Skip to main content
  • 285 Accesses

Abstract

In this chapter, alternative dynamic models of consumer behavior are presented and evaluated. I first review historical models, including the partial adjustment model and state adjustment model, which are mainly empirical in nature. Next, models based on the theory of the consumer are presented. These modeling approaches are both myopic models (i.e., models that ignore consumer’s choices on future marginal utility), and fully intertemporal models. The intertemporal models discussed include both single-equation models and multivariate models. The rational addiction model is an important single-equation model. Multivariate generalizations of intertemporal models include the Multivariate Rational Addiction model (MRA), the SNAP model, and Habits-as-Durables model. To show how to empirically implement the system of dynamic consumer demand functions approach, I present a data set for alcoholic beverages and estimate demand parameters for the MRA model. Results indicate close conformity with theory.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

eBook
USD 16.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 16.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    Wohlgenant and Hahn (1982), in application of the state adjustment model to monthly demand for beef, pork, and chicken, approximate MA(1) process by second-order autoregressive process and then transform the model so that it is nonlinear in the A’s and autoregressive parameters, \(\rho_{1}\) and \(\rho_{2}\). The resulting model is estimated by nonlinear OLS.

  2. 2.

    In Wohlgenant (2012), the composite good is included in the utility function as in Becker et al. (1994). For sake of convenience, it is treated as additively separable here. This is consistent with the two-stage budgeting process in Chapter 3. One could also make the function \(\varphi \left( {y_{j} } \right)\) depend on lagged consumption of the composite good, but this would have no consequence for the problem at hand. For simplicity as well, I have not included the life-cycle variables as in Becker et al. (1994).

  3. 3.

    While the consumer chooses quantities, he/she cannot know with certainty that the planned choice next period will be the actual choice, given that market prices and income are not known. Moreover, the analyst modeling consumer behavior does not know the consumer’s next period choice. With rational expectations, it is thus logical to model \(E_{\varvec{t}} \varvec{q}_{t + 1} = \varvec{q}_{t + 1} - \varvec{u}_{t + 1}\).

  4. 4.

    The unobserved variable \(z_{it - 1}\) is calculated according to (9.34) with the initial value of \(z_{it - 1}\) set to \(z_{i0} = q_{i0} /\left( {1 - \delta_{i} } \right)\).

  5. 5.

    Data covering at home and away from consumption are preferred, but only data by alcoholic beverage are available for only at home consumption.

  6. 6.

    Because the instrumental variables used, \(\varvec{p}_{t} , \varvec{ p}_{t - 1} ,\varvec{ p}_{t + 1} , y_{t} ,\) and \(t\) are exogenous, the residuals from 3SLS are consistently estimated. Durbin–Watson statistics from these estimated models indicated serial correlation in all three equations.

  7. 7.

    We also fail to reject the test for overidentifying restrictions with a p-value of 0.9. This is often interpreted as a test of the validity of the model.

References

  • Almon, S. “The Distributed Lag Between Capital Appropriations and Expenditures.” Econometrica 33(1965): 178–196.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bask, M., and M. Melkersson. “Rationally Addicted to Drinking and Smoking?” Applied Economics 36(2004): 373–386.

    Google Scholar 

  • Becker, G.S., M. Grossman, and K.M. Murphy. “An Empirical Analysis of Cigarette Addiction.” The American Economic Review 84(1994): 396–418.

    Google Scholar 

  • Blanciforti, L., and R Green. “An Almost Ideal Demand System Incorporating Habits: An Analysis of Expenditures on Food and Aggregate Commodity Groups.” The Review of Economics and Statistics 65(3)(1983): 511–515.

    Google Scholar 

  • Browning, M. “A Simple Nonadditive Preference Structure for Models of Household Behavior over Time.” Journal of Political Economy 99(1991): 607–637.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fuller, W.A. Introduction to Statistical Time Series. New York: Wiley, 1976.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gallet, C.A. “The Demand for Alcohol: A Meta-Analysis of Elasticities.” Australian Journal of Agricultural and Resource Economics 51(2007): 121–135.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gorman, W.M. “Tastes, Habits and Choices.” International Economic Review 8(1967): 218–222.

    Google Scholar 

  • Greene, W.H. Econometric Analysis. Upper Saddle River, NJ: Pearson Education, Inc., 2003.

    Google Scholar 

  • Holt, M.T., and B.K. Goodwin. “Generalized Habit Formulation in an Inverse Almost Ideal Demand System: An Application to Meat Expenditures in the U.S.” Empirical Economics 22(1997): 293–320.

    Google Scholar 

  • Houthakker, H.S., and L.D. Taylor. Consumer Demand in the United States: Analyses and Projections. 2nd Ed. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, 1970.

    Google Scholar 

  • Jorgenson, D.W. “Rational Distributed Lag.” Econometrica 34(1966): 135–149.

    Google Scholar 

  • Koksal, A., and Michael Wohlgenant. “How Do Smoking Bans in Restaurants Affect Restaurant and at Home Alcohol Consumption? Empirical Economics 50(2016): 1193–1213.

    Google Scholar 

  • Manser, M. “Elasticities of Demand for Food: An Analysis Using Functions Allowing for Habit Formation.” Southern Economic Journal (1976): 879–891.

    Google Scholar 

  • Meghir, C., and G. Weber. “Intertemporal Nonseparability or Borrowing Restrictions? A Disaggregate Analysis Using a U.S. Consumption Panel.” Econometrica 64(1996): 1151–1181.

    Google Scholar 

  • Nerlove, M. Distributed Lags and Demand Analysis. Agricultural Handbook No. 141, U.S. Department of Agriculture, Washington, 1958.

    Google Scholar 

  • Newey, K.N., and K.D. West. “A Simple Positive-Definite Heteroskedasticity and Autocorrelation Consistent Covariance Matrix.” Econometrica 55(1987): 703–708.

    Google Scholar 

  • Phlips, L. “A Dynamic Version of the Linear Expenditure Model.” The Review of Economics and Statistics 54(1972): 450–458.

    Google Scholar 

  • Phlips, L. Applied Consumption Analysis. Amsterdam: North-Holland Publishing Co., 1983.

    Google Scholar 

  • Pierani, P., and S. Tiezzi. “Addiction and Interaction Between Alcohol and Tobacco Consumption.”  Empirical Economics 37(2009): 1–23.

    Google Scholar 

  • Spinnewyn, F. “Rational Habit Formation.” European Economic Review 15(1981): 91–109.

    Google Scholar 

  • Stigler, G.J., and G.S. Becker. “De Gustibus Non Est Disputandum.” The American Economic Review 67(1977): 76-90.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wohlgenant, M.K. “The Multivariate Rational Addiction Model.” Theoretical Economics Letters 2(2012): 459–464.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wohlgenant, Michael K., and William F. Hahn. “Dynamic Adjustment in Monthly Consumer Demands for Meats.” American Journal of Agricultural Economics 64(1982): 553–557.

    Google Scholar 

  • Zhen, Chen, Michael K. Wohlgenant, Shawn Karns, and Philip Kaufman. “Habit Formation and Demand for Sugar-Sweetened Beverages.” American Journal of Agricultural Economics 93(2011): 175–193.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Appendix: Proof of Theorem 4

Appendix: Proof of Theorem 4

Following Wohlgenant (2012), Eq. (9.21) can be written as a matrix polynomial in

Lags as follows:

$$\left( {\beta^{ - 1} \varvec{I}L^{2} + \beta^{ - 1} \varvec{B}^{ - 1} \varvec{A}L + \varvec{I}} \right)L^{ - 1} E_{\varvec{t}} \varvec{q}_{t} = \lambda \beta^{ - 1} \varvec{B}^{ - 1} E_{t} \varvec{p}_{t}$$

Because \(\varvec{B}\) is a positive definite matrix, we know there exists an orthogonal matrix \(\varvec{P}\) such that \(\varvec{PBP^{\prime}} = \varvec{N}\), a diagonal matrix with all positive diagonal elements. Define \(\varvec{S} = \varvec{N}^{0.5} \varvec{P}\), where \(\varvec{N}^{0.5}\) is a diagonal matrix whose elements are positive square roots. Because \(\varvec{B} = \varvec{P^{\prime}NP} = \varvec{S^{\prime}S}\), we see that \(\varvec{B}\) can be written as the product of two square root matrices. Because \({-}\varvec{A}\) is a positive definite matrix, \(- \varvec{S^{\prime}}^{ - 1} \varvec{AS}^{ - 1}\) is also positive definite. Therefore, there exists an orthogonal matrix \(\varvec{R}\) such that \(- \varvec{RS^{\prime}}^{ - 1} \varvec{AS}^{ - 1} \varvec{R^{\prime}} = \varvec{M}\), a diagonal matrix whose diagonal elements are positive. Define \(\varvec{Q} = \varvec{S}^{ - 1} \varvec{R^{\prime}}\), then \(- \varvec{Q}^{ - 1} \varvec{B}^{ - 1} \varvec{AQ} = - \varvec{RS^{\prime}}^{ - 1} \varvec{A} \varvec{S}^{ - 1} \varvec{R^{\prime}} = \varvec{M}\). Thus, we have proved \(- \varvec{B}^{ - 1} \varvec{A}\) is similar to \(- \varvec{A}\), implying it has the same positive roots. The rest of the steps are identical to Wohlgenant (2012), where we multiply both sides of the matrix polynomial by \(\varvec{Q}^{ - 1}\) and post-multiply by \(\varvec{Q}\) to obtain

$$\varvec{Q}^{ - 1} \left( {\beta^{ - 1} \varvec{Q}L^{2} - \beta^{ - 1} \varvec{QM}L + \varvec{Q}} \right)\varvec{Q}^{ - 1} L^{ - 1} E_{\varvec{t}} \varvec{q}_{t} = \lambda \beta^{ - 1} \varvec{Q}^{ - 1} \varvec{B}^{ - 1} E_{t} \varvec{p}_{t} \mathop \Rightarrow \limits_{{}}$$
$$\left( {\beta^{ - 1} \varvec{I}L^{2} - \beta^{ - 1} \varvec{M}L + \varvec{I}} \right)\varvec{Q}^{ - 1} L^{ - 1} E_{\varvec{t}} \varvec{q}_{t} = \lambda \beta^{ - 1} \varvec{Q}^{ - 1} \varvec{B}^{ - 1} E_{t} \varvec{p}_{t} \mathop \Rightarrow \limits_{{}}$$
$$\left( {\varvec{I} -\varvec{\varLambda}_{1} L} \right)\left( {\varvec{I} -\varvec{\varLambda}_{2} L} \right)\varvec{Q}^{ - 1} L^{ - 1} E_{\varvec{t}} \varvec{q}_{t} = \lambda \beta^{ - 1} \varvec{Q}^{ - 1} \varvec{B}^{ - 1} E_{t} \varvec{p}_{t} \mathop \Rightarrow \limits_{{}}$$
$$-\varvec{\varLambda}_{2} L\left( {\varvec{I} -\varvec{\varLambda}_{2}^{ - 1} L^{ - 1} } \right)\left( {\varvec{I} -\varvec{\varLambda}_{1} L} \right)\varvec{Q}^{ - 1} L^{ - 1} E_{\varvec{t}} \varvec{q}_{t} = \lambda \beta^{ - 1} \varvec{Q}^{ - 1} \varvec{B}^{ - 1} E_{t} \varvec{p}_{t} \mathop \Rightarrow \limits_{{}}$$
$$\left( {\varvec{I} -\varvec{\varLambda}_{1} L} \right)\varvec{Q}^{ - 1} E_{\varvec{t}} \varvec{q}_{t} = - \left( {\varvec{I} -\varvec{\varLambda}_{2}^{ - 1} L^{ - 1} } \right)^{ - 1} \lambda \beta^{ - 1}\varvec{\varLambda}_{2}^{ - 1} \varvec{Q}^{ - 1} \varvec{B}^{ - 1} E_{t} \varvec{p}_{t} \mathop \Rightarrow \limits_{{}}$$
$$\left( {\varvec{I} - \varvec{Q\varLambda }_{1} \varvec{Q}^{ - 1} L} \right)E_{\varvec{t}} \varvec{q}_{t} = - \varvec{Q}\left( {\varvec{I} -\varvec{\varLambda}_{2}^{ - 1} L^{ - 1} } \right)^{ - 1} \lambda \beta^{ - 1} \varvec{\varLambda }_{2}^{ - 1} \varvec{Q}^{ - 1} \varvec{B}^{ - 1} E_{t} \varvec{p}_{t}$$

where we use the results that \(\varvec{M} =\varvec{\varLambda}_{1} +\varvec{\varLambda}_{2}\) and \(\varvec{\varLambda}_{1}\varvec{\varLambda}_{2} = \beta^{ - 1} \varvec{I}\). Wohlgenant (2012) shows that there are exactly \(2n\) distinct positive roots such that \(\lambda_{1i} < 1\) and \(\lambda_{2i} = \beta^{ - 1} \lambda_{1i}^{ - 1} > 1\). After substituting \(E_{\varvec{t}} \varvec{q}_{t} = \varvec{q}_{t} - \varvec{u}_{t}\), we obtain the desired result. QED

Problems

  1. 9.1

    Derive the discrete version of the State Adjustment Model, Eq. (9.10), and show how the reduced-form coefficients, the \(K_{i}\)’s, are related to the underlying structural parameters. Show that Eq. (9.11) is the overidentifying restriction.

  2. 9.2

    Derive Becker et al.’s (1994) rational addiction model. Discuss the issues in estimation of the model. How would you obtain short-run and long-run price elasticities of demand from this model? How do the elasticities change depending upon not only the length of time for adjustment to price changes but also the consumer’s perception of how long the price change is expected to last?

  3. 9.3

    Given the intraperiod profit function, Eq. (9.30), derive the SNAP model, Eq. (9.31). Discuss how expectations are modeled and how the model nests the AIDS model. Discuss why this model is highly restrictive regarding intertemporal substitution between individual goods.

  4. 9.4

    Taxes on alcoholic beverages have favored wine and beer over spirits. The federal tax shares of alcohol price are approximately 4.6 percent for beer, 2.6 percent for wine, and 9.7 percent for spirits, respectively. Taxes are levied on a per gallon basis. Using the elasticities from the estimated MRA model in Table 9.3, estimate the effects on beer, wine, and spirits consumption from increasing the tax rates for beer and wine by 30 percent, but leaving the tax rate for spirits the same. How do the short-run and long-run effects (for permanent price change) differ?

    Table 9.3 Elasticities of Dynamic Demand for Wine, Beer, and Spirits

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2021 The Author(s), under exclusive license to Springer Nature Switzerland AG

About this chapter

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this chapter

Wohlgenant, M.K. (2021). Dynamic Consumer Demand. In: Market Interrelationships and Applied Demand Analysis. Palgrave Studies in Agricultural Economics and Food Policy(). Palgrave Macmillan, Cham. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-030-73144-1_9

Download citation

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-030-73144-1_9

  • Published:

  • Publisher Name: Palgrave Macmillan, Cham

  • Print ISBN: 978-3-030-73143-4

  • Online ISBN: 978-3-030-73144-1

  • eBook Packages: Economics and FinanceEconomics and Finance (R0)

Publish with us

Policies and ethics