Skip to main content

A Large Population Parental Care Game with Asynchronous Moves

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
Advances in Dynamic Games

Part of the book series: Annals of the International Society of Dynamic Games ((AISDG,volume 13))

Abstract

This article considers two game-theoretic models of parental care which take into account the feedback between patterns of care and the operational sex ratio. Attention is paid to fish species which care for their young by mouthbrooding, in particular to St. Peter’s Fish. It is assumed here that individuals can be in one of the two states: searching for a mate or breeding (including caring for their offspring). However, the sets of states can be adapted to the physiology of a particular species. The length of time an individual remains in the breeding state depends on the level of care he/she gives. According to one model, parents make their decision regarding the amount of care they give simultaneously. Under the second model, one individual in a pair (for convenience, the female) makes her decision before the male makes his decision. When in the searching state, individuals find partners at a rate dependent on the proportion of members of the opposite sex searching. These rates are defined to satisfy the Fisher condition that the total number of offspring of males equals the total number of offspring of females. The operational sex ratio is not defined exogenously, but can be derived from the adult sex ratio and the pattern of parental care. The results obtained go some way to explain the variety of parental care behaviour observed in fish, in particular the high frequency of male care, although further work is required to explain the exact patterns observed.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 84.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 109.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD 109.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Similar content being viewed by others

References

  • Balshine-Earn S (1997) The benefits of uniparental versus biparental mouth brooding in Galilee St. Peter’s fish. J Fish Biol 50:371–381

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Balshine-Earn S, Earn DJD (1997) An evolutionary model of parental care in St. Peter’s fish. J Theor Biol 184:423–431

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Broom M, Ruxton GD (1998) Evolutionarily stable stealing: Game theory applied to kleptoparatism. Behav Ecol 9(4):397–403

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Clutton-Brock TH, Parker GA (1992) Potential reproductive rates and the operation of sexual selection. Q Rev Biol 67:437–456

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dawkins R, Carlisle TR (1976) Parental investment and mate desertion: A fallacy. Nature 262: 131–133

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Emlen ST, Oring LW (1977) Ecology, sexual selection, and the evolution of mating systems. Science 197:215–223

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Eriksson A, Lindgren K, Lundh T (2004) War of attrition with implicit time costs. J Theor Biol 203:319–332

    Article  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  • Fishelson L, Hilzerman F (2002) Flexibility in reproductive styles of male St. Peter’s tilapia Sarotherodon Galilaeus (Cichlidae). Environ Biol Fishes 63:173–182

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Grafen A, Sibly R (1978) A model of mate desertion. Anim Behav 26:645–652

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Grüter C, Taborsky B (2005) Sex ratio and the sexual conflict about brood care in a biparental mouthbrooder. Behav Ecol Sociobiol 58:44–52

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gubernick DJ, Teferi T (2000) Adaptive significance of male parental care in a monogamous mammal. Proc R Soc Lond B 267:147–150

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hayward A, Gillooly JF (2011) The cost of sex: Quantifying energetic investment in gamete production by males and females. PLoS ONE 6(1):e16,557

    Google Scholar 

  • Houston AI, McNamara JM (2002) A self-consistent approach to paternity and parental effort. Phil Trans R Soc Lond B 357:351–362

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Houston AI, McNamara JM (2005) John Maynard Smith and the importance of consistency in evolutionary game theory. Biol Philos 20:933–950

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jennions M, Polakow D (2001) The effect of partial brood loss on male desertion in a cichlid fish: An experimental test. Behav Ecol 12(1):84–92

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jennions MD, Kokko H (2010) Sexual selection. In: Westneat DF, Fox CW (eds) Evolutionary behavioral ecology. Oxford University Press, Oxford, pp 343–364

    Google Scholar 

  • Kokko H, Jennions M (2003) It takes two to tango. Trends Ecol Evol 18:103–104

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kokko H, Jennions MD (2008) Parental investment, sexual selection and sex ratios. J Evol Biol 21:919–948

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kokko H, Rankin DJ (2006) Lonely hearts or sex in the city? density-dependent effects in mating systems. Phil Trans R Soc B 361:319–334

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Maynard Smith J (1977) Parental investment: A prospective analysis. Anim Behav 25:1–9

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Maynard Smith J (1982) Evolution and the theory of games. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Book  MATH  Google Scholar 

  • McNamara JM, Székely T, Webb JN, Houston AI (2005) A dynamic game-theoretic model of parental care. J Theor Biol 205:605–623

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ramsey DM (2010) A large population parental care game: Polymorphisms and feedback between patterns of care and the operational sex ratio. J Theor Biol 266:675–690

    Article  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  • Ros AFH, Zeilstra I, Oliveira RF (2003) Mate choice in the Galilee St. Peter’s fish, Sarotherodon Galilaeus. Behaviour 140:1173–1188

    Google Scholar 

  • Trivers RL (1972) Parental investment and sexual selection. In: Campbell B (ed) Sexual selection and the descent of man 1871–1971. Aldine Press, Chicago, pp 139–179

    Google Scholar 

  • Webb JN, Houston AI, McNamara JM, Székely T (1999) Multiple patterns of parental care. Anim Behav 58:983–993

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wright HWY (2006) Paternal den attendance is the best predictor of offspring survival in the socially monogamous bat-eared fox. Anim Behav 71:503–510

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Yamamura N, Tsuji N (1993) Parental care as a game. J Evol Biol 6:103–127

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Yaniv O, Motro U (2004) The parental investment conflict in continuous time: St. Peter’s fish as an example. J Theor Biol 228:377–388

    MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

The author is grateful for the support of Science Foundation Ireland under the BIO-SI project (no. 07MI012).

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to David M. Ramsey .

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

Appendices

Appendix 1: Stability Conditions in Game with Simultaneous Moves

The left-hand side of each inequality is the reproduction rate of males (which is the reproduction rate of the females divided by the ASR), the first entry on the right-hand side is the reproduction rate of a mutant male and the second entry is the reproduction rate of a mutant female divided by the ASR.

Only male parental care is an ESS if

$$\displaystyle{ k_{m}\lambda _{1}q_{1}^{CD}p_{ 1}^{CD} >\max \left \{ \frac{\lambda _{1}\lambda _{m}^{D}q_{ 1}^{CD}} {\lambda _{m}^{D} +\lambda _{1}q_{1}^{CD}}, \frac{k_{b}\lambda _{1}\lambda _{f}^{C}p_{1}^{CD}} {\lambda _{f}^{C} +\lambda _{1}rp_{1}^{CD}}\right \}. }$$
(8.44)

Only female parental care is an ESS if

$$\displaystyle{ k_{f}\lambda _{1}q_{1}^{DC}p_{ 1}^{DC} >\max \left \{ \frac{k_{b}\lambda _{1}\lambda _{m}^{C}q_{ 1}^{DC}} {\lambda _{m}^{C} +\lambda _{1}q_{1}^{DC}}, \frac{\lambda _{1}\lambda _{f}^{D}p_{1}^{DC}} {\lambda _{f}^{D} +\lambda _{1}rp_{1}^{DC}}\right \}. }$$
(8.45)

Parental care by both sexes is an ESS if

$$\displaystyle{ k_{b}\lambda _{1}q_{1}^{CC}p_{ 1}^{CC} >\max \left \{\frac{k_{f}\lambda _{1}\lambda _{m}^{D}q_{ 1}^{CC}} {\lambda _{m}^{D} +\lambda _{1}q_{1}^{CC}}, \frac{k_{m}\lambda _{1}\lambda _{f}^{D}p_{1}^{CC}} {\lambda _{f}^{D} +\lambda _{1}rp_{1}^{CC}}\right \}. }$$
(8.46)

Appendix 2: Stability Conditions in Game with Asynchronous Moves

No parental care with unconditional desertion by males, [(D, D), D], is neutrally stable when

$$\displaystyle\begin{array}{rcl} \max \{k_{f}, \frac{k_{b}} {k_{f}}\}& <& \frac{\lambda _{m}^{D}(\lambda _{m}^{C} +\lambda _{1}q_{1}^{DD})} {\lambda _{m}^{C}(\lambda _{m}^{D} +\lambda _{1}q_{1}^{DD})}{}\end{array}$$
(8.47)
$$\displaystyle\begin{array}{rcl} k_{f}& <& \frac{\lambda _{f}^{D}(\lambda _{f}^{C} +\lambda _{1}rp_{1}^{DD})} {\lambda _{f}^{C}(\lambda _{f}^{D} +\lambda _{1}rp_{1}^{DD})}.{}\end{array}$$
(8.48)

This strategy profile is strongly stable when, in addition

$$\displaystyle{ k_{b} < \frac{\lambda _{f}^{D}(\lambda _{f}^{C} +\lambda _{1}rp_{1}^{DD})} {\lambda _{f}^{C}(\lambda _{f}^{D} +\lambda _{1}rp_{1}^{DD})}. }$$

Biparental care with unconditional care from males, [(C, C), C], is neutrally stable when

$$\displaystyle\begin{array}{rcl} \min \{k_{f}, \frac{k_{b}} {k_{f}}\}& >& \frac{\lambda _{m}^{D}(\lambda _{m}^{C} +\lambda _{1}q_{1}^{CC})} {\lambda _{m}^{C}(\lambda _{m}^{D} +\lambda _{1}q_{1}^{CC})}{}\end{array}$$
(8.49)
$$\displaystyle\begin{array}{rcl} \frac{k_{b}} {k_{f}}& >& \frac{\lambda _{f}^{D}(\lambda _{f}^{C} +\lambda _{1}rp_{1}^{CC})} {\lambda _{f}^{C}(\lambda _{f}^{D} +\lambda _{1}rp_{1}^{CC})}.{}\end{array}$$
(8.50)

The condition required for strong stability, i.e.

$$\displaystyle{ k_{b} > \frac{\lambda _{f}^{D}(\lambda _{f}^{C} +\lambda _{1}rp_{1}^{CC})} {\lambda _{f}^{C}(\lambda _{f}^{D} +\lambda _{1}rp_{1}^{CC})}, }$$

is a weaker condition than Condition (8.50). Hence, if [(C, C), C] is neutrally stable, then it is strongly stable.

Finally, it can be shown that [(C, D), C], i.e. biparental care with male care being conditional on the female giving care, is neutrally stable when

$$\displaystyle\begin{array}{rcl} k_{f}& <& \frac{\lambda _{m}^{D}(\lambda _{m}^{C} +\lambda _{1}q_{1}^{CC})} {\lambda _{m}^{C}(\lambda _{m}^{D} +\lambda _{1}q_{1}^{CC})} < \frac{k_{b}} {k_{f}}{}\end{array}$$
(8.51)
$$\displaystyle\begin{array}{rcl} k_{b}& >& \frac{\lambda _{f}^{D}(\lambda _{f}^{C} +\lambda _{1}rp_{1}^{CC})} {\lambda _{f}^{C}(\lambda _{f}^{D} +\lambda _{1}rp_{1}^{CC})}.{}\end{array}$$
(8.52)

This strategy profile is strongly stable when, in addition

$$\displaystyle{ \frac{k_{b}} {k_{f}} > \frac{\lambda _{f}^{D}(\lambda _{f}^{C} +\lambda _{1}p_{1}^{CC}r)} {\lambda _{f}^{C}(\lambda _{f}^{C}(\lambda _{f}^{D} +\lambda _{1}p_{1}^{CC}r))}. }$$

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2013 Springer International Publishing Switzerland

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Ramsey, D.M. (2013). A Large Population Parental Care Game with Asynchronous Moves. In: Křivan, V., Zaccour, G. (eds) Advances in Dynamic Games. Annals of the International Society of Dynamic Games, vol 13. Birkhäuser, Cham. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-319-02690-9_8

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics