Skip to main content

On the Access Principle in Science: A Law and Economics Analysis

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
Copyright Versus Open Access

Part of the book series: International Law and Economics ((ILEC))

Abstract

This section provides a comprehensive analysis comparing both systems from a social welfare point of view and hence asking whether academic publishing should be organized by means of a universal closed or open access mode. The first subsection is an extensive view on both regimes and their impact in the light of the publishing game and hence the prevailing “publish or perish”—environment in scientific research. The impact on researcher’s private incentives to write high quality papers will be investigated as well as the social welfare effects when shifting towards an universal OA regime. Several robustness checks and a model extension to think outside the box of the model’s inherent contest character provide a broad picture on the superiority of either regime. The second subsection picks up on the distributive effects from shifting towards an “author pays” principle when introducing OA as the dominant publishing mode, briefly highlighting some possible distortions that may result in an obviously heterogeneous world. In this regard, especially the consequences for developing countries will be addressed, providing the analytical framework for investigating the international political economy of access to scientific knowledge in Sect. 4.2 of this chapter.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 39.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Hardcover Book
USD 54.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    This section is joint research with Eberhard Feess (Frankfurt School of Finance and Management). However, this subsection presents a shortened version of the original model in Feess and Scheufen (2013). In particular, the model extensions (robustness) are not presented here, but will be discussed in the conclusions.

  2. 2.

    See Congleton et al. (2008) on the theory of rent-seeking.

  3. 3.

    Of course, such a perspective does not necessarily contradict the relevance of intrinsic motivation. See e.g. the case studies discussed in Andreff and Szymanski (2006) on intrinsic motivation in tournaments. As we have seen, there are two types of intrinsic motivation in scientific research: community-based intrinsic motivation (peer recognition/reputation) and enjoyment-based intrinsic motivation (intellectual satisfaction).

  4. 4.

    See the seminal contribution on multi-tasking by Holmström and Migrom (1991), followed by a large body of literature showing that incentives are often distorted as only easily measurable activities are rewarded. We will further elaborate on these insights in Chap. 5

  5. 5.

    This is a direct consequence of the “publish or perish” environment of scientific research. Obviously, researchers are “locked-in” to a system that gives credit only based on publications and rankings. Meho (2007) finds empirical evidence that more and more of research has been produced, but is hardly ever read. The author shows that only 50 % of all peer-reviewed journal articles are ever read by anybody else but the reviewers and the authors. About 90 % of all articles are never cited. See also Laband and Tollison (2003). We will pick up on the negative incentives of “publish or perish” in Chap. 5

  6. 6.

    See Konrad (2009) for a comprehensive overview on contest models.

  7. 7.

    Crane (1965) provides evidence that scientists at major schools also attract higher peer recognition than researchers at minor universities.

  8. 8.

    Costs for a single publication, for example in a Public Library of Science (PLoS) journal, currently ranges from $1,350 (PLoS ONE) to $2,900 (PLoS Biology or PLoS Medicine). See http://www.plos.org/journals/pubfees.html (last accessed on September 1, 2014). Besides, King (2007) estimates that the average fixed costs for publishing a single article is $3,000.

  9. 9.

    We will elaborate on this aspect in Sect. 4.1.2.

  10. 10.

    Please note that our model seeks a welfare comparison of both pure systems, i.e. we do not analyze the decisions of scientists between coexisting regime (closed versus open access), but the assume that all scientists publish under the same mode. Consequently, our paper does not address the previously mentioned problem of an inefficient Nash equilibrium in a system where both publishing modes coexist. For a game theoretical analysis of this aspect see e.g. Hanauske et al. (2009).

  11. 11.

    While top universities dominate the ranking, it contains also many academics from smaller institutions with lower reputation, and rules on the coverage of submission fees are quite different. Notwithstanding the fact that the ranking is subject to reasonable criticism, it has high incentive effects.

  12. 12.

    Normalizing readership with open access to 1 is without loss of generality.

  13. 13.

    Both properties also hold for the more general case where \(p_{H} = \frac{\theta \left (e_{H}\right )^{t}} {\theta \left (e_{H}\right )^{t}+\left (e_{L}\right )^{t}}\) and \(p_{L} = \frac{\left (e_{L}\right )^{t}} {\theta \left (e_{H}\right )^{t}+\left (e_{L}\right )^{t}}\). In this more general version, t captures the degree of discrimination, that is the sensitivity of winning the contest to the efforts taken by the players.

  14. 14.

    As submission costs are only positive for the low type under open access, we will subsequently write g instead of g L o for short.

  15. 15.

    In our non-strategic model below, we follow Shavell (2010) by deriving readership explicitly as a function of prices. Including this in a contest-model, however, would yield a very convoluted model structure and would add nothing to the points we wish to make.

  16. 16.

    Superscript “f” denotes “first best”.

  17. 17.

    The differences in the private and socially optimal efforts with open access are \(\Delta e_{L}^{O} \equiv e_{L}^{O} - e_{L}^{f} = \frac{\theta \left (1-g\right )^{2}} {\left (1+\theta -g\right )^{2}} -\frac{\beta ^{2}} {4}\) and \(\Delta e_{H}^{O} \equiv e_{H}^{O} - e_{H}^{f} = \frac{\theta \left (1-g\right )} {\left (1+\theta -g\right )^{2}} -\frac{\theta \beta ^{2}} {4}\) which gives derivatives of \(\frac{\partial \Delta e_{L}^{O}} {\partial g} = -\frac{2\theta ^{2}\left (1-g\right )} {\left (\theta -g+1\right )^{3}} < 0\) and \(\frac{\partial \Delta e_{H}^{O}} {\partial g} = -\frac{\theta \left (g+\theta -1\right )} {\left (\theta -g+1\right )^{3}} < 0\).

  18. 18.

    Recall that r C implicitly measures the readership with closed access relative to open access as r O is normalized to one.

  19. 19.

    For reasons of clarity we refrain from presenting the specific model extension here, but focus on a short discussion and the results. Please see Feess and Scheufen (2013) for a detailed presentation.

  20. 20.

    Note that differences between the cost functions of the players in the contest is an often applied alternative for modelling heterogeneity in tournaments. See also the overview in Konrad (2009).

  21. 21.

    In our model this is captured by arguing that the effort costs are θ i e i , where \(\theta _{h} <\theta _{l}\) determines that the high type has a cost advantage over the low type researcher.

  22. 22.

    Note that the reputation of an author, e.g. his position in a ranking, may be a signal of quality. With other words, it is not far fetched to believe that well-renowned researchers attract a higher readership as compared to a hardly known (young) academic.

  23. 23.

    We integrate type-specific readership into the social welfare function by introducing a parameter that is h(l) when reading a high-type (low-type) article, where h = 1 > l expresses the higher benefit from reading an article from an author with high reputation. See Feess and Scheufen (2013) for a detailed discussion.

  24. 24.

    In a follow-up paper, we drop the rent-seeking motive and hence the contest character. Instead we consider a non-strategic model of quality provision. In doing so we follow Shavell (2010) as closely as possible, but introduce quality and also depart from the assumptions that all universities will cover the publication costs under OA. We then find that quality incentives are always too low for both types under closed access. Interestingly, however, quality incentives for the low type would be even lower with OA, while the ranking depends on the royalties earned under closed access for the high type. A preliminary conclusion of this paper is that OA may be more beneficial for articles, whereas a closed access regime may be superior for textbooks. See Feess and Scheufen (2014) for a discussion.

  25. 25.

    Note that θ is now endogenous, i.e. author i can choose the level of θ. This differs from the model in Feess and Scheufen (2013), where θ is given by nature and distinguishes the good from the bad type researcher. Obviously, arguing that talent may be directly chosen sounds a bit awkward. However, at least indirectly this may be the case.

  26. 26.

    Obviously \(\varepsilon = 0\) for closed access, since \(\varepsilon = r^{C} - 1 = 1 - 1 = 0\).

  27. 27.

    Of course, one may argue that the productivity level may not be chosen endogenously by the author, but that it is rather exogenously given by nature. Nevertheless, one may also find arguments for the very opposite if we assume that the disposition of the group of researchers regarding θ may decisively be determined by means of labor market characteristics. Thus, it is the researcher’s decision whether to enter the academic labor market that chooses whether high or low qualified researchers are present. If we believe in this argument, both parameters r k and g may drive the decision making of our high (low) qualified author whether to become an academic or not. As a result, the level of θ may at least indirectly depend on the market characteristics and hence on r k and g.

  28. 28.

    Similarly, Feess and Scheufen (2013) find that effort levels are the same under CA.

  29. 29.

    We use the ranking published annually by the Academic Ranking of World Universities (ARWU). The ARWU is the first worldwide ranking of universities to be published. The rankings by ARWU have been conducted since 2003 and are updated on an annual basis. See http://www.shanghairanking.com/ (last accessed on September 1, 2014). For the data see ARWU (2012).

  30. 30.

    To see this just assume that only researchers from the US receive a waiver on the publication costs in an OA regime. Then we would face a situation where g US  = 0 < g others . Furthermore, assuming that g Germany  < g DC , suggests that the distortion may differ considerably between countries outside the US. Thus, taking account of particular country parameters seems necessary when shaping an appropriate redistribution mechanism for OA funding. The development of a clear framework for such a mechanism is outside the scope of this work. However, we will sketch some basic principles to be considered in Sect. 4.2.

  31. 31.

    Recall from Sect. 3.2 that only 28.24 % of all OA journals do actually charge author fees.

  32. 32.

    The fees for low or middle income countries are calculated based on the PLoS Global Participation Initiative. See their website at http://www.plos.org/about/viewpoints/global-participation-initiative/ (last accessed on September 1, 2014) for more information.

  33. 33.

    For a list of eligible group one countries see http://www.plos.org/group-one-countries/ (last accessed on September 1, 2014).

  34. 34.

    For a list of eligible group two countries see http://www.plos.org/group-two-countries/ (last accessed on September 1, 2014).

  35. 35.

    In this regard, Art.1 of the TRIPS Agreement specifies that “members shall be free to determine the appropriate method of implementing the provisions of this Agreement within their own legal system and practice” (TRIPS 1994, Art. 1.1).

  36. 36.

    A detailed comparison of both approaches is offered in Seltzer (1976) and Förster (2008).

  37. 37.

    Ricketson and Ginsburg (2006) note that Article 9(2) was primarily intended to govern the use of academic works for research purposes. In fact, the general clause under Article 9(2) was also intended to replace the express reference under Article 10(2) that was included in the draft prior to the Stockholm Act (Ricketson and Ginsburg 2006, p. 782; Reichman and Okediji 2012, p. 1379). Nowadays, the exception under Article 10(2) is limited to only teaching purposes.

  38. 38.

    The TRIPS agreement also incorporates similar statements for trademarks (Article 17), industrial designs (Article 26.2) and patents (Article 30). See section 3 in Kur (2009) for a comparison of the wording of the different provisions.

  39. 39.

    See the case WT/DS160, available at http://www.wto.org/French/news_f/news00_f/1234db.pdf (last accessed on September 1, 2014). See also Oliver (2002).

  40. 40.

    Fiscor (2002) highlights that the tradition of the Berne Convention actually prohibits an application of the fair-use approach. See also supra note 460 in Reichman and Okediji (2012) for a discussion.

  41. 41.

    Reichman and Okediji (2012) discuss several legislative steps to accommodate the needs of science. Their proposals cover recommendations such as a tailor-made exemption for scientific research, a deliberalisation of the DRM measurements as well as a reform of database protection laws. Despite the equal importance of these aspects for adapting the legal framework to the various needs of science, a broad discussion of all issues involved is beyond the scope of this thesis. Accordingly, we will focus on changes in the copyright law that more specifically serve the promotion of OA publishing. For further reading see besides Reichman and Okediji (2012) also Peukert (2013a,b). In Chap. 5 we will further elaborate on the pros and cons of different OA policies. For now we will more generally assess the openness of the international legal framework and the steps needed to further adapt legislation for the promotion of OA on a global scale.

  42. 42.

    In a recent decision, the WTO has highlighted the importance of the deference provision under Art. 1.1 of the TRIPS Agreement. See the panel report WT/DS362/R in WTO (2009).

  43. 43.

    A critical assessment of the prevailing legal uncertainty (Netherlands) and inflexibility (France) in the European system is provided by Senftleben (2010). He concludes that “the present regulation of copyright limitations in the EC offers neither legal certainty nor sufficient flexibility. The adaptation of EC copyright law to the digital environment has led to a legislative framework that employs the open-ended three-step test to erode the legal certainty following from precisely defined exceptions instead of using the test as a means for providing sufficient flexibility” (Senftleben 2010, p. 69).

  44. 44.

    See Geiger et al. (2008) for the declaration.

  45. 45.

    Note that the three-step test was similarly recodified also for trademark law (TRIPS Agreement, Art. 17). See Senftleben (2006).

  46. 46.

    See also Senftleben (2004). Besides, see Geiger et al. (2008) for an application of the three-step test under this premise.

  47. 47.

    We will discuss the pros and cons of various policies which aim at fostering the evolution of an OA mode in academic publishing in Chap. 5 In this context, specific references on how to incorporate these aspects into the international legal framework will be made, reverting to the lessons made here.

  48. 48.

    See http://www.eifl.net/access-knowledge-a2k (last accessed on September 1, 2014) for the A2K treaty.

  49. 49.

    Reichman and Okediji (2012) stress that steps towards an implementation of such a soft-law instrument by regional groups such as Latin American or African countries could help to accelerate a broader movement for a deliberalisation of the international copyright framework. Reichman and Okediji (2012) also highlight that Brazil has started to implement a provision on “transformative and incidental uses”. See Helfer et al. (2009) and Armstrong et al. (2010) on similar steps in South America and Africa, respectively.

  50. 50.

    See WIPO (1999, 2001) for the panel reports.

  51. 51.

    As seen before there are two forms of transfer of copyright: (1) Copyright Assignment and (2) Copyright Licensing. We concentrate on the latter, as an assignment of copyright would involve a transfer of (all) rights in an exclusive and definite manner. Thus, this approach does not comply with the “droit d’auteur” principle and does not account for attribution as the most relevant aspect for scientific researchers.

  52. 52.

    See the website of Springer at http://www.springer.com/open+access/open+choice?SGWID=0-40359-0-0-0 (last accessed on September 1, 2014).

  53. 53.

    For more information see the website of CC at www.creativecommons.org/licenses (last accessed on September 1, 2014).

  54. 54.

    See the CC website at http://wiki.creativecommons.org/International_Overview (last accessed on September 1, 2014) for a detailed overview on the ten-steps for porting the CC licenses.

  55. 55.

    See Rosenkranz (2011) on the problems of choice of law clauses in CC licenses.

  56. 56.

    Similarly see Woods (2009).

  57. 57.

    See the CC wiki at https://wiki.creativecommons.org/4.0 (last accessed on September 1, 2014) for a general overview on CC version 4.0.

  58. 58.

    For the legal code see the CC website at http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/3.0/legalcode (last accessed on September 1, 2014).

  59. 59.

    On the medieval lex mercatoria see e.g. Donahue (2004).

  60. 60.

    See the UNIDROIT website at http://www.unidroit.org/english/principles/contracts/main.htm (last accessed on September 1, 2014) for further information. See also Berger (1996) on the lex mercatoria doctrine and the UNIDROIT Principles of International Commercial Contracts.

  61. 61.

    The modern lex mercatoria approach was primarily influenced by Goldman (1964). A further development of this approach is Goldman (1979, 1986).

  62. 62.

    Note that the arguments similarly apply to other open innovation communities, such as the open source software (OSS) community. On OSS as the new lex mercatoria see Marrella and Yoo (2007). On the analogy between the OSS and the OA movement see Scheufen (2011) and Willinsky (2005).

  63. 63.

    See Sect. 3.1 for a review of the history of academic journal publishing.

  64. 64.

    We will further elaborate on the opportunities and requirements of academic associations in Chap. 5

  65. 65.

    Reichman and Okediji (2012) also point to options for imposing analogs to fair use and other codified limitations by contract.

  66. 66.

    Pure OA journals are journals that follow the definition by the BOAI (2002). Pure OA journals are listed by the DOAJ. See the website at http://www.doaj.org/ (last accessed on September 1, 2014). See also Sect. 3.2 for a review.

  67. 67.

    We will focus on the first. Obviously, mandates that require publication with gold OA are not very reasonable as long as OA journals still lack considerably in terms of reputation as compared to established CA journals. The impact factor advantage of CA journals would in fact induce just another distortion between authors with and without commitment to publish in OA journals only. Moreover, Suber (2012) stresses the low number of OA journals, constituting only 25 % of all peer-reviewed journals.

  68. 68.

    OA mandates typically use words like “must” or “shall” and hence require or seem to require OA. In contrast to a mandate, request or encouragement policies merely ask or recommend to their members to publish OA (Suber 2012, p. 78).

  69. 69.

    We will see later that a copyright exception by means of a so-called “inalienable right of secondary publication” may offer a similar tool to ensure rights-retention mandates.

  70. 70.

    See the website at http://www.sherpa.ac.uk/romeo/ (last accessed on September 1, 2014).

  71. 71.

    SHERPA/RoMEO classifies publishers in four categories according to their self-archiving policy: (1) “green”, i.e. authors can archive pre- and post-print; (2) “blue”, i.e. authors can archive post-print; (3) yellow, i.e. authors can archive pre-print; (4) white, i.e. archiving is not formally supported. See the website of SHERPA/RoMEO at http://www.sherpa.ac.uk/romeo/statistics.php?la=en&fIDnum=|&mode=simple (last accessed on September 1, 2014) for more information.

  72. 72.

    Bitton (2012) analyzes the implementation of the “Public Sector Information” (PSI) directive by the EU member states.

  73. 73.

    For the bill see RegE (2013).

  74. 74.

    See Bundesratsbeschluss (2013). Note that on 27 June 2013 the German Bundestag enacted an inalienable right of secondary publication for academic works, not considering the recommendations of the Bundesrat. See http://open-access.net/de/austausch/news/news/anzeige/bundestag_beschliesst_open/ (last accessed on September 1, 2014) for more information. See Pampel (2013) for a comment. We will further elaborate on the inalienable right of secondary publication in Chap. 5

  75. 75.

    See Senftleben (2010) on an EC fair use doctrine.

  76. 76.

    See Hackl and Pruckner (2001) for further reading.

  77. 77.

    This subsection serves as a draft for a spin-off and joint research project with Frank Mueller-Langer from the Max Planck Institute for Intellectual Property and Competition Law in Munich. The written words and the analysis are solely my work. However, in the labor-intensive process of data collection I enjoyed support by Frank Mueller-Langer and his student assistant Jonas Jungbauer. Parts of the empirical analysis evolved in joint discussions with Frank Mueller-Langer. Moreover, I am highly thankful for valuable comments from Patrick Andreoli-Versbach, Joel Waldfogel, Ruth Towse and Stan Liebowitz as well as the conference participants at the annual congress of the Society of Economic Research on Copyright Issues (SERCI) on 9 and 10 July 2013 in Washington DC, USA.

  78. 78.

    Obviously, we have seen that an OA publishing mode may also have a downside, especially when considering the publishing costs which have to be born by the author. Nevertheless, our analytical setting is not influenced by this potential threat to the participation constraint as the journals under the Research4Life regime do not raise any author fees. By contrast, most of the journals are actually “closed access”. The publishers instead commit to provide with an open or reduced fee access to their journals. As a result, these journals provide a perfect setting as they are freely accessible (benefit of OA) but without charging authors for publication (cost of OA).

  79. 79.

    See the website of HINARI at http://www.who.int/hinari/en/ (last accessed on September 1, 2014) for more information.

  80. 80.

    In fact, the participating publishers themselves may decide who is eligible or not. Several scholars in this respect argue that emerging markets like India and China may have been excluded from such OA initiatives as these countries account for a significant part in the subscriber portfolio of publishers.

  81. 81.

    Please note that the collected data allows for an analysis of all “Research4Life”-initiatives. Nevertheless, we focus our investigation on the OARE initiative as there is no research available so far and as a coverage of all four initiatives would be beyond the scope of this thesis.

  82. 82.

    See Ahmed (2007) on page 349 for an overview on OA initiatives in Africa.

  83. 83.

    See their website at http://www.research4life.org (last accessed on September 1, 2014) for more information.

  84. 84.

    Among them were Blackwell, Elsevier Science, the Harcourt Worldwide STM Group, Wolters Kluwer International Health & Science, Springer Verlag and John Wiley.

  85. 85.

    Eligible institutions are national universities, research institutes, professional schools (medicine, nursing, pharmacy, public health, dentistry), teaching hospitals, government offices and national medical libraries. Access is provided to staff as well as students of these institutions. See http://www.who.int/hinari/eligibility/en/index.html (last accessed on September 1, 2014).

  86. 86.

    The data is obtained from World Bank figures and can be accessed via the HINARI website at http://www.who.int/hinari/eligibility/en/index.html (last accessed on September 1, 2014).

  87. 87.

    The only country eligible for registration with HINARI that did not register is North Korea. The core of Band 1 countries is geographically located in Sub-Saharan Africa. Among the countries with the most registered institutions (more than 100) are primarily countries located in Latin America (Venezuela, Columbia and Peru) and Sub-Saharan Africa (Sudan, Ethiopia, Uganda, Kenya, Tanzania, Nigeria and Ghana).

  88. 88.

    Among them are Blackwell Publishing, CABI Publishing, Elsevier, Kluwer Academic Publishing, Lippincott, Williams & Wilkins, Nature Publishing Group, Oxford University Press, Springer Verlag and John Wiley & Sons.

  89. 89.

    See the AGORA website at http://www.aginternetwork.org/en/about_agora/ (last accessed on September 1, 2014). Eligible institutions are universities and colleges, research institutes, agricultural extension centres, government offices and libraries.

  90. 90.

    As is the case with HINARI, the core of Band 1 countries are geographically located in Sub-Saharan Africa.

  91. 91.

    See their website at http://www.oaresciences.org/ (last accessed on September 1, 2014) for more information.

  92. 92.

    Eligible institutions and non-governmental organizations are for example universities and colleges, professional training schools, research institutes, government ministries and other governmental offices, libraries, public media and local NGOs. See http://www.oaresciences.org/eligibility/en/index.html (last accessed on September 1, 2014).

  93. 93.

    See the website of “Research4Life” at http://www.research4life.org/about.html (last accessed on September 1, 2014) for more information.

  94. 94.

    See the website at http://www.itoca.org/ (last accessed on September 1, 2014).

  95. 95.

    See the website at http://www.itoca.org/node/81 (last accessed on September 1, 2014) for an overview on upcoming trainings.

  96. 96.

    In this regard, the WIPO cooperated especially with 12 major publishers in the field of development and innovation. The publishers are: American Association for the Advancement of Science, American Institute of Physics, Elsevier, Institute of Physics, John Wiley & Sons; Oxford University Press, National Academy of Sciences, Nature Publishing Group, Royal Society of Chemistry, Sage Publications, Springer Science+Business Media; Taylor & Francis. Other programme partners include the FAO, the International Association of Scientific, Technical & Medical Publishers, the United Nations Environment Programme and the WHO. See http://www.wipo.int/ardi/en/partners.html (last accessed on September 1, 2014) for more information.

  97. 97.

    See their website at http://www.wipo.int/ardi/en/ (last accessed on September 1, 2014) for more information.

  98. 98.

    See http://www.wipo.int/ardi/en/ (last accessed on September 1, 2014).

  99. 99.

    See Cetto (2001), Riddoch (2000), Goldenberg (1998), May (1997), and Gibbs (1995).

  100. 100.

    See Ahmed (2007), p. 348.

  101. 101.

    Note that this draft is work in progress and is the start for a joint research project with Frank Mueller-Langer. In the proceedings of the project the scope will be broadened to include all “Research4Life” programmes. Furthermore, also the role of pure OA journals shall be analyzed. We will further elaborate on the proceedings in our section on “limitations and proceedings”. The fact that this is the first research to include all programmes as well as OA journals in general, shows the innovativeness of the project as a whole.

  102. 102.

    Selection criterion: More than 75 institutions registered to Research4Life.

  103. 103.

    Selection criterion: More than 75 institutions registered to Research4Life.

  104. 104.

    Selection criterion: At the edge of eligibility for the Research4Life initiative based on GNI per capita.

  105. 105.

    For instance, inserting the query “cu=(“Cameroon”)” allows to search for publications from authors with affiliations to Cameroon universities.

  106. 106.

    Please note that Thomson Reuter’s allows to retrieve only 500 full records at a time. In cases where more than 500 records were listed, the data extraction was segmented into several steps. That is, if for example 1,261 records were listed, three country files were extracted, where file one contained records 1–500, file two the records 501–1000 and file three 1001–1261. Afterwards, all record files were merged to one single country file containing the full record of publications of a country for the time from January 2000 until June 2012.

  107. 107.

    Editing of the files included the creation of separate excel sheets for the evaluation of “the references” and “author affiliations”. Most importantly, the raw data as retrieved from the Web of Science database arranged the information on authors and references in single fields. Accordingly, all authors were listed in a single column and each separate cited reference with information on year, journal, author etc. was also listed in one column. For a further evaluation of both citations and affiliations via the “VLOOKUP” function in excel the information on the particular journal, for instance, had to be separated in columns.

  108. 108.

    Note that the ISSN number allows for a perfect matching of both journal lists, as the number is unique and hence guarantees the identification of a certain journal. However, for some journals the ISSN number was not provided. In such cases, a separate matching via the journal name allowed for an identification.

  109. 109.

    See the descriptive statistics for an evaluation.

  110. 110.

    In the proceedings of the research project the empirical analysis will be broadened to allow for a more elaborate assessment of this complex matter. In this regard, we will for example apply a regression discontinuity model. See our section on “limitations and proceedings” for a discussion.

  111. 111.

    Gap years included the years 2000, 2004, 2008 and 2012.

  112. 112.

    See Fig. 7.8 in the Appendix for a detailed picture, also on the number of registered institutions with OARE.

  113. 113.

    See also Fig. 7.9 in the Appendix.

  114. 114.

    In doing so, we created five dummy variables for each single publication to control for co-authors affiliated with institutions from (1) OECD countries, (2) EU countries, (3) EU 15 countries, (4) countries from North America and the (5) USA. That is, the dummy took the value 1 if at least one co-author was affiliated with such an institution, 0 if not. With other words: For publications that were referred to authors solely from developing countries, the value was 0. For all others, some form of cooperation with the developed world was found.

  115. 115.

    See Figs. 7.10 (for Sub-Saharan Africa) and 7.11 (for South America) in the Appendix for the numbers.

  116. 116.

    Please note the overlap between the control variables (1)–(5) as the EU memberstates and the USA are also members of the OECD. As the OECD reveals the broadest coverage, we will primarily report the findings for control variable (1) in this section. An overview on all numbers is given in Figs. 7.10 and 7.11 of the Appendix.

  117. 117.

    Exceptions are reported in Nigeria and Uganda (both Sub-Saharan Africa) and Venezuela (South America).

  118. 118.

    A comparison between both control variables (2) EU countries and (3) EU 15 shows that the majority of cooperations was driven by EU 15 memberstates.

  119. 119.

    Other indicators were the number of academic journals and the number of OARE registrations.

  120. 120.

    For a definition and overview of the different World Bank indicators see their website at http://data.worldbank.org/indicator (last accessed on September 1, 2014).

  121. 121.

    See Fig. 7.12 in the Appendix for an overview.

  122. 122.

    Please note that Cameroon stands out as one of the “richest” countries in the Sub-Saharan Africa sample. Among the poorest countries is Congo with a GDP per capita (in constant US dollars) of 86.75 (109.81) in 2000 (2011).

  123. 123.

    The summary statistics of all previously reported variables are also shown in Fig. 7.13 of the Appendix.

  124. 124.

    We use a robust regression based on iteratively reweighted least squares. Stata offers this robust option via the rreg command. A similar robust regression is the so-called cluster option. In executing our empirical analysis we also used this option by clustering our regression by means of both “country number” and “country group” (Sub-Saharan Africa, South America, control group), with results similar to the results presented here.

  125. 125.

    As discussed in the descriptive statistics, the controls include aspects like research cooperations with researchers from (1) OECD, (2) EU, (3) EU15, (4) North America or (5) USA as well as variables related to the level of economic development and ICT infrastructure.

  126. 126.

    Please note that the OARE initiative was launched in October 2006. To account for possible timegaps in the registration process we set the start of the initiative to January 2007 (i.e. for the years 2007 and later the dummy After i takes on the value 1, before the value is 0). In the Appendix we also present an empirical analysis where we account for a longer timegap. Such an assessment may be reasonable as the time between writing and publishing an academic paper is (very) long for some disciplines. However, we will see that this does not change much for the results as presented here.

  127. 127.

    Obviously, as EU memberstates as well as the USA are also members of the OECD, we have to assess their role separately from one another.

  128. 128.

    This is an aspect that will have to be investigated in more detail as the project advances. We will elaborate on the proceedings of our research project in the next section.

  129. 129.

    Interesting in this regard would be to examine the possible effect of HINARI on common health indicators, such as life expectancy.

  130. 130.

    Please note that the matching data—i.e. the list of OA journals—was generated by using the metadata harvesting tool from the DOAJ. See OAI (2008) for more information on the metadata harvesting tool.

  131. 131.

    See Fig. 3.9 Obviously, all three countries belong to the top ten list of most active countries in launching OA journals. See also the website of the DOAJ at http://www.doaj.org/doaj?func=byCountry&uiLanguage=en (last accessed on September 1, 2014) for an updated overview.

  132. 132.

    The “synthetic control” method is a very new empirical method to account for problems associated to the common trend assumption in the “DiD”-methodology. See Abadie et al. (2010).

  133. 133.

    For further information on the “degression discontinuity model” see Imbens and Lemieux (2007) and Hahn et al. (2001).

Bibliography

  • Abadie, A., Diamond, A., & Hainmueller, J. (2010). Synthetic control methods for comparative case studies: Estimating the effect of California’s tobacco control program. Journal of the American Statistical Association, 105(490), 493–505.

    Google Scholar 

  • Acs, Z. J., Audretsch, D. B., & Feldman, M. P. (1994). R&d spillovers and recipient firm size. Review of Economics and Statistics, 76(2), 336–340.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ahmed, A. (2007). Open access towards bridging the digital divide - Policies and strategies for developing countries. Information Technology for Development, 13(4), 337–361.

    Google Scholar 

  • Akerlof, G. A. (1970). The market for ‘lemons’: Quality uncertainty and the market mechanism. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 84(3), 488–500.

    Google Scholar 

  • Akerlof, G. A., Hahn, R., Litan, R. E., Arrow, K. J., Bresnahan, T. F., Buchanan, J. M., Coase, R. H., Cohen, L. R., Friedman, M., Green, J. R., Hazlett, T. W., Hemphill, C. S., Noll, R. G., Schmalensee, R., Shavell, S., Varian, H. R., & Zeckhauser, R. J. (2002). The copyright term extension act of 1998: An economic analysis. AEI-Brookings Joint Center for Regulatory Studies, Brief 02-1. http://www.aei-brookings.org/admin/authorpdfs/page.php?id=16.

  • Allison, P. D., & Stewart, J. A. (1974). Productivity differences among scientists: Evidence for accumulative advantage. American Sociological Review, 39(4), 596–606.

    Google Scholar 

  • Andreff, W., & Szymanski, S. (Eds.) (2006). Handbook of the economics of sport. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.

    Google Scholar 

  • Andreoli-Versbach, P., & Mueller-Langer, F. (2013). Open access to data: An ideal professed but not practiced. RatSWD Working Paper Series No. 215. http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=2224146.

  • Annan, K. (2004). Science for all nations. Science, 303, 925.

    Google Scholar 

  • Armstrong, C., DeBeer, J., Kawooya, D., Prabhala, A., & Schonwetter, T. (Eds.) (2010). Access to knowledge in Africa: The role of copyright. Claremont: UCT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Arrow, K. (1962). Economic welfare and the allocation of resources for invention. In R. Nelson (Ed.), The rate and direction of inventive activity (pp. 609–624). Cambridge: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • ARWU (2012). Academic ranking of world universities-2012. http://www.shanghairanking.com/ARWU2012.html.

  • Audretsch, D. B., & Feldman, M. P. (1996). R&d spillovers and the geography of innovation and production. American Economic Review, 86(3), 630–640.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bakos, Y., & Brynjofsson, E. (1999). Bundling information goods: Pricing, profits and efficiency. Management Science, 45(12), 1613–1630.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bakos, Y., & Brynjofsson, E. (2000). Bundling and competition on the internet. Marketing Science, 19(1), 63–82.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bargheer, M. (2006). Open access und universitätsverlage: Auswege aus der publication crisis. In Internetökonomie der Medienbranche. Göttingen: Universitätsverlag Göttingen.

    Google Scholar 

  • Benkler, Y. (2002). Coase’s penguin, or, linux and the “nature of the firm”. The Yale Law Journal, 112(3), 369–446.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bently, L. (2010). Introduction to part i: The history of copyright. In L. Bently, U. Suthersanen, & P. Torremans (Eds.), Global copyright. Three hundred years since the statute of anne, from 1709 to cyberspace. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bently, L., & Kretschmer, M. (2013). Primary sources on copyright (1450–1900). www.copyrighthistory.org.

  • Berger, K. P. (1996). Lex mercatoria doctrine and the unidroit principles of international commercial contracts. Law and Policy in International Business, 28, 943–990.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bergstrom, T. C. (2001). Free labor for costly journals. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 15(3), 183–198.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bergstrom, T. C., Courant, P., & McAffee, R. P. (2013). Big deal contract project. http://www.econ.ucsb.edu/~tedb/Journals/BundleContracts.html.

  • Bergstrom, T. C., & McAffee, R. P. (2013). Summary statistics. http://www.hss.caltech.edu/~mcafee/Journal/.

  • Bernius, S. (2010). The impact of open access on the management of scientific knowledge. Online Information Review, 34(4), 583–603.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bernius, S., & Hanauske, M. (2009). Open access to scientific literature-increasing citations as an incentive for authors to make their publications freely available. In Hawaii International Conference on System Science (HICSS-42).

    Google Scholar 

  • Bernius, S., Hanauske, M., Koenig, W., & Dugall, B. (2009). Open access models and their implications for the players on the scientific publishing market. Economic Analysis and Policy, 39(1), 103–115.

    Google Scholar 

  • Besen, S. M. (1986). Private copying, reproduction costs, and the supply of intellectual property. Information Economics and Policy, 2(1), 5–22.

    Google Scholar 

  • Besen, S. M., & Raskind, L. J. (1989). New technologies and intellectual property: Collectives that collect. Technical report, Rand Corporation, RAND Report No. R-3751-MF.

    Google Scholar 

  • Besen, S. M., & Raskind, L. J. (1991). An introduction to the law and economics of intellectual property. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 5(1), 3–27.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bitton, M. (2012). Implementing the public sector information directive. European Intellectual Property Review, 34(2), 75–86.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bjoerk, B.-C. (2004). Open access to scientific publications. An analysis of the barriers to change. Information Research, 9(2), 1–17.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bjoerk, B.-C. (2012). The hybrid model for open access publication of scholarly articles: A failed experiment? Journal of the American Society for Information Science and Technology, 63(8), 1496–1504.

    Google Scholar 

  • BOAI (2002). Budapest open access initiative. http://www.soros.org/openaccess/read.shtml.

  • Boldrine, M., & Levine, D. K. (2002). The case against intellectual property. American Economic Review, 92(2), 209–212.

    Google Scholar 

  • Boldrine, M., & Levine, D. K. (2005). Intellectual property and the efficient allocation of social surplus from creation. Review of Economic Research on Copyright Issues, 2(1), 45–67.

    Google Scholar 

  • Boldrine, M., & Levine, D. K. (2008). Against intellectual property (1st ed.) Cambridge: Cambridge University Press

    Google Scholar 

  • Börsenverein. (2011). Börsenverein des deutschen buchhandels. stellungnahme zum gesamtkonzept für die informationsinfrastruktur in deutschland (kii-papier), frankfurt.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bosch, X. (2009). A reflection on open-access, citation counts, and the future of scientific publishing. Archivum Immunologiae et Therapiae Experimentalis, 57(2), 91–93.

    Google Scholar 

  • Breyer, S. (1970). The uneasy case for copyright: A study of copyright in books, photocopies and computer programs. Harvard Law Review, 84, 281–351.

    Google Scholar 

  • Brody, T., Harnad, S., & Les, C. (2006). Earlier web usage statistics as predictors of later citation impact. Journal of the Association for Information Science and Technology, 57(8), 1060–1072.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bundesratsbeschluss. (2013). Mehr open access in der wissenschaft.

    Google Scholar 

  • Calabresi, G., & Melamed, D. A. (1972). Property rules, liability rules, and inalienability: One view of the cathedral. Harvard Law Review, 85(6), 1089–1128.

    Google Scholar 

  • Callon, M. (1994). Is science a public good? Fifth Mullins lecture. Science, Technology, and Human Values, 19(4), 395–424.

    Google Scholar 

  • Campanario, J. M. (1996). Using citation classics to study the incidence of serendipity in scientific discovery. Scientometrics, 20, 4–21.

    Google Scholar 

  • Campbell. (1994). Campbell, aka skywalker, et al. v. acuff-rose music, inc. (92-1292), 510 U.S. 569. http://www.law.cornell.edu/supct/html/92-1292.ZS.html.

  • Card, D., & Krueger, A. B. (1994). Minimum wages and employment: A case study of the fast-food industry in New Jersey and Pennsylvania. American Economic Review, 84(4), 772–793.

    Google Scholar 

  • Castells, M. (2000). The information age: The rise of the network society. Oxford: Blackwell.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cavaleri, P., Keren, M., Ramello, G. B., & Valli, V. (2009). Publishing an e-journal on a shoe string: Is it a sustainable project? Economic Analysis and Policy, 39(1), 89–101.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cetto, M. A. (2001). The contribution of electronic communication to science - Has it lived up to its promise? In Proceedings to the 2nd ICSU-UNESCO International Conference on Electronic Publishing in Science, 20–23 February, UNESCO House, Paris.

    Google Scholar 

  • Chang, C. C. (2003). Business models for open access journals publishing. Online Information Review, 30(6), 699–713.

    Google Scholar 

  • Choi, J. P. (2012). Bundling information goods. In M. Peitz & J. Waldfogel (Eds.), The Oxford handbook of the digital economy (pp. 273–305). Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Christian, G. E. (2008). Open access initiative and the developing world. African Journal of Library Archives and Information Science, 18(2).

    Google Scholar 

  • Coase, R. (1960). The problem of social cost. Journal of Law and Economics, 3(1), 1–44.

    Google Scholar 

  • Coccia, M. (2006). Economic and social studies of scientific research: Nature and origins. Working Paper CERIS-CNR, 8(7).

    Google Scholar 

  • Cofer, C. N., & Apply, M. H. (1967). Motivation: Theory and research. New York: Wiley.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cohen, W. M., & Levinthal, D. A. (1989). Innovation and learning: The two faces of r&d. Economic Journal, 99(397), 569–596.

    Google Scholar 

  • Congleton, R. D., Hillman, A. L., & Konrad, K. (2008). 40 years of research on rent seeking 1. New York: Springer.

    Google Scholar 

  • Conney-McQuat, S., Busch, S., & Kahn, D. (2010). Open access publishing: A viable solution for society publishers. Learned Publishing, 23(2), 101–105.

    Google Scholar 

  • Coolidge, H. J., & Lord, R. H. (1932). Archibald cary coolidge: Life and letters. New York: Boston

    Google Scholar 

  • Cornish, W. (2010). The statute of anne 1709-10: Its historical setting. In L. Bently, U. Suthersanen, & P. Torremans (Eds.), Global copyright. Three hundred years since the statute of anne, from 1709 to cyberspace. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.

    Google Scholar 

  • Corrigan, R., & Rogers, M. (2005). The economics of copyright. World Economics, 6(3), 153–174.

    Google Scholar 

  • Craig, I., Plume, A. M., McVeigh, M. E., Pringle, J., & Amin, M. (2007). Do open access articles have greater citation impact? A critical review of the literature. Publishing research consortium. Journal of Informetrics, 1(3), 239–248.

    Google Scholar 

  • Crane, D. (1965). Scientists at major and minor universities: A study of productivity and recognition. American Sociological Review, 30(5), 699–714.

    Google Scholar 

  • Csikszentmihalyi, H. (1974). Beyond boredom and anxiety: The experience of play in work and games. San Francisco: Jossey Bass Inc.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dahlberg, B. (2011). Orphan works problem: Preserving access to the cultural history of disadvantaged groups. Southern California Review of Law and Social Justice 20, 275.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dalrymple, D. (2003). Scientific knowledge as a global public good: Contributions to innovation and the economy. In J. M. Esanu, & P. F. Uhlir (Eds.), The Role of Scientific and Technical Data and Information in the Public Domain: Proceedings of a Symposium (pp. 35–49). Washington: National Academic Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dasgupta, P., & David, P. A. (1987). Information disclosure and the economics of science and technology. In G. R. Feiwel (Ed.), Arrow and the ascent of modern economic theory. New York: Macmillan Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dasgupta, P., & David, P. A. (1994). Towards a new economics of science. Research Policy, 23(4), 487–521.

    Google Scholar 

  • David, P. A. (1993). Intellectual property institutions and the panda’s thumb: Patents, copyrights and trade secrets in economic theory and history. In NRC (pp. 19–61).

    Google Scholar 

  • Davis, P. M. (2009). Author-choice open access publishing in the biological and medical literature. Journal of the American Society for Information Science and Technology, 60(1), 3–8.

    Google Scholar 

  • Davis, P. M. (2011). Open access, readership, citations: A randomized controlled trial of scientific journal publishing. The FASEB Journal, 25, 1–6.

    Google Scholar 

  • Davis, P., Lewenstein, B., Simon, D., Booth, J., & Connolly, M. (2008). Open access publishing, article downloads and citations. British Medical Journal, 337, a568.

    Google Scholar 

  • Davis, P. M., Lewenstein, B. V., Simon, D. H., Booth, J. G., Connolly, M. J. L. (2008). Open access publishing, article downloads, and citations: Randomized control trial. British Medical Journal, 337, a568. http://www.bmj.com/cgi/content/full/337/jul31_1/a568.

  • Deci, E. L., Koester, R., & Ryan, R. M. (1999). A meta-analytic review of experiments examining the effects of extrinsic rewards on intrinsic motivation. Psychological Bulletin, 125(6), 627–668.

    Google Scholar 

  • Deci, E. L., & Ryan, R. M. (1985). Intrinsic motivation and self-determination in human behavior. New York: Plenum Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Deene, J. (2010). The influence of the statute of anne on Belgian copyright law. In L. Bently, U. Suthersanen, & Torremans, P. (Eds.), Global copyright. Three hundred years since the statute of anne, from 1709 to cyberspace. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.

    Google Scholar 

  • Demsetz, H. (1970). The private production of public goods. Journal of Law and Economics, 13, 293–306.

    Google Scholar 

  • Demsetz, H. (2009). Creativity and the economics of the copyright controversy. Review of Economic Research on Copyright Issues, 6(2), 5–12.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dewatripont, M., Ginsburgh, V., Legros, P., Walckiers, A., Devroey, J. P., Dujardin, M., et al. (2006). Study on the economic and technical evolution of the scientific publication markets in Europe. Brussels: European Commission.

    Google Scholar 

  • Diamond, A. M. (1986). The life-cycle research productivity of mathematicians and scientists. Journal of Gerontology, 41(4), 520–525.

    Google Scholar 

  • Diamond, A. M. (2000). The complementarity of scientometrics and economics. In B. Cronin & H. B. Adkins (Eds.), The web of knowledge: A festschrift in honor of eugene garfield (pp. 321–336). New Jersey: Information Today.

    Google Scholar 

  • Diamond, A. M. (2004). Zvi grichiles’s contributions to the economics of technology and growth. Economics of Innovation and New Technology, 13(4), 365–397.

    Google Scholar 

  • Diamond, A. M. (2005). Measurement, incentives and constraints in stigler’s economics of science. The European Journal of the History of Economic Thought, 12(4), 635–661.

    Google Scholar 

  • DMCA (1998). The digital millenium copyright act of 1998. U.S. copyright office summary. http://www.copyright.gov/legislation/dmca.pdf.

  • Donahue, C. (2004). Medieval and early modern lex mercatoria: An attempt at the probatio diabolica. Chicago Journal of International Law 5, 21

    Google Scholar 

  • ECReport. (2006). Study on the economic and technical evolution of the scientific publication markets in Europe. EC Report. http://ec.europa.eu/research/science-society/pdf/scientific-publication-study_en.pdf.

  • Edlin, A. S., & Rubinfeld, D. L. (2004). Exclusion or efficient pricing? The “big deal” bundling of academic journals. Antitrust Law Journal, 72, 128–159.

    Google Scholar 

  • Edlin, A. S., & Rubinfeld, D. L. (2005). Competition policy for journals: The bundling of academic journals. American Economic Review, 95(2), 441–445.

    Google Scholar 

  • Eger, T. (2013). Einige bemerkungen zur aktuellen diskussion um das urheberrecht aus ökonomischer sicht. In H. Curti & T. Effertz (Eds.), Die ökonmische Analyse. Entwicklung und Perspektive einer interdisziplinären Wissenschaft (pp. 121–140). New York: Peter Land Academic Publishing.

    Google Scholar 

  • Eger, T., & Scheufen, M. (2012a). Das urheberrecht im zeitenwandel: Von gutenberg zum cyberspace. In C. Müller, F. Trosky, & M. Weber (Eds.), Ökonomik als Allgemeine Theorie Menschlichen Verhaltens: Grundlagen und Anwendungen, Schriften zu Ordnungsfragen der Witzschaft (Vol. 94, pp. 151–180). Stuttgart: Lucius & Lucius.

    Google Scholar 

  • Eger, T., & Scheufen, M. (2012b). The past and the future of copyright law: Technological change and beyond. In J. De Mot (Ed.), Liber Amicorum Boudewijn Bouckaert, forthcoming (pp. 37–65). Bruges: de Keuren.

    Google Scholar 

  • Eger, T., Scheufen, M., & Meierrieks, D. (2013). The determinants of open access publishing: Survey evidence from Germany. SSRN Working Paper.

    Google Scholar 

  • Eger, T., Scheufen, M., & Meierrieks, D. (2014). The determinants of open access publishing: Survey evidence from countries in the Mediterranean open access network (medoanet). SSRN Working Paper.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ehrenberg, R. G. (1992). The flow of new doctorates’. Journal of Economic Literature, 30(2), 830–875.

    Google Scholar 

  • Elkin-Koren, N. (2006). Creative commons: A sceptical view of a worthy pursuit. In B. P. Hugenholtz & L. Guibault (Eds.), The future of the public domain (pp. 1–21). Netherlands: Kluwer Law International.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ethiraj, S. K., & Levinthal, D. A. (2009). Hoping for a to z while rewarding only a: Complex organizations and multiple goals. Organization Science, 20, 4–21.

    Google Scholar 

  • Evans, J., & Reimer, J. (2009a). Open access and global participation in science. Science, 323, 1025.

    Google Scholar 

  • Evans, J., & Reimer, J. (2009b). Open access and global participation in science, supporting online material. Science, 323, 72–75.

    Google Scholar 

  • Eysenbach, G. (2006). Citation advantage of open access articles. PLoS Biology, 4(5), 692–698.

    Google Scholar 

  • Feather, J. (1980). The book trade in politics: The making of the copyright act of 1710. Publishing History, 8, 19–44.

    Google Scholar 

  • Feess, E., & Scheufen, M. (2013). Academic copyright in the publishing game: A contest perspective. SSRN Working Paper.

    Google Scholar 

  • Feess, E., & Scheufen, M. (2014). Copyright versus open access for academic works: A non-strategic model on quality provision. Mimeo.

    Google Scholar 

  • Finch, J. (2012). Accessibility, sustainability, excellence: How to expand access to research publications. Report of the working group on expanding access to published research findings-the Finch group. http://www.researchinfonet.org/wp-content/uploads/2012/06/Finch-Group-report-FINAL-VERSION.pdf.

  • Fiscor, M. (2002). The Law of Copyright and the Internet-the 1996 WIPO treaties, their interpretation and implementation. Oxford: Oxford University Press

    Google Scholar 

  • Förster, A. (2008). Fair Use: Ein Systemvergleich der Schrankengeneralklausel des US-amerikanischen Copyright Act mit dem Schrankenkatalog des deutschen Urheberrechtsgesetzes. Tuebingen: Mohr Siebeck.

    Google Scholar 

  • Freedman, P. (1960). The principles of scientific research (2nd ed.). New York: Pergamon Press (1st ed. 1949)

    Google Scholar 

  • Frey, B.S. (1992). Tertium datur: Pricing, regulating and intrinsic motivation. Kyklos, 45, 161–185.

    Google Scholar 

  • Frey, B. S., & Neckermann, S. (2008). Academics appreciate awards. A new aspect of incentives in research. Institute for Empirical Research in Economics, University of Zurich, Working Paper No. 400.

    Google Scholar 

  • Frey, B. S., & Neckermann, S. (2009). Awards: A view from economics. In G. Brennan & G. Eusepi (Eds.), The economics of ethics and the ethics of economics. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.

    Google Scholar 

  • Frost, G. E. (1967). The 1967 patent law debate-first-to-invent vs. first-to-file. Duke Law Journal, 1967(5), 923–942.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fudenberg, D., & Villas-Boas, J. M. (2012). Price discrimination in the digital economy. In M. Peitz & J. Waldfogel (Eds.), The Oxford handbook of the digital economy (pp. 254–272). Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gadd, E., Oppenheim, C., & Probets, S. (2003). Romeo studies 4: An analysis of journal publishers’ copyright agreements. Learned Publishing, 16(4), 293–308.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gallini, N., & Scotchmer, S. (2002). Intellectual property: When is it the best incentive system. Innovation Policy and the Economy, 2, 51–78.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gans, J. S., & Shepherd, G. B. (1994). How are the mighty fallen: Rejected classic articles by leading economists. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 8, 165–179.

    Google Scholar 

  • Garfield, E. (1955). Citation indexes to science: A new dimension in documentation through association of ideas. Science, 122(3159), 108–111.

    Google Scholar 

  • Garfield, E. (1996). What is the premordial reference for the phrase ‘publish or perish’? The Scientist, 10(12), 11.

    Google Scholar 

  • Garfield, E. (2003). The meaning of the impact factor. International Journal of Clinical and Health Psychology, 3(2), 363–369.

    Google Scholar 

  • Garfield, E. (2005). The agony and the ecstasy—The history and meaning of the journal impact factor. In International Congress on Peer Review and Biomedical Publication, Chicago, September 16, 2005

    Google Scholar 

  • Gargouri, Y., Hajjem, C., Larivière, V., Gingras, Y., Carr, L., Brody, T., et al. (2010). Self-selected or mandated, open access increases citation impact for higher quality research. PLoS One, 5(10), e13636.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gassaway, L. (2002). Copyright and moral rights. Information Outlook, 6(12), 40–41.

    Google Scholar 

  • Geiger, C. (2007). The role of the three-step-test in the adaptation of copyright law to the information society. UNESCO E-Copyright Bulletin, 2007, 1–21.

    Google Scholar 

  • Geiger, C. (2010a). The influence (past and present) of the statute of anne in France. In L. Bently, U. Suthersanen, & P. Torremans (Eds.), Global copyright. Three hundred years since the statute of anne, from 1709 to cyberspace. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.

    Google Scholar 

  • Geiger, C. (2010b). Promoting creativity through copyright limitations: Reflections on the concept of exclusivity in copyright law. Vanderbilt Journal of Entertainment and Technology Law, 12(3), 515–548.

    Google Scholar 

  • Geiger, C., Griffiths, J., & Hilty, R. (2008). Declaration on a balanced interpretation of the “three-step test” in copyright law. International Review of Intellectual Property and Competition Law, 39, 707

    Google Scholar 

  • Geller, P. E. (2000). Copyright history and the future: What’s culture got to do with it? Journal of the Copyright Society of the USA, 47, 209–264.

    Google Scholar 

  • Geller, P. E. (2010). A German approach to fair use: Test cases for trips criteria for copyright limitations. Journal of the Copyright Society of the USA, 57, 555–601.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gibbons, M., & Johnston, R. (1974). The role of science in technological innovation. Research Policy, 3(3), 221–242.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gibbs, W. W. (1995). Lost science in the third world. Science in America, 273, 92–99.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gienas, K. (2008). Scientific works: Another dimension of copyright perspective. Journal of Intellectual Property Law and Practice, 3(12), Article 1, 801–803.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ginsburg, J. C. (1990). A tale of two copyrights: Literary property in revolutionary France and America. Tulane Law Review, 64(5), 991–1031.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ginsburg, J. C. (2001). Toward supranational copyright law? The WTO panel decision and the “three-step” test for copyright exceptions. Revue Internationale du Droit d’Auteur (RIDA), 187(1), 1–16.

    Google Scholar 

  • Godin, B. (2001). Defining r&d: Is research always systematic. Project on the History and Sociology of S&T Statistics. Paper No. 7. http://www.csiic.ca/PDF/Godin_7.pdf.

  • Goldenberg, J. (1998). What is the role of science in dcs? Science, 279, 1140–1141.

    Google Scholar 

  • Goldman, B. (1964). Frontières du droit et “lex mercatoria”. Archives de Philosophie du Droit, 9, 177–192.

    Google Scholar 

  • Goldman, B. (1979). La lex mercatoria dans le contrats et l’arbitrage internationaux: Réalité et perspectives. Journal du Droit International, 106, 475–505.

    Google Scholar 

  • Goldman, B. (1986). The applicable law: General principals of law - The lex mercatoria. In J. D. M. Lew (Ed.), Contemporary problems in international arbitration. Boston: Martinus Nijhoff Publishers.

    Google Scholar 

  • Goldstein, P. (2001). International copyright: Principles, law and practice. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Goodall, A. H. (2006). Should top universities be led by top researchers and are they? Journal of Documentation, 62, 388–411.

    Google Scholar 

  • Goodall, A. H. (2009). Highly cited leaders and the performance of research universities. Research Policy, 38, 1079–1092.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gordon, W. J. (1982). Fair use as market failure: A structural and economic analysis of the betamax case and its predecessors. Columbia Law Review, 82(8), 1600–1657.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gordon, W. J. (1989). An inquiry into the merits of copyright: The challenges of consistency, consent and encouragement theory. Stanford Law Review, 41, 1343–1469.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gordon, W. J. (1992a). Asymmetric market failure and prisoner’s dilemma in intellectual property. University of Dayton Law Review, 17, 853–869.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gordon, W. J. (1992b). Of harms and benefits: Torts, restitution and intellectual property. Journal of Legal Studies, 21, 449–482.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gordon, W. J. (1998). Intellectual property as price discrimination: Implications for contract. Chicago-Kent Law Review, 73, 1367.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gordon, W. J., & Bone, R. G. (1999). Copyright. Encyclopedia of law and economics, No. 1610. http://encyclo.findlaw.com/1610book.pdf.

  • Granstrand, O. (1999). The Economics and management of intellectual property. Towards intellectual capitalism. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.

    Google Scholar 

  • Grendler, P. F. (1975). The roman inquisition and the Venetian press. Journal of Modern History, 47(1), 48–65.

    Google Scholar 

  • Griliches, Z. (1992). The search for r&d spillovers. Scandinavian Journal of Economics, 94, 29–47.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hackl, F., & Pruckner, G. J. (2001). The economics of the kyoto protocol. In P. J. Welfens (Ed.), Internationalization of the economy and environmental policy options. New York: Springer.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hadfield, G. K. (1992). The economics of copyright: A historical perspective. Copyright Law Symposium, 38(1), 1–46.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hagstrom, W. O. (1965). The scientific community. New York: Basic Books.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hahn, J., Todd, P., & VanderKlouw, W. (2001). Identification and estimation of treatment effects with a regression discontinuity desgn. Econometrica, 69(1), 201–209.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hajjem, C., Harnad, S., & Gingras, Y. (2005). Ten-year cross-disciplinary comparison of the growth of open access and how it increases research citation impact. IEEE Data Engineering Bulletin, 18(4), 39–47.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hanauske, M., Bernius, S., & Dugall, B. (2009). Quantum game theory and open access publishing. Physica A, 382, 650–664.

    Google Scholar 

  • Handke, C. (2010). The economics of copyright and digitisation: A report on the literature and need for further research. Report for the Strategic Advisory Board for Intellectual Property Policy (SABIP), London, UK. http://www.ipo.gov.uk/ipresearch-economics-20105.pdf.

  • Handke, C., & Towse, R. (2007). The economics of copyright collective societies. International Review of Intellectual Property and Competition Law, 38(8), 937–957.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hansen, G. (2005). Zugang zu wissenschaftlicher information - Alternative urheberrechtliche ansätze. Gewerblicher Rechtsschutz und Urheberrecht. Internationaler Teil (GRUR International), 54(5), 378–387.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hardy, T. (1999). Copyright and “new-use” technologies. Faculty Publications. Paper 187. http://scholarship.law.wm.edu/facpubs/187.

  • Hargreaves, I. (2011). Digital opportunity: A review of intellectual property and growth. http://www.ipo.gov.uk/ipreview-finalreport.pdf.

  • Harnad, S., Brody, T., Vallières, F., Carr, L., Hitchcock, S., Gingras, Y., et al. (2004). The access/impact problem and the green and gold roads to open access. Serials Review, 30(4), 310–314.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hayek, F. A. v. (1973). Die anmaßung von wissen. Ordo, 26, 12–21.

    Google Scholar 

  • Heide, T. (2004). Making law and economics work for copyright. In R. M. Hilty & A. Peukert (Eds.), Interessenausgleich im urheberrecht. Baden-Baden: Nomos

    Google Scholar 

  • Helberger, N. (2005). A2k: Access to knowledge-make it happen. INDICARE Monitor, 2(3).

    Google Scholar 

  • Helfer, L. R., Alter, K. J., & Guerzovich, M. F. (2009). Islands of effective internationa adjudication: Constructing an intellectual property rule of law in the andean community. The American Journal of International Law, 103(1), 1–46.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hilty, R. (2006a). Das urheberrecht und der wissenschaftler. Gewerblicher Rechtsschutz und Urheberrecht. Internationaler Teil (GRUR International), 55(3), 179–190.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hilty, R. (2006b). Five lessons about copyright in the information society: Reaction of the scientific community to over-protection and what policy makers should learn. Journal of the Copyright Society of the USA, 53(1), 103–138.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hilty, R. (2007). Copyright law and scientific research. In P. Torremans (Ed.), Copyright law. A handbook of contemporary research. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hilty, R., Krujatz, S., Bajon, B., Früh, A., Kur, A., Drexl, J., et al. (2008). European commission - Green paper: Copyright in the knowledge economy - Comments by the max planck institute for intellectual property, com-petition and tax law. Max Planck Institute for Intellectual Property, Competition & Tax Law Research Paper Series No. 08-05, 08, 1–20.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hilty, R., & Peukert, A. (2004). Interessenausgleich im urheberrecht. Baden-Baden: Nomos.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hirschfelder, M. (2008). Anforderungen an eine rechtliche Verankerung des Open Access Prinzips. Bologna: Verlag Alma Mater.

    Google Scholar 

  • Holmström, B., & Migrom, P. (1991). Multitask principal-agent analyses: Incentive contracts, asset ownership, and job design. Journal of Law, Economics & Organizations, 7(special issue), 24–52.

    Google Scholar 

  • Houghton, J., & Oppenheim, C. (2010). The economic implications of alternative publishing models. Prometheus, 28(1), 41–54.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hugenholtz, B. (2001). Copyright and freedom of expression in Europe. In R. C. Dreyfuss, H. First, & D. L. Zimmermann (Eds.), Expanding the boundaries of intellectual property. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hugenholtz, B. P., & Okediji, R. L. (2008). Conceiving an international instrument on limitations and exceptions to copyright. Final report. http://www.opensocietyfoundations.org/sites/default/files/copyright_20080506.pdf.

  • Hui, K.-L., & Png, I. P. L. (2002). On the supply of creative work: Evidence from the movies. American Economic Review, 92(2), 217–220.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hull, D. L. (1988). Science as a process. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hurt, R. M., & Schuchman, R. M. (1966). The economic rationale of copyright. American Economic Review (Papers and Proceedings), 56(1/2), 421–432.

    Google Scholar 

  • Imbens, G. W., & Lemieux, T. (2007). Regression discontinuity designs: A guide to practice. NBER Working Paper Series, Working Paper No. 13039.

    Google Scholar 

  • Imbens, G. W., & Wooldridge, J. M. (2007). Difference-in-differences estimation, lecture notes 10, summer 2007. http://www.nber.org/WNE/lect_10_diffindiffs.pdf.

  • Imbens, G. W., & Wooldridge, J. M. (2009). Recent developments in the econometrics of program evaluation. Journal of Economic Literature, 47(1), 5–86.

    Google Scholar 

  • Jaffe, A. B. (1989). Real effects of academic research. American Economic Review, 79(5), 957–970.

    Google Scholar 

  • JCR. (2011). Journal citation reports. http://thomsonreuters.com.

  • Jeon, D.-S., & Rochet, J.-C. (2010). The pricing of academic journals: A two-sided market perspective. American Economic Journal: Microeconomics, 2, 222–255.

    Google Scholar 

  • Jochum, U. (2009). “Open Access”. Zur Kritik einiger populärer Annahmen. Göttingen: Wallstein.

    Google Scholar 

  • Johnson, J. P., & Waldman, M. (2005). The limits of indirect appropriability in markets for copiable goods. Review of Economic Research on Copyright Issues, 2(1), 19–37.

    Google Scholar 

  • Johnson, W. R. (1985). The economics of copying. Journal of Political Economy, 93, 158–174.

    Google Scholar 

  • Johnson, W. R. (2005). Creative pricing in markets for intellectual property. Review of Economic Research on Copyright Issues, 2(1), 39–44.

    Google Scholar 

  • Joyce, C., Leaffer, M., Jaszi, P. A., & Ochoa, T. (2010). Copyright law (8th ed.). Gurgaon: LexisNexis.

    Google Scholar 

  • Joyce, P. (1990). Price discrimination in top scientific journals. Applied Economics, 22(8), 1127–1135.

    Google Scholar 

  • Joyce, P., & Merz, T. E. (1985). Price discrimination in academic journals. The Library Quarterly, 55(3), 273–283.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kapp, F., & Goldfriedrich, J. (1908). Geschichte des deutschen Buchhandels: Im Auftrage des Börsenvereins der deutschen Buchhändler. Leipzig: Bibliolife.

    Google Scholar 

  • King, D. W. (2007). The cost of journal publishing: A literature review and commentary. Learned Publishing, 20(2), 85–106.

    Google Scholar 

  • Koboldt, C. (1995). Intellectual property and optimal copyright protection. Journal of Cultural Economics, 19, 131–155.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kodrzycki, Y. K., & Yu, P. D. (2006). New approaches to ranking economics journals. B. E. Journal of Economics Analysis and Policy, 5(1), Article 24, 1–47.

    Google Scholar 

  • Konrad, K. (2009). Strategy and dynamics in contest. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ku, R. S. R. (2002). The creative destruction of copyright: Napster and the new economics of digital technology. University of Chicago Law Review, 69(1), 263–324.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kuhlen, R. (2008). Erfolgreiches Scheitern - eine Götterdämmerung des Urheberrechts? Schriften zur Informationsgesellschaft (Vol. 48). Boizenburg: Verlag Werner Hülsbusch.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kur, A. (2009). Of oceans, islands, and inland water - How much room for exceptions and limitations under the three-step-test? Richmond Journal of Global Law and Business, 8, 287

    Google Scholar 

  • Laasko, M., Welling, P., Bukvova, H., Nyman, L., Björk, B.-C., & Hedlund, T. (2011). The development of open access journal publishing from 1993 to 2009. PLoS ONE, 6(6), 1–10.

    Google Scholar 

  • Laband, D. N., & Tollison, R. D. (2003). Dry holes in economic research. Kyklos, 56, 161–174.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lakhani, K. R., & Wolf, R. C. (2005). Why hackers do what they do: Understanding motivation and effort in free/open source software projects. In J. Feller, B. Fitzgerald, S. A. Hissam, & K. R. Lakhani (Eds.), Perspectives on free and open source software (pp. 3–23). Cambridge: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Landes, W. M., & Posner, R. A. (1989). An economic analysis of copyright law. Journal of Legal Studies, 18(2), 325–363.

    Google Scholar 

  • Landes, W. M., & Posner, R. A. (2002). Indefinitely renewable copyright. Working Paper No. 154. University of Chicago John M. Olin Law and Economics.

    Google Scholar 

  • Landes, W. M., & Posner, R. A. (2003). The Economic structure of intellectual property law. Massachusetts: Belknap Press of Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lawrence, S. (2001). Free online availability substantially increases a paper’s impact. Nature, 411, 521–522.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lawrence, S., & Giles, C. L. (2000). Accessibility of information on the web. Intelligence, 11(1), 32–39.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lemley, M. A., & Weiser, P. (2007). Should property or liability rules govern information. Texas Law Review, 85(4), 783–841.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lerner, J., & Tirole, J. (2002). Some simple economics of open source. Journal of Industrial Economics, 50(2), 197–234.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lerner, J., & Tirole, J. (2005). Economic perspectives on open source. In J. Feller, B. Fitzgerald, S. A. Hissam, & K. R. Lakhani (Eds.), Perspectives on free and open source software (pp. 46–78). Cambridge: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Leslie, L. R., & Oaxaca, R. L. (1993). Scientist and engineer supply and demand. In J. C. Smart (Ed.), Higher education: Handbook of theory and research (Vol. IX, pp. 154–211). New York: Agathon Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lessig, L. (1999). Code and other laws of cyberspace. New York: Basic Books.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lessig, L. (2001). The future of ideas: The fate of the commons in a connected world. New York: Random House.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lessig, L. (2004). Free culture: How big media uses technology and the law to lock down culture and control creativity. New York: Penguin Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lévêque, F., & Méniére, Y. (2004). The economics of patents and copyrights. http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=642622.

  • Levin, S. G., & Stephan, P. E. (1991). Research productivity over the life cycle: Evidence for academic scientists’. American Economic Review, 81(1), 114–132.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lichtenberg, F. R. (1988). The private r&d investment response to federal design and technical competitors’. American Economic Review, 78(3), 550–559.

    Google Scholar 

  • Liebowitz, S. J. (1981). The impact of reprography on the copyright system. Ottawa: Consumer and Corporate Affairs Canada.

    Google Scholar 

  • Liebowitz, S. J. (1983). Price discrimination by journal publishers: Its impact on copyright law and photocopying. European Intellectual Property Review, 6, 184–189.

    Google Scholar 

  • Liebowitz, S. J. (1985). Copying and indirect appropriability: Photocopying of journals. Journal of Political Economy, 93(5), 945–957.

    Google Scholar 

  • Liebowitz, S. J. (1986). Copyright law, photocopying, and price discrimination. Research in Law and Economics, 8, 181–200.

    Google Scholar 

  • Liebowitz, S. J. (2005). Economists’ topsy-turvy view of piracy. Review of Economic Research on Copyright Issues, 2(1), 5–17.

    Google Scholar 

  • Liebowitz, S. J. (2014). Willfull blindness: The inefficient reward structure in academic research. Economic Inquiry, 52(4), 1267–1283.

    Google Scholar 

  • Liebowitz, S. J., & Margolis, S. E. (2005). Seventeen famous economists weigh in on copyright: The role of theory, empirics, and network effects. Harvard Journal of Law and Technology, 18(2), 435–457.

    Google Scholar 

  • Liebowitz, S. J., & Palmer, J. C. (1984). Assessing the relative impacts of economics journals. Journal of Economic Literature, 22(1), 77–88.

    Google Scholar 

  • Liebowitz, S. J., & Watt, R. (2006). How to best ensure remuneration for creators in the market for music? Copyright and its alternatives. Journal of Economic Surveys, 20(4), 513–545.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lindenberg, S. (2001). Intrinsic motivation in a new light. Kyklos, 54(2), 317–342.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lindsey, D. (1989). Using citation counts as a measure of quality in science. measuring what’s measurable rather than what’s valid. Scientometrics, 15(3–4), 189–203.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lipszyc, D. (2010). Historical appearances and disappearances of formalities: From berne to national laws. In L. Bently, U. Suthersanen, & P. Torremans (Eds.), Global copyright. Three hundred years since the statute of anne, from 1709 to cyberspace. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.

    Google Scholar 

  • Litman, J. (2006). The economics of open access law publishing. Lewis & Clark Law Review, 10(4), 101–117.

    Google Scholar 

  • Locke, J. (1689). In T. Hollis (Ed.), The two treatises of civil government. New York: The Online Library of Liberty.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lunney, G. S. (2008). Copyright’s price discrimination panacea. Harvard Journal of Law & Technology, 21(2), 387–456.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mann, F., von Walter, B., Hess, T., & Wigand, R. T. (2008). Open access publishing in science: Why it is highly appreciated but rarely used. Communications of the ACM, 52, 1–7.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mansfield, E. (1995). Academic research underlying industrial innovations: Sources, characteristics, and financing. Review of Economics and Statistics, 77(1), 55–65.

    Google Scholar 

  • Maracke, C. (2010). Creative commons international. the international license porting project - origins, experiences, and challenges. Journal of Intellectual Property, Information Technology and E-Commerce Law (JIPITEC), 4, 4–18.

    Google Scholar 

  • Marrella, F., & Yoo, C. S. (2007). Is open source software the new lex mercatoria? Virginia Journal of International Law, 47(4), 807–837.

    Google Scholar 

  • May, C. (2009). The pre-history and establishment of the wipo. The WIPO Journal: Analysis and Debate of Intellectual Property Issues, 1(1), 16–26.

    Google Scholar 

  • May, R. M. (1997). The scientific wealth of nations. Science, 275, 793–796.

    Google Scholar 

  • McCabe, M. J. (2002). Journal pricing and mergers: A portfolio approach. American Economic Review, 92(1), 259–269.

    Google Scholar 

  • McCabe, M. J. (2011). Online access and the scientific journal market: An economist’s perspective. Technical report, Draft Report for the National Academy of Sciences.

    Google Scholar 

  • McCabe, M. J., & Snyder, C. M. (2004). A model of academic journal quality with applications to open-access journals. NET Institute Working Paper No. 04-18.

    Google Scholar 

  • McCabe, M. J., & Snyder, C. M. (2005). Open access and academic journal quality. American Economic Review, 95(2), 453–458.

    Google Scholar 

  • McCabe, M. J., & Snyder, C. (2011). Did online access to journals change the economics literature. SSRN Working Paper. http://ssrn.com/abstract=1746243.

  • McCain, M., & Bobick, J. E. (1981). Patterns of journal use in a department library: A citation analysis. Journal of the American Society for Information Science, 32(4), 257–267.

    Google Scholar 

  • McGuigan, G. S., & Russel, R. D. (2008). The business of academic publishing: A strategic analysis of the academic journal publishing industry and its impact on the future of scholarly publishing. Electronic Journal of Academic and Special Librarianship, 9(3).

    Google Scholar 

  • McManis, C. (2009). A rhetorical approach to boldrine & levine: Against intellectual (property) extremism. Review of Law and Economics, 5(3), 1081–1100.

    Google Scholar 

  • Meek, R., Raphael, D. D., & Stein, P. (Ed.). (1762). Lectures on Jurisprudence. Oxford: Clarendon Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Megheli, M., & Ramello, G. B. (2013). Open access, social norms and publication choice. European Journal of Law and Economics, 35(2), 149–167.

    Google Scholar 

  • Meho, L. I. (2007). The rise and rise of citation analysis. Physics World, 20(1), 32–36.

    Google Scholar 

  • Menell, P. S. (1999). Intellectual property: General theories. In Encyclopedia of law and economics, No. 1600. http://encyclo.findlaw.com/1600book.pdf.

  • Merton, R. K. (1948). The self-fulfilling prophecy. Antioch Review, 8, 193–210.

    Google Scholar 

  • Merton, R. K. (1957). Priorities in scientific discovery: A chapter in the sociology of science. American Sociological Review, 22(6), 635–659.

    Google Scholar 

  • Merton, R. K. (1968). The Matthew effect in science. Science, 159, 56–63.

    Google Scholar 

  • Merton, R. K. (1973). The sociology of science. Theoretical and Empirical investigations. Chicago: The University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Metzger, A. (2012). Transnational law for transnational communities. The emergence of a lex mercatoria (or lex informatica) for international creative communities. Journal of Intellectual Property, Information Technology and E-Commerce Law (JIPITEC), 3, 361–368.

    Google Scholar 

  • Meurer, M. J. (2001). Copyright law and price discrimination. Cardozo Law Review, 23, 55–148.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mish, F. (Ed.) (1985). Webster’s new collegiate dictionary (9th ed.) New York: Merriam-Webster.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mitra-Kahn, B. H. (2011). Copyright, evidence and lobbynomics: The world after the UK’s Hargreaves review. Review of Economic Research on Copyright Issues, 8(2), 65–100.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mortimer, J. H. (2007). Price discrimination, copyright law, and technological innovation: Evidence from the introduction of dvds. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 122(3), 1307–1350.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mueller-Langer, F., & Scheufen, M. (2011a). Die Ökonomische analyse geistiger eigentumsrechte. WiSt - Wirtschaftswissenschaftliches Studium, 40(3), 137–142.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mueller-Langer, F., & Scheufen, M. (2011b). The google book search settlement: A law and economics analysis. Review of Economic Research on Copyright Issues, 8(1), 7–50.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mueller-Langer, F., & Scheufen, M. (2013). Academic publishing and open access. In R. Towse & C. Handke (Eds.), Handbook of the digital creative economy (pp. 365–377). Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mueller-Langer, F., & Watt, R. (2010). Copyright and open access for academic works. Review of Economic Research on Copyright Issues, 7(1), 45–65.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mueller-Langer, F., & Watt, R. (2012). Optimal pricing and quality of academic journals and the ambiguous welfare effects of forced open access: A two-sided model. TILEC Discussion Paper No. 2012-019.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mueller-Langer, F., & Watt, R. (2013). Analysis of the impact of hybrid open access on journals and authors. New Zealand: University of Canterbury, Mimeo.

    Google Scholar 

  • Nelson, R. R. (1962). The link between science and invention: The case of the transistor. In The rate and direction of inventive activity: Economic and social factors (pp. 549–583). Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Nicita, A., & Ramello, G. B. (2007). Property, liability and market power: The antitrust side of copyright. Review of Law and Economics, 3, 767–791.

    Google Scholar 

  • NIH. (2005). Policy on enhancing public access to archived publications resulting from NIH-funded research. http://grants.nih.gov/grants/guide/notice-files/NOT-OD-05-022.html.

  • NIH. (2008). Revised policy on enhancing public access to archived publications resulting from NIH-funded research. http://grants.nih.gov/grants/guide/notice-files/NOT-OD-08-033.html.

  • Noll, R. G. (1996). The economics of scholarly publications and the information superhighway. Working Paper 3, Brookings Institution Domestic Economics.

    Google Scholar 

  • Norris, M., Oppenheim, C., & Rowland, F. (2008). The citation advantage of open-access articles. Journal of the American Society for Information Science and Technology, 59(12), 1963–1972.

    Google Scholar 

  • Novos, I., & Waldman, M. (1984). The effects of increased copyright protection: An analytic approach. Journal of Political Economy, 92, 236–246.

    Google Scholar 

  • OAI. (2008). The open archives initiatives protocol for metadata harvesting. http://www.openarchives.org/OAI/openarchivesprotocol.html.

  • O’Hare, M. (1985). Copyright: When is monopoly efficient. Journal of Policy Analysis & Management, 4, 407.

    Google Scholar 

  • Okediji, R. (2007). The limits of development strategies at the intersection of intellectual property and human rights. In D. J. Gervais (Ed.), Intellectual property, trade & development: Strategies to optimize economic development in a TRIPS plus era (pp. 367–373). Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Oliver, J. (2002). Panel discussion. Copyright in the wto: The panel decision on the three-step test. Columbia Journal of Law & the Arts, 25, 119–170.

    Google Scholar 

  • Opderbeck, D. W. (2007). The penguin’s paradox: The political economy of international intellectual property and the paradox of open intellectual property models. Stanford Law and Policy Review, 18, 101–160.

    Google Scholar 

  • Osterloh, M. (2013). Das paradox der leistungsmessung und die nachhaltigkeit der forschung. In Nachhaltigkeit in der Wissenschaft (Vol. 398, pp. 103–113). Berlin: Nova Acta Leopoldina.

    Google Scholar 

  • Osterloh, M., & Frey, B. S. (2000). Motivation, knowledge transfer, and organizational forms. Organization Science, 11, 538–550.

    Google Scholar 

  • Owen, D. (2004). Copies in seconds: How a lone inventor and an unknown company created the biggest communication breakthrough since gutenberg. New York: Simon & Schuster.

    Google Scholar 

  • Palmer, T. G. (1990). Are patents and copyright morally justified? The philosophy of property rights and ideal objects. Harvard Journal of Law & Public Policy, 13(3), 817–865.

    Google Scholar 

  • Pampel, H. (2013). Bundestag bringt zweitveröffentlichungsrecht auf den weg. http://wisspub.net/2013/06/28/bundestag-bringt-zweitveroffentlichungsrecht-auf-den-weg/.

  • Parks, R. P. (2001). The faustian grip of academic publishing. Journal of Economic Methodology, 9, 317–335.

    Google Scholar 

  • Peters, D., & Ceci, S. J. (1982). Peer review practices of psychological journals: The fate of published articles, submitted again. The Behavioral and Brain Sciences, 5, 187–195.

    Google Scholar 

  • Pethig, R. (1988). Copyright and copying costs: A new price theoretic approach. Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics, 144, 462–495.

    Google Scholar 

  • Peukert, A. (2013a). Ein wissenschaftliches kommunikationssystem ohne verlage - zur rechtlichen implementierung von open access als goldstandard wissenschaftlichen publizierens. In M. Grünberger & S. Leible (Eds.), Die Kollision von Urheberrecht und Kommunikationsverhalten der Nutzer im Informationszeitalter (forthcoming) (pp. 145–172). Bayreuth: Universität Bayreuth.

    Google Scholar 

  • Peukert, A. (2013b). The relationship between copyright and science: A matter of perspective. Journal of Intellectual Property, Information Technology and E-Commerce Law (JIPITEC), 4(2), 142–156.

    Google Scholar 

  • Phillips, O. R., & Phillips, L. J. (2002). The market for academic journals. Applied Economics, 34(1), 39–48.

    Google Scholar 

  • Pigou, A. C. (1920). The Economics of welfare. London: Macmillan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Plant, A. (1934). The economic aspects of copyright in books. Economica, 1, 167–195.

    Google Scholar 

  • PLoS. (2001). Open letter to scientific publishers. http://web.archive.org/web/20110719181919/ http://www.plos.org/about/letter.php.

  • Png, I. P. L. (2006). Copyright: A plea for empirical research. Review of Economic Research on Copyright Issues, 3(2), 3–13.

    Google Scholar 

  • Png, I. P. L., & Wang, Q.-H. (2009). Copyright law and the supply of creative work: Evidence from the movies. Working Paper, National University of Singapore. http://www.comp.nus.edu.sg/~ipng/research/copyrt.pdf.

  • Pollock, R. (2007). Optimal copyright over time: Technological change and the stock of works. Review of Economic Research on Copyright Issues, 4(2), 35–60.

    Google Scholar 

  • Posner, R. A. (2005). Intellectual property: The law and economics approach. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 19(2), 57–73.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ramello, G. B. (2008). Access to vs. exclusion from knowledge: Intellectual property, efficiency and social justice. In A. Gosserie, A. Marciano, & A. Strowel (Eds.), Intellectual property and theories of justice. Basingstoke: Palgrave

    Google Scholar 

  • Ramello, G. B. (2010). Copyright & endogenous market structure: A glimpse from the journal-publishing market. Review of Economic Research on Copyright Issues, 7(1), 7–29.

    Google Scholar 

  • Raskind, L. J. (1998). Copyright. In P. Newman (Ed.), The New palgrave dictionary of economics and the law (Vol. I, pp. 478–482). London: Macmillan Press

    Google Scholar 

  • Raymond, E. (1999). The cathedral and the bazaar: Musings on linux and open source by an accidental revolutionary. Cambridge: O’Reilly,

    Google Scholar 

  • RCUK. (2012a). Note of the meeting held at polaris house on 13 November 2012 to discuss implementation & guidance questions relating to the revised RCUK open access policy. http://www.rcuk.ac.uk/documents/documents/NoteRCUKOpenAccessWorkshop3-Nov-2012.pdf.

  • RCUK. (2012b). Research councils UK policy on access to research outputs. http://roarmap.eprints.org/671/1/RCUK%20_Policy_on_Access_to_Research_Outputs.pdf.

  • RegE. (2013). Entwurf eines gesetzes zur nutzung verwaister und vergriffener werke und einer weiteren Änderung des urheberrechtsgesetzes. http://dip21.bundestag.de/dip21/btd/17/134/1713423.pdf.

  • Rehbinder, M. (2006). Urheberrecht (14th ed.). Munich: Beck Juristischer Verlag

    Google Scholar 

  • Reichman, J. H. (2009). Intellectual property in the twenty-first century: Will the developing countries lead or follow? Houston Law Review, 46(4), 1115–1185.

    Google Scholar 

  • Reichman, J. H., & Okediji, R. L. (2012). When copyright law and science collide: Empowering digitally integrated research methods on a global scale. Minnesota Law Review, 96, 1362–1480.

    Google Scholar 

  • Reichman, J. H., & Uhlir, P. F. (2003). A contractually reconstructed research commons for scientific data in a highly protectionist intellectual property environment. Law and Contemporary Problems, 66, 315–462.

    Google Scholar 

  • Reuss, R., & Rieble, V. (Eds.). (2009). Autorschaft als Werkherrschaft in digitaler Zeit. Vittorio: Klostermann.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ricketson, S., & Ginsburg, J. C. (2006). International copyright and neighboring rights (2nd ed.). Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Riddoch, I. (2000). Bridging the quality gap. Nature, 408, 402.

    Google Scholar 

  • Roach, M., & Sauermann, H. (2010). A taste for science? PhD scientists’ academic orientation and self-selection into research career in industry. Research Policy, 39, 422–434.

    Google Scholar 

  • Robinson, J. (1932). Imperfect competition and falling supply price. The Economic Journal, 42, 544–554.

    Google Scholar 

  • Romer, P. M. (1986). Increasing returns and long-run growth. Journal of Political Economy, 94(5), 1002–1037.

    Google Scholar 

  • Romer, P. M. (1990). Endogenous technological change. Journal of Political Economy, 98(5), 71–102.

    Google Scholar 

  • Romer, P. M. (1994). The origins of endogenous growth. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 8(1), 3–22.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rosen, S. (1981). The economics of superstars. American Economic Review, 71, 845–858.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rosenbaum, D. I., & Ye, M.-H. (1997). Price discrimination and economics journals. Applied Economics, 29(12), 1611–1618.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rosenberg, N. (1974). Science, invention and economic growth. Economic Journal, 84(333), 90–108.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rosenberg, N. (1990). Why do firms do basic research (with their own money)? Research Policy, 19(2), 165–174.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rosenkranz, T. (2011). Open Contents - Eine Untersuchung der Rechtsfragen beim Einsatz “freier” Urheberrechtsmodelle. Tuebingen: Mohr Siebeck.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ross, S. V. T. (2008). The scholarly use of journals offered through the health internetwork access to research initiative (hinari) and access to global online research in agriculture (agora) programs as suggested by the journal-citing patterns of authors in the least developed nations. http://etd.lib.fsu.edu/theses/available/etd-08082008-171628.

  • Ross, S. V. T., & Buckles, C. (2011). The health internetwork access to research initiative (hinari) in eligible American countries: Benefits, challenges and relationship to internet use. First Monday, 16(7).

    Google Scholar 

  • Rossi, M. A. (2006). Decoding the free/open source software puzzle: A survey of theoretical and empirical contributions. In J. Blitzer & P. Schröder (Eds.), The Economics of open source software development (pp. 15–56). Amsterdam: Elsevier.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ryan, R. M., & Deci, E. L. (2000). Intrinsic and extrinsic motivations: Classic definitions and new directions. Contemporary Educational Psychology, 25, 54–67.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sagan, C. (1980). Cosmos. New York: Random House.

    Google Scholar 

  • Samuels, E. (2000). The illustrated story of copyright. Washington: Thomas Dunne Books.

    Google Scholar 

  • Samuelson, P. A. (1954). The pure theory of public expenditure. Review of Economics and Statistics, 36(4), 387–389.

    Google Scholar 

  • Scherer, F. M. (1982). Demand-pull and technological invention: Schmookler revisited. Journal of Industrial Economics, 30(3), 225–237.

    Google Scholar 

  • Scheufen, M. (2011). What can scientists learn from the penguin? Open access and open source. Paper presented at the 10th Annual Congress of the Society of Economic Research on Copyright Issues, Bilbao, Spain. http://www.serci.org/congress/papers/Scheufen.pdf.

  • Schirmbacher, P. (2007). Open access - ein historischer abriss. In D. U. Kommission (Ed.), Open Access. Chancen und Herausforderungen - ein Handbuch. Bonn: Deutsche UNESCO Kommission.

    Google Scholar 

  • Schonwetter, T. (2007). The three-step test within the copyright system. http://pcf4.dec.uwi.edu/viewpaper.php?id=58&print=1.

  • Scotchmer, S. (2011). Ideas and innovations: Which should be subsidized? Presented at the American Economic Association.

    Google Scholar 

  • Scotchmer, S. & Maurer, S. M. (2006). A Primer for Nonlawyers on Intellectual Property. Innovation and Incentives (pp. 65–95). MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • SCST. (2004). Scientific publications: Free for all? Select committee on science and technology. 10th Report. http://www.publications.parliament.uk/pa/cm200304/cmselect/cmsctech/399/399.pdf.

  • Seltzer, L. E. (1976). Exemptions and fair use in copyright: The “exclusive rights” tension in the new copyright act. Bulletin of the Copyright Society of the USA, 24, 215.

    Google Scholar 

  • Senftleben, M. (2004). Copyright, limitations and the three-step test: An analysis of the three-step test in international and ec copyright law. Netherlands: Kluwer Law International

    Google Scholar 

  • Senftleben, M. (2006). Towards a horizontal standard for limiting intellectual property rights? - wto panel reports shed light on the three-step-test in copyright law and related tests in patent and trademark law. International Review of Intellectual Property and Competition Law, 37(4), 407–438.

    Google Scholar 

  • Senftleben, M. (2010). Bridging the differences between copyright’s legal traditions - the emerging ec fair use doctrine. Journal of the Copyright Society of the USA, 57(3), 521–552.

    Google Scholar 

  • Shapiro, C., & Varian, H. R. (1998). Versioning: The smart way to sell information. Harvard Business Review, 76(6), 106–114.

    Google Scholar 

  • Shavell, S. (2010). Should copyright for academic works be abolished? Journal of Legal Analysis, 2(1), 301–358.

    Google Scholar 

  • Shavell, S., & van Ypersele, T. (2002). Rewards versus intellectual property rights. Journal of Law and Economics, 44(2), 525–548.

    Google Scholar 

  • Shechtman, D. (1988). The icosahedral quasiperiodic phase. Physica Scripta, 49, 49.

    Google Scholar 

  • Silva, F., & Ramello, G. B. (2000). Sound recording market: The ambiguous case of copyright and piracy. Industrial and Corporate Change, 9, 415–442.

    Google Scholar 

  • Solow, R. M. (1956). A contribution to the theory of economic growth. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 70(1), 65–94.

    Google Scholar 

  • Spindler, G. (2008). Anreize zum verschenken - Open source, open access, creative commons und wikipedia als phänomene neuer geschäfts- und informationsmodelle. erste annäherungen. In T. Eger, J. Bigus, C. Ott, & G. Wangenheim (Eds.), Internationalisierung des Rechts und seine ökonomische Analyse: Festschrift für Hans-Bernd Schäfer zum 65. Geburtstag (pp. 89–102). New York: Springer.

    Google Scholar 

  • Starbuck, W. H. (2005). How much better are the most prestigious journals? The statistics of academic publication. Organization Science, 16, 180–200.

    Google Scholar 

  • Stephan, P. E. (1996). The economics of science. Journal of Economic Literature, 34(3), 1199–1235.

    Google Scholar 

  • Stephan, P. E., & Audretsch, D. B. (Eds.). (2000). The economics of science and innovation (2 Vols.). Cheltenham: Edward Elgar

    Google Scholar 

  • Stephan, P. E., & Everhart, S. S. (1998). The changing rewards to science: The case of biotechnology. Small Business Economics, 10, 141–151.

    Google Scholar 

  • Stephan, P. E., & Levin, S. G. (1992). How science is done; why science is done. In Striking the mother lode in science: The importance of age, place and time, chapter 2 (pp. 11–24). Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Stigler, G. J. (1961). The economics of information. Journal of Political Economy, 69, 213–225.

    Google Scholar 

  • Stock, J. H., & Watson, M. M. (2011). Introduction to econometrics (3th ed.). New Jersey: Pearson

    Google Scholar 

  • Stodden, V. (2009). Enabling reproducible research: Open licensing for scientific innovation. International Journal of Communications Law and Policy, 13(Winter 2009), 1–25.

    Google Scholar 

  • Suber, P. (2004). Praising progress, preserving precision. SPARC Open Access Newsletter, No. 77, available at: http://www.earlham.edu/~peters/fos/newsletter/09-02-04.htm.

  • Suber, P. (2006). Open access in the united states. In N. Jacobs (Ed.), Open access: Key strategic, technical and economic aspects. Oxford: Chandos Publishing.

    Google Scholar 

  • Suber, P. (2012). Open access. London: The MIT Press Essential Knowledge Series.

    Google Scholar 

  • Suber, P., & Arunachalam, S. (2005). Open access to science in the developing world. http://www.firstauthor.org/Downloads/openaccess.pdf.

  • Sung, M., Villacisneros, C., Hsueh, S., & Yang, R. (2009). Copyright and the advent of xerox machines, Berkeley. http://blogs.ischool.berkeley.edu/i103su09/structure-projects-assignments/research-project/.

  • Swan, T. W. (1956). Economic growth and capital accumulation. Economic Record, 32(2), 334–361.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tenopir, C., & King, D. W. (2000). Towards electronic journals: Realities for scientists, librarians and publishers. Washington: Special Libraries Association.

    Google Scholar 

  • Thatcher, S. G. (1978). On fair use and library photocopying. Scholarly Publishing, 9, 313–334.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tietzel, M. (1995). Literaturökonomik. Tuebingen: J.C.B. Mohr.

    Google Scholar 

  • Towse, R. (2001). Creativity, incentive and reward: An economic analysis of copyright and culture in the information age. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar

    Google Scholar 

  • Towse, R. (2006). Copyright and creativity: An application of cultural economics. Review of Economic Research on Copyright Issues, 3(2), 83–91.

    Google Scholar 

  • Towse, R., Handke, C., & Stepan, P. (2008). The economics of copyright law: A stocktake of the literature. Review of Economic Research on Copyright Issues, 5(1), 1–22.

    Google Scholar 

  • TRIPS. (1994). Agreement on trade-related aspects of intellectual property rights. http://www.wto.org/.

  • Turnbull, H. W. (Ed.) (1959). Letter to Robert Hooke (5 February 1676). Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Turnbull, S. (1998). Should ownership last forever? Journal of Socio-Economics, 27(3), 341–363.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ulph, D., & Vulkan, N. (2000). Electronic commerce and competitive first-degree price discrimination. http://else.econ.ucl.ac.uk/papers/vulkan.pdf.

  • Varian, H. R. (2000). Buying, sharing and renting information goods. Journal of Industrial Organizations, 4, 473–488.

    Google Scholar 

  • Varian, H. R. (2005). Copying and copyright. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 19(2), 121–138.

    Google Scholar 

  • Venske, A. (2000). Johannes gutenberg - Der erfinder des buchdrucks und seine zeit. Munich: Piper.

    Google Scholar 

  • Viswanathan, S., & Anandalingam, G. (2005). Pricing strategies for information goods. Sadhana, Journal of the Indian Academy of Sciences, 30, 257–274.

    Google Scholar 

  • Watt, R. (2004). The past and the future of the economics of copyright. Review of Economic Research on Copyright Issues, 1(1), 151–171.

    Google Scholar 

  • Watt, R. (2005). Indirect appropriability 20 years on. Review of Economic Research on Copyright Issues, 2(1), 1–4.

    Google Scholar 

  • Watt, R. (2007). Patent and/or copyright for software: What has been done so far? Review of Economic Research on Copyright Issues, 4(1), 3–14.

    Google Scholar 

  • Watt, R. (2010). Introduction: Copyright and the publishing of scientific works. Review of Economic Research on Copyright Issues, 7(1), 1–6.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wiebe, A. (2010). The economic perspective: Exhaustion in the digital age. In L. Bently, U. Suthersanen, & P. Torremans (Eds.), Global copyright. Three hundred years since the statute of anne, from 1709 to cyberspace (pp. 321–336). Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.

    Google Scholar 

  • Willinsky, J. (2005). The unacknowledged convergence of open source, open access, and open science. First Monday, 10(8).

    Google Scholar 

  • Willinsky, J. (2009). The stratified economics of open access. Economic Analysis and Policy, 39(1), 53–70.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wills, G. (1999). Saint augustine. New York: Viking Penguin.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wilson, L. (1942). The academic man: A study in the sociology of a profession. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • WIPO. (1999). Joint recommendation concerning provisions on the protection of well-known marks. http://www.wipo.int/export/sites/www/about-ip/en/development_iplaw/pdf/pub833.pdf.

  • WIPO. (2001). Joint recommendation concerning provisions on the protection of marks and other industrial property rights in signs, on the internet. http://www.wipo.int/export/sites/www/about-ip/en/development_iplaw/pdf/pub845.pdf.

  • Woods, T. M. (2009). Working towards spontaneous copyright licensing: A simple solution for a complex problem. Vanderbilt Journal of Entertainment and Technology Law, 11(4), 1141–1168.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wooldridge, J. M. (2005). Introductory econometrics: A modern approach. Boston: Cengage Learning Services.

    Google Scholar 

  • WTO. (2000). United States - Section 110(5) of the US copyright act. http://www.wto.org/english/tratop_e/dispu_e/1234da.pdf.

  • WTO. (2009). China - Measures affecting the protection and enforcement of intellectual property rights. Report of the panel. http://www.worldtradelaw.net/reports/wtopanelsfull/china-iprights(panel)(full).pdf.

  • Yuan, M. (2010). Digital technology, price discrimination, and copyright duration extension. Review of Economic Research on Copyright Issues, 7(1), 39–55.

    Google Scholar 

  • Zimmermann, C. (2009). Academic rankings with repec. Working Paper 2007-36R. Department of Economics,University of Connecticut.

    Google Scholar 

  • Zuckerman, H. (1992). The proliferation of prizes: Nobel complements and nobel surrogates in the reward system of science. Theoretical Medicine, 13, 217–231.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2015 Springer International Publishing Switzerland

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Scheufen, M. (2015). On the Access Principle in Science: A Law and Economics Analysis. In: Copyright Versus Open Access. International Law and Economics. Springer, Cham. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-319-12739-2_4

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics