flach L, Yalcin E, Benz S (2013) Dimensionen und Auswirkungen eines Freihandelsabkommens zwischen der EU und den USA, ifo Forschungsbericht, Nr. 62, München 2013

    Google Scholar 

  • Hamilton JD (2008) Regime-switching models. In: Durlauf SN, Blume LE (eds) The New Palgrave dictionary of economics, 2nd edn. Palgrave Macmillan. Available from: http://www.dictionaryofeconomics.com/article?id=pde2008_R000269. doi:10.1057/9780230226203.1411

  • Jovanovic MN (ed) (2011) International handbook on the economics of integration (3 vols). Edward Elgar, Cheltenham

    Google Scholar 

  • Keuschnigg C, Kohler W (1996) Austria in the European Union: dynamic gains from integration and distributional implications. Econ Policy 22:155–211

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Levchenko AA, Zhang J (2012) Comparative advantage and the welfare impact of European integration. NBER Working Paper, No. 18061, May 2012

    Google Scholar 

  • McKinsey Germany (2012) The future of the euro: an economic perspective on the eurozone crisis. McKinsey & Company, Frankfurt

    Google Scholar 

  • Viner J (1950) The customs union issue. Carnegie Endowment, New York

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Fritz Breuss .

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

Appendices

Appendix 1: The Estimated Integration Model for Austria

Real GDP (Cobb–Douglas production function; bn. EUR, 2005 prices)

GDPR = (TFP) * ((K^0.26) * (EE^0.74))

Total factor productivity (TFP)

DLOG(TFP) = −0.0117597194657 + 0.975350400527 * DLOG(AP) + 0.00368866066045 * RAD + 0.000364739422324 * D(XQUOTA)

Research & development: R&D in % of GDP

RAD = −0.771758304314 + 0.0900123360683 * LOG(GDPR) + 0.918022689413 * RAD(−1) + 0.450963636885 * D_1995_2015

Private consumption deflator

DLOG(PCN) = 0.974494644295 * DLOG(CPI) − 0.0100090054202 * D_2002

Private consumption index: National definition

DLOG(CPI) = 0.00685148354097 + 0.210308218697 * MARKUP * DLOG(ULC) + 0.232379177613 * MARKUP * DLOG(PM) + 0.407094518941 * DLOG(CPI(−1)) + 0.014977340126 * D_1984

Harmonized index of consumer prices: HICP

DLOG(HICP) = 0.974397164556 * DLOG(CPI)

GDP deflator

DLOG(PGDP) = 0.883285761406 * DLOG(CPI) + 0.432199804412 * DLOG(PX) − 0.275658593485 * DLOG(PM)

Wage per employee (Phillips curve)

DLOG(WE) = −0.00688732197519 + 0.658922532489 * DLOG(CPI) + 0.439378457835 * DLOG(AP(−1)) + 0.0643927893279 * 1 / U − 0.059812308921 * D_1980

Wages

WN = (WE * E) / 1000

Taylor rule for the euro area

RSH_EA18 = 2 + DLOG(HICP_EA18) * 100 + 0.5 * (DLOG(HICP_EA18) * 100 − 2.0) + 0.5 * (DLOG(GDPR_EA18) * 100 − 1.5)

Interest rate, short-term

RSH = −5.5262147236 + 0.667905535844 * RSH_EA18 + 0.0136803208004 * LOG(CPI) * 100 − 2.35378845633 * D_1983

Interest rate, long-term

RLH = 0.400105575997 + 0.23428902887 * RSH + 0.152448613707 * DLOG(CPI) * 100 + 0.674036427571 * RLH(−1)

Capital demand

DLOG(K) = 0.000347597990373 + 0.000690816072569 * D(BUD) − 0.000555726084856 * PRDEF + 0.10749650936 * DLOG(GDPR) + 0.000211122052822 * D(DLOG(WE) * 100 − (RLH − DLOG(PGDP) * 100)) + 0.879984556303 * DLOG(K(−1))

Capital coefficient: K/Y

KY = (K / GDPR)

Labor demand (total employment)

DLOG(EE) = 0.174447800692 * DLOG(GDPR) − 0.0646686954094 * DLOG(WE) + 0.00183780684966 * D(BUD) + 0.688076954685 * DLOG(EE(−1))

Labor demand (employees)

DLOG(E) = −0.0020926578709 + 0.787853784774 * DLOG(EE) + 0.174748348465 * DLOG(GDPR) + 0.262099988497 * DLOG(E(−1))

Labor supply: Labor force

LS = EE + US

Labor productivity (total economy)

AP = (GDPR / EE)

Unit labor costs

ULC = (WN / GDPR)

Unemployment rate (Okun’s law)

D(U) = 0.0856028080042 − 7.48943374025 * DLOG(GDPR) + 0.00304288354196 * D(POP − MIGR_OST89 − MIGR_EU95 − MIGR_EUEW04) + 0.804600244209 * D_1982 − 0.0362182637141 * BUD

Unemployment, total in 1000 persons

US = ((U * LS) / 100)

Exports of goods and services, total, real

DLOG(XGSR) = −0.0436572302437 + 2.22907387142 * DLOG(GDPR_EU28) − 0.555430829575 * DLOG(REER_IC37) + 0.0393558155438 * D_1989_2015

Exports of goods and services, total, nominal bn. EUR

XGSN = XGSR * (PX / 100)

Export quota: Exports goods and services in % of GDP

XQUOTA = (XGSN / GDPN) * 100

Imports of goods and services, total, real

LOG(MGSR) = −5.3567516112 + 1.77756769413 * LOG(GDPR) + 0.228751889216 * D_1989_2015

Imports of goods and services, total, nominal bn. EUR

MGSN = MGSR * (PM / 100)

Import quota: Imports goods and services in % of GDP

MQUOTA = (MGSN / GDPN) * 100

Current account in nominal bn. EUR (AMECO)

CA = XGSN − MGSN

Current account in % of GDP (AMECO)

CAGDPN = ((XGSN − MGSN) / GDPN) * 100

Current account in nominal bn. EUR (OeNB)

CA_OeNB = CA − CA_Diff_to_OeNB

Current account in % of GDP (OeNB)

CA_OeNBGDPN = ((CA_OeNB) / GDPN) * 100

FDI outflows in % of GDP

FDIEX = 0.375640070717 + 1.02837425753 * D(FDISOUT)

FDI outward stocks in % of GDP

FDISOUT = −23.7147058544 + 0.883784157118 * FDISOUT(−1) + 23.3682906272 * D_1989_2015

FDI inflows in % of GDP

FDIIN = 0.671986218682 + 0.84990945751 * D(FDISIN)

FDI inwards stocks in % of GDP

FDISIN = −28.0471754242 + 0.810412880324 * FDISIN(−1) + 28.0293244537 * D_1989_2015

Net household disposable income, nominal (bn. EUR; OECD Economic Outlook; Macrobond)

YDN = 2.18851454149 + 0.11686303161 * GDPN + 0.817157924902 * YDN(−1)

Net household disposable income, real (bn. EUR)

YDR = (YDN / (PCN / 100))

GDP, nominal (bn. EUR)

GDPN = (GDPR * (PGDP / 100))

Real GDP per capita (in 1000 EUR) − WELFARE measure 1

GDPRPC = ((GDPR * 1000) / (POP − MIGR_OST89 − MIGR_EU95 − MIGR_EUEW04))

GDP per capita in PPS (EU-28 = 100) − WELFARE measure 2

LOG(GDPPC_PPSEU28) = 0.43328354923 + 0.00346210004573 * DLOG(GDPRPC) + 0.911257550549 * LOG(GDPPC_PPSEU28(−1)) − 0.0461887756332 * D_2001

Budget position: Budget balance in % of GDP

BUD = −1.28851868518 + 0.354920098741 * DLOG(GDPR) * 100 − 0.594239170511 * ELEC + 0.700806989349 * BUD(−1) − 2.70112458588 * D_2004

Budget position: Budget balance in % of GDP incl. Net contribution to EU budget

BUDNET = BUD + NETEU

Austria–EU Budget position absolute values in bn. EUR

NETEUABS = (NETEU * GDPN) / 100

Public debt dynamics: Gross public debt in % of GDP (DEBT = DEBT(−1) − PD − (r − g)*DEBT(−1) + SF (Stock flow))

DEBT = DEBT(−1) − PRDEF + SNOW + SF

Primary budget balance in % GDP

PRDEF = BUD − INTEREST

Interest payments in % of GDP

INTEREST = 0.187508058025 + 7.27693766331 * (RLH / 100) * ((DEBT(−1)) / GDPN(−1)) + 0.893137557651 * INTEREST(−1)

Snow-ball effect

SNOW = 0.276597903339 + 0.00796005959488 * (RLH − DLOG(GDPN) * 100) * DEBT(−1)

Wage share: Wages in % of GDP (‘Globalization’ reduces LQ)

LQ = 15.1699479237 − 0.0316886728056 * (XQUOTA + MQUOTA) − 0.00942994300939 * D(FDISOUT + FDISIN) + 0.791815264509 * LQ(−1) + 3.87639625065 * D_1975

  1. DLOG(Variable) = percentage change operator. Estimation with EViews 7.0 for the period 1960–2015. Data source AMECO database of the European Commission; PX (PM) = deflators of exports (imports) of goods and services; D_1989_2015 = ‘smart’ dummy ‘Regime change T+FDI’; D_1995_2015 = ‘smart’ dummy for ‘Regime change R&D’; FDI = foreign direct investment; OeNB = Austrian National Bank
Table 7
Table 8

Appendix 2: Quantitative Model Inputs of Four Integration Scenarios (Additional Effects Compared to the Baseline Scenario Without EU Integration)

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2016 Springer International Publishing Switzerland

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Breuss, F. (2016). A Prototype Model of European Integration: The Case of Austria. In: Bednar-Friedl, B., Kleinert, J. (eds) Dynamic Approaches to Global Economic Challenges. Springer, Cham. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-319-23324-6_2

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics