Skip to main content

Connecting the Two Approaches

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
Productivity

Part of the book series: Contributions to Economics ((CE))

  • 448 Accesses

Abstract

Productivity analysis is carried out at various levels of aggregation. In microdata studies the emphasis is on individual firms (or plants), whereas in sectoral studies it is on (groupings of) industries. Microdata researchers do not care too much about the interpretation of the weighted means of firm-specific productivities employed in their analyses. In this chapter the consequences of this attitude are explored, based on a review of the literature. However, a structurally similar phenomenon happens in sectoral studies, where the productivity change of industries is compared to each other and to the productivity change of some next-higher-level aggregate, which is usually the (measurable part of the) economy. Though there must be a relation between sectoral and economy-level measures, in most publications by statistical agencies and academic researchers this aspect is more or less neglected. The point of departure of this chapter is that aggregate productivity should be interpreted as productivity of the aggregate. It is shown that this implies restrictive relations between the productivity measure, the set of weights, and the type of mean employed.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 99.00
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 129.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD 129.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    The relation between levels and indices was discussed in Sect. 5.4.

  2. 2.

    PROD t can be considered as a 2-stage aggregation procedure: first PROD kt aggregates over basic inputs and outputs per production unit k, and then PROD t aggregates over all the units \(k \in \mathcal {K}^t\). \(\mathit {PROD}^{\mathcal {K}^{t}t}\) can be considered as a 1-stage aggregate of the same basic inputs and outputs. See Diewert (1980, 495–498) for a similar discussion in terms of variable profit (or, value added) functions and technological change (assuming continuous time and differentiability), and the PPI Manual (2004, Chapter 18) for the cases of revenue, intermediate-input-cost, and value-added based price indices. Notice the double role of the variable t in \(\mathit {PROD}^{\mathcal {K}^{t}t}\).

  3. 3.

    Expression (9.9) is the model underlying GEAD-TFP as implemented by Calver and Murray (2016).

  4. 4.

    Notice that we are considering here additivity of production units, which is different from additivity of commodities as considered in Sect. 5.2.

  5. 5.

    This is the model underlying the CSLS decomposition as implemented by Calver and Murray (2016).

  6. 6.

    This reflects the denominator rule and the numerator rule of Fare and Karagiannis (2017), respectively.

  7. 7.

    This measure was also considered by Foster et al. (2001). Actually, two variants were considered, one where the labour unit was an hour worked and one where it was a worker. The geometric alternative was employed by Hyytinen and Maliranta (2013) for plants; labour quantity was thereby measured in full-time equivalents.

  8. 8.

    Actually, their multi-factor productivity index, discussed in Sect. 5.4.4.2, can be seen as a special case of \(\mathit {TFPROD}_{Y}^{k}(t,b)\).

  9. 9.

    Essentially the same method was used by Figal Garone et al. (2020), except that \(\mathit {TFPROD}_{Y}^{k}(t,b)\) was replaced by revenue productivity.

References

  • Baily, M.N., E.J. Bartelsman, and J. Haltiwanger. 2001. Labor Productivity: Structural Change and Cyclical Dynamics. The Review of Economics and Statistics 83: 420–433.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bartelsman, E.J., and Ph.J. Dhrymes. 1998. Productivity Dynamics: US Manufacturing Plants, 1972–1986. Journal of Productivity Analysis 9: 5–34.

    Google Scholar 

  • Basu, S., and J.G. Fernald. 2002. Aggregate Productivity and Aggregate Technology. European Economic Review 46: 963–991.

    Google Scholar 

  • Calver, M., and A. Murray. 2016. Decomposing Multifactor Productivity Growth in Canada by Industry and Province, 1997–2014. International Productivity Monitor 31: 88–112.

    Google Scholar 

  • Collard-Wexler, A., and J. de Loecker. 2015. Reallocation and Technology: Evidence from the U. S. Steel Industry. American Economic Review 105: 131–171.

    Google Scholar 

  • De Loecker, J., and J. Konings. 2006. Job Reallocation and Productivity Growth in a Post-Socialist Economy: Evidence from Slovenian Manufacturing. European Journal of Political Economy 22: 388–408.

    Google Scholar 

  • Diewert, W.E. 1980. Aggregation Problems in the Measurement of Capital. In The Measurement of Capital, ed. Dan Usher (National Bureau of Economic Research, Cambridge MA; University of Chicago Press).

    Google Scholar 

  • Eslava, M., J. Haltiwanger, A. Kugler, and M. Kugler. 2013. Trade and Market Selection: Evidence from Manufacturing Plants in Colombia. Review of Economic Dynamics 16: 135–158.

    Google Scholar 

  • Färe, R., and G. Karagiannis. 2017. The Denominator Rule for Share-weighting Aggregation. European Journal of Operational Research 260: 1175–1180.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Figal Garone, L., P.A. López Villalba, A. Maffioli, and C.A. Ruzzier. 2020. Firm-level Productivity in Latin America and the Caribbean. Research in Economics 74: 186–192.

    Google Scholar 

  • Foster, L., J. Haltiwanger and C.J. Krizan. 2001. Aggregate Productivity Growth: Lessons from Microeconomic Evidence. In New Developments in Productivity Analysis, ed. C.R. Hulten, E.R. Dean, and M.J. Harper. Studies in Income and Wealth, vol. 63. Chicago and London: The University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hyytinen, A., and M. Maliranta. 2013. Firm Lifecycles and Evolution of Industry Productivity. Research Policy 42: 1080–1098.

    Google Scholar 

  • Maliranta, M., and N. Määttänen. 2015. An Augmented Static Olley-Pakes Productivity Decomposition with Entry and Exit: Measurement and Interpretation. Economica 82: 1372–1416.

    Google Scholar 

  • Melitz, M.J., and S. Polanec. 2015. Dynamic Olley-Pakes productivity decomposition with entry and exit. The RAND Journal of Economics 46: 362–375.

    Google Scholar 

  • Olley, S., and A. Pakes. 1996. The Dynamics of Productivity in the Telecommunications Equipment Industry. Econometrica 64: 1263–1297.

    Google Scholar 

  • PPI Manual. 2004. Producer Price Index Manual: Theory and Practice (Published for ILO, IMF, OECD, UN, Eurostat, The World Bank by IMF, Washington, DC).

    Google Scholar 

  • van Biesebroeck, J. 2008. Aggregating and Decomposing Productivity. Review of Business and Economics LIII: 122–146.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2021 The Author(s), under exclusive license to Springer Nature Switzerland AG

About this chapter

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this chapter

Balk, B.M. (2021). Connecting the Two Approaches. In: Productivity. Contributions to Economics. Springer, Cham. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-030-75448-8_9

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics