Skip to main content

Derived Demand, Marketing Margins, and Relationship Between Output and Raw Material Prices

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
Market Interrelationships and Applied Demand Analysis
  • 298 Accesses

Abstract

This chapter reviews the historical approach to modeling derived demand for raw materials, with a focus primarily on derived demand for agricultural inputs. This discussion is followed by the presentation of a general model of derived demand that allows one to link the system of consumer demand functions to the corresponding system of derived demand functions for agricultural inputs. The focus is on developing a framework that is theoretically consistent with consumer demand behavior and market intermediary behavior. The Gardner (1975) model develops theoretical implications for a long-run competitive behavior. The Wohlgenant (1989) model is an empirical model used to estimate and test basic tenets of competitive behavior for retail-to-farm price linkage of a complete system of demand functions. Empirical results from ChapterĀ 5 for consumer demand for meats with linkages to other goods are used in the estimation of reduced-form equations for retail and farm prices, thereby linking retail demand to farm-level demand for each of the meat commodities. Tests for symmetry and constant returns to scale show consistency with the Gardner model.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

eBook
USD 16.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 16.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    See Tomek and Robinson (1981, ChapterĀ 6) for a graphical analysis of these relationships.

  2. 2.

    See, e.g., Varian (1992) for properties of conditional input demand functions.

  3. 3.

    Normal means downward sloping demand for output and upward-sloping supply curves for inputs.

  4. 4.

    The analysis ignores technical change. If technical change is farm-input saving then the farmerā€™s share of the retail dollar would decrease. See Miedema (1976) or Wohlgenant (2011).

  5. 5.

    Wohlgenant (1989) found significant input substitution for six out of seven disaggregate food commodities for earlier time period. Goodwin and Brester (1995) estimate an input demand system for all food and find significant input substitution between agricultural raw materials and each other input.

  6. 6.

    If supply is jointly determined with price, then the analysis is still valid, conditional on the quantity of the raw material supply being fixed. In empirical estimation, the quantity m can be taken as endogenous with appropriate instruments used in estimation.

  7. 7.

    From the first equation, \(\varepsilon_{pr} + \varepsilon_{pw} = \varepsilon \cdot \varepsilon_{pz}\). Because \(\varepsilon = \frac{1}{{\varepsilon_{pz} }} + e\), it follows that \(\varepsilon \cdot \varepsilon_{pz} = \left( {\frac{1}{{\varepsilon_{pz} }} + e} \right)\varepsilon_{pz} = 1 + e \cdot \varepsilon_{pz}\).

  8. 8.

    These two restrictions result from the fact that proportionate changes in both m and va will lead to a proportional change in industry output. This must occur with input prices and output price constant. As can be seen from (7.47) and (7.48), r and p will remain constant for proportional changes in m and z only if the conditions in (7.69) and (7.70) hold.

  9. 9.

    Note that this implies that the own-price elasticity is the compensated elasticity as well.

  10. 10.

    To be consistent with retail demand, beef and veal quantities are added together for ā€œbeefā€ quantity designation.

  11. 11.

    Initially, an index of wage rates and index of fuels and related products and power was constructed and used but was found to be inferior to simply the wage rate index. Therefore, the index of wage rate was used in estimation.

  12. 12.

    Complete time series data for poultry are unavailable, so median shares are used rather than mean shares in estimation. Comparison of median with mean values for beef and veal and pork indicates only small differences between the two measures of central tendency.

  13. 13.

    The general form of the SUR estimator is nonlinear SUR, for which the likelihood ratio test is \(L = S\left( {\widetilde{\varvec{\theta}},\widehat{\varvec{\varOmega}}} \right) - S\left( {\widehat{\varvec{\theta}},\widehat{\varvec{\varOmega}}} \right)\), distributed chi-squared with r (number of restrictions), where \(S\left( {\varvec{\theta},\widehat{\varvec{\varOmega}}} \right) = \sum\nolimits_{t = 1}^{T} {\left[ {\varvec{y}_{\varvec{t}} - \varvec{f}\left( {\varvec{x}_{\varvec{t}} ,\varvec{\theta}} \right)} \right]^{'} \widehat{\varvec{\varOmega}}^{ - 1} \left[ {\varvec{y}_{\varvec{t}} - \varvec{f}\left( {\varvec{x}_{\varvec{t}} ,\varvec{\theta}} \right)} \right]}\). Note that both \(S\left( \cdot \right)\) functions are minimized with respect to the vector of parameters, \(\varvec{\theta}\). Because of the estimation method, each uses the same variance-covariance matrix, \(\widehat{\varvec{\varOmega}}\varvec{ }\), estimated using residuals from OLS estimation in the first stage. For estimation of reduced-form parameters, the function \(\varvec{f}\left( {\varvec{x}_{\varvec{t}} ,\varvec{\theta}} \right)\) is linear in both variables and parameters. For estimation of structural parameters, the estimator is linear in variables but nonlinear in parameters. See Gallant (1987, ChapterĀ 5) for more details.

  14. 14.

    Because cross-price and income elasticities are taken as deterministic, the reported asymptotic standard errors underestimate the true standard errors. These standard errors are not reported here. Murphy and Topel (2001) provide formulas for this case.

  15. 15.

    The supply elasticity is computed as \(\frac{1}{{\varepsilon_{pz} }} + e\) and the input demand elasticity is computed as \(\frac{ - 1}{{\varepsilon_{rm} }}\), using the appropriate parameters from TableĀ 7.2 and TableĀ 7.5.

  16. 16.

    The compensated industry derived demand elasticities hold output constant and are measured by setting the term \(\widehat{s}_{mi} \widehat{e}_{ii} = 0\).

  17. 17.

    A third approach to testing the validity of the retail consumption data is to model demand for meats as derived demand functions directly (Brester and Wohlgenant 1993). This results in a model with an index of marketing inputs as an additional variable in the model. Under constant returns to scale, the elasticity of derived demand with respect to this variable and elasticity of demand with respect to retail price can be used to identify the true retail demand elasticity. The wage rate variable was included in the conditional demand functions for beef and veal, pork, and poultry, and found statistically insignificant in all three cases, suggesting no significant bias with use of disappearance data in this application.

References

  • Allen, R.G.D. Mathematical Analysis for Economists.Ā London:Ā Macmillan & Co., 1938.

    Google ScholarĀ 

  • Alston, J.A., and G.M. Scobie. ā€œDistribution of Research Gains in Multistage Production Systems: Comment.ā€ American Journal of Agricultural Economics 65(1983): 353ā€“356.

    Google ScholarĀ 

  • Amemyia, T. Advanced Econometrics. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, 1985.

    Google ScholarĀ 

  • Braulke, M. ā€œThe Firm in Short-Run Equilibrium: Comment.ā€ The American Economic Review 74(1984): 750ā€“753.

    Google ScholarĀ 

  • Braulke, M. ā€œOn the Comparative Statics of a Competitive Industry.ā€ The American Economic Review 77(1987): 479ā€“485.

    Google ScholarĀ 

  • Brester, Gary W., and Michael K. Wohlgenant. ā€œCorrecting for Measurement Error in Food Demand Estimation.ā€ The Review of Economics and Statistics 75(1993): 352ā€“356.

    Google ScholarĀ 

  • Buccola, S.T. ā€œMaterial and Value-Adding Inputs in Manufacturing Enterprises.ā€ Journal of Productivity Analysis 13(2000): 231ā€“247.

    Google ScholarĀ 

  • Diewert, W.E. ā€œThe Comparative Statics of Long-Run Equilibrium.ā€ Canadian Journal of Economics 14(1981): 78ā€“92.

    Google ScholarĀ 

  • Friedman, M. Price Theory. Chicago: Aldine Publishing Co., 1976.

    Google ScholarĀ 

  • Gallant, A.R. Nonlinear Statistical Models. New York: Wiley, 1987.

    Google ScholarĀ 

  • Gardner, B.Ā ā€œThe Farm-Retail Price Spread in a Competitive Food Industry.ā€ American Journal of Agricultural Economics 57(1975): 399ā€“409.

    Google ScholarĀ 

  • George, P.S., and G.A.Ā King.Ā  Consumer Demand for Food Commodities in the United State with Projections for 1980. Giannini Foundation Monograph No. 26, California Agricultural Experiment Station, Berkeley, CA, 1971.

    Google ScholarĀ 

  • Goodwin, B.K., and G.W. Brester. ā€œStructural Change in Factor Demand Relationships in the U.S. Food and Kindred Products Industry.ā€ American Journal of Agricultural EconomicsĀ 77(1995): 69ā€“79.

    Google ScholarĀ 

  • Hadley, G. Linear Algebra. Reading, MA: Addison-Wesley Publishing Company, Inc., 1961.

    Google ScholarĀ 

  • Hausman, J.A. ā€œSpecification Tests in Econometrics.ā€ Econometrica 46(1978): 1251ā€“1271.

    Google ScholarĀ 

  • Heiner, R.A. ā€œTheory of the Firm in ā€˜Short-Runā€™ Industry Equilibrium.ā€ The American Economic Review 82(1982): 555ā€“562.

    Google ScholarĀ 

  • Hicks, J.R. The Theory of Wages. New York: St. Martinā€™s Press, 1957.

    Google ScholarĀ 

  • Liviatan, N. ā€œThe Marginalist Principle in a Discrete Production Model under Uncertain Demand.ā€ Quarterly Journal of Economics 85(1971): 684ā€“709.

    Google ScholarĀ 

  • Marshall, A. Principles of Economics. New York: MacMillan Co. Ltd., Inc., 1920.

    Google ScholarĀ 

  • Miedema, A.K. ā€œThe Retail-Farm Price Ratio, the Farmerā€™s Share and Technical Change.ā€ American Journal of Agricultural Economics 58(1976): 750ā€“756.

    Google ScholarĀ 

  • Mosak, J.L. ā€œInterrelations of Production, Price, and Derived Demand.ā€ Journal of Political Economy 46(1938): 761ā€“787.

    Google ScholarĀ 

  • Mundlak, Y., and H. Huang. ā€œInternational Comparisons of Cattle Cycles.ā€ American Journal of Agricultural Economics 78(1996): 855ā€“868.

    Google ScholarĀ 

  • Panzar, J.C., and R.D. Willig. ā€œOn the Comparative Statics of a Competitive Industry with Inframarginal Firms.ā€ The American Economic Review 68(1978): 474ā€“478.

    Google ScholarĀ 

  • Stigler, G.J., and G.S.Ā Becker.Ā ā€œDe Gustibus Non Est Disputandum.ā€ The American Economic ReviewĀ 67(1977):Ā 76ā€“90.

    Google ScholarĀ 

  • Vernon, J.M., and D.A. Graham. ā€œProfitability of Monopolization by Vertical Integration.ā€ Journal of Political Economy 79(1971): 924ā€“925.

    Google ScholarĀ 

  • Walters, A.A. ā€œMarginal Productivity and Probability Distributions of Factor Services.ā€ The Economic Journal 70(1960): 325ā€“330.

    Google ScholarĀ 

  • Wegge, L.L. ā€œConstrained Indirect Least Squares Estimators.ā€ Econometrica 46(1978): 435ā€“449.

    Google ScholarĀ 

  • Wohlgenant, M.K. ā€œDemand for Farm Output in a Complete System of Demand Functions.ā€ American Journal of Agricultural Economics 71 (1989): 241ā€“252.

    Google ScholarĀ 

  • Wohlgenant, M.K. ā€œMarketing Margins: Empirical Analysis.ā€ In B.L. Gardner and G.C. Rausser (eds.) Handbook of Agricultural Economics, Vol. 1B, pp. 934ā€“970. Amsterdam: Elsevier Science B.V., 2001, Chapter 16.

    Google ScholarĀ 

  • Wohlgenant, M.K., and J.D.Ā Mullen.Ā ā€œModeling the Farm-Retail Price Spread for Beef.ā€ Western Journal of Agricultural EconomicsĀ 12(1987): 119ā€“125.

    Google ScholarĀ 

  • Wohlgenant, M.K., and R.C. Haidacher. Retail to Farm Demand Linkages of a Complete System of Demand Functions, USDA Technical Bulletion No. 1775, Washington, 1989.

    Google ScholarĀ 

  • Wohlgenant, Michael K. ā€œConsumer Demand and Welfare in Equilibrium Displacement Models.ā€ In Lusk, J., J. Roosen, and J. Shogren (eds.) Handbook on the Economics of Food Consumption and Policy. London: Oxford University Press, 2011, Chapter 11.

    Google ScholarĀ 

  • Wohlgenant, Michael K. ā€œDistribution of Gains from Research and Promotion in Multi-Stage Production Systems: The Case of the U.S. Beef and Pork Industries.ā€ American Journal of Agricultural Economics 75(1993): 642ā€“651. (Errata: 75(1993): 1072.).

    Google ScholarĀ 

  • Wohlgenant, Michael K. ā€œMarket Middlemen and Determinants of the Price Spread Under Competition.ā€ Theoretical Economics Letters 4(2014): 834ā€“838.

    Google ScholarĀ 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Appendix: Input Substitution and Output Demand Uncertainty

Appendix: Input Substitution and Output Demand Uncertainty

The purpose of this Appendix is to show how continuous, convex-shaped isoquants can result from a linear programming problem of choosing a variable factor, \(v\), in combination with a quasi-fixed factor, \(m\), via two production techniques to minimize input use subject to given expected output, \(q\), and a fixed available level of the factor, \(b\). It is assumed that both factors, \(v\) and \(m\) are divisible and that \(v\) is freely available in supply. This corresponds closely to livestock slaughter and processing where predetermined quantities of the livestock are scheduled for processing ahead of time, and where the plant adjusts its variable factors to meet expected demand. The Appendix parallels Liviathan (1971) for the simplest case of two production techniques.

The processor minimizes \(v_{1} + v_{2}\) (equivalently, minimizing costs, \(w\left( {v_{1} + v_{2} } \right.), {\text{where}} w {\text{is fixed}}\)) subject to the production function, \(q \le a_{q1} v_{1} + a_{q2} v_{2}\), and the restriction on the availability of the raw material, \(b \ge a_{m1} v_{1} + a_{m2} v_{2}\), with \(v_{i} \ge 0, \forall i\). The deterministic solution can be seen graphically from the figure below.

With the way the two constraints are shown, the solution to the problem is at point B where the curve intersecting point B gives the lowest possible sum of \(v_{1}\) and \(v_{2}\). For a given level of output, represented by the ordinate q/aq1, there is a tradeoff between \(v\) and \(m\) between points A and B. At point B both constraints are satisfied, but at point A only the production constraint is met. Suppose point C is the ex ante choice of inputs with expected output given by the dotted line. This point predetermines the quasi-fixed input \(m\). Suppose ex post output is given by the line segment AB. With the quasi-fixed factor fixed by point C, the input combination \(v_{1}\) and \(v_{2}\) will be directly below point C on the line segment AB. With the variable factor freely available, it will adjust downward to meet output \(q\). In general, for the output \(q,\) combinations of \(v_{1}\) and \(v_{2}\) would be distributed between A and B. For points to the left of the ray OC, whose slope is \(\frac{{{\text{a}}_{q1} }}{{{\text{a}}_{m1} }}\), the optimum relationship between \(v {\text{and}} b\) for given \(q\) is \(v = \gamma^{1} q - \beta^{1} b\) where \(\beta^{1} = 0\). For points to the right of \(\frac{{{\text{a}}_{q1} }}{{{\text{a}}_{m1} }}\), the optimum relationship between \(v {\text{and}} m\) for given \(q\) is \(v = \gamma^{2} q - \beta^{2} b\).

Define \(\alpha \left( b \right) = \frac{{{\text{a}}_{q1} }}{{{\text{a}}_{m1} }}\) and let \(f(q,m) = \gamma q - \beta b\) and let the probability density function for demand be \(h\left( q \right)\) such that \(\mathop \smallint \limits_{L}^{U} h\left( q \right)dq = 1\). The relationship between the expected value of \(v\) and output is \(E\left( v \right) = \mathop \smallint \limits_{L}^{\alpha \left( b \right)} f\left( {q,b} \right) h\left( q \right)dq + \mathop \smallint \limits_{\alpha \left( b \right)}^{U} f\left( {q,b} \right)h\left( q \right)dq\). Partially differentiating with respect to \(b\) we obtain

$$\frac{\partial E\left( v \right)}{\partial b} = \mathop \smallint \limits_{L}^{\alpha \left( b \right)} \frac{{\partial f\left( {q,b} \right)}}{\partial b}h\left( q \right)dq - \mathop \smallint \limits_{\alpha \left( b \right)}^{U} \frac{{\partial f\left( {q,b} \right)}}{\partial b}h\left( q \right)dq$$
$$= \mathop \smallint \limits_{L}^{\alpha \left( b \right)} - \beta^{1} h\left( q \right)dq - \mathop \smallint \limits_{\alpha \left( b \right)}^{U} - \beta^{2} h\left( q \right)dq\quad \text{or}$$
$$\frac{\partial E\left( v \right)}{\partial b} = \beta^{2} \mathop \smallint \limits_{\alpha \left( b \right)}^{U} h\left( q \right)dq$$

because \(\beta^{1} = 0.\) The marginal rate of substitution between b and v is \({\text{MRS }} = - \frac{\partial E\left( v \right)}{\partial b}\). Differentiating with respect to \(b\):

$$\frac{\partial MRS}{\partial b} = - \beta^{2} h\left( {\alpha \left( b \right)} \right) \alpha \left( b \right) < 0$$

Therefore, the MRS is continuously differentiable and convex to the origin as postulated.

Problems

  1. 7.1

    It is frequently observed that income and the farm value share are negatively correlated. Using the Gardner long-run competitive model of the food industry, explain two ways in how this could occur. Do these conditions seem reasonable?

  2. 7.2

    For pork where we find the elasticity of substitution is not significantly different from zero, calculate the new reduced-form parameters using Eqs.Ā (7.78)ā€“(7.80) using data from TableĀ 7.2.

  3. 7.3

    Define incidence of marketing charges on farmers as \(I_{r,w} = \frac{{\left| {\frac{dlog r}{dlog w}} \right|}}{{\left( {\left| {\frac{dlog r}{dlog w}} \right| + \left| {\frac{dlog p}{dlog w}} \right|} \right)}}\). Calculate values of \(I_{r,w}\) for beef and veal, pork, and poultry from the empirical results in TablesĀ 7.6 and 7.8 for beef and veal and poultry, and from problem 7.2 for pork. Explain why there are differences in the incidence of marketing charges across commodities.

  4. 7.4

    The Wohlgenant (1989) model takes farm quantities as predetermined in the short run. Suppose over a period of time, producers are able to adjust supplies in response to the change in farm price. In particular, suppose that the supply elasticities for beef and veal, pork, and poultry are 0.5, 1.0, and 3.0. Using the results from TablesĀ 7.6ā€“7.8 estimate the effects of exogenous shifts in demand, processing costs, and farm supplies on retail and farm prices for each commodity. Assume that for each commodity, supply changes can be written as \(Er_{i} = \left( {1/\varepsilon_{i} } \right)Em_{i} + Es_{i}\), where \(\varepsilon_{i}\) is the supply elasticity of commodity and \(Es_{i}\) is the (vertical) relative change in supply. Discuss the new results incorporating the supply functions, and compare with the results in TablesĀ 7.6ā€“7.8.

  5. 7.5

    The COVID-19 pandemic caused disruptions in red meat and poultry processing. In some instances, there was more than a 40 percent reduction in the workforce. Using the comparative static results from Gardnerā€™s model with the parameter estimates from this study, calculate the effect of a 10 percent reduction in employment on retail-to-farm price ratios for the three meat commodities. For determinate solutions, assume that the short-run supply elasticity for each farm input is 0.1. Discuss the results and explain why meat processors would not necessarilyĀ profit from the increase in the price spread, in this instance.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

Ā© 2021 The Author(s), under exclusive license to Springer Nature Switzerland AG

About this chapter

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this chapter

Wohlgenant, M.K. (2021). Derived Demand, Marketing Margins, and Relationship Between Output and Raw Material Prices. In: Market Interrelationships and Applied Demand Analysis. Palgrave Studies in Agricultural Economics and Food Policy(). Palgrave Macmillan, Cham. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-030-73144-1_7

Download citation

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-030-73144-1_7

  • Published:

  • Publisher Name: Palgrave Macmillan, Cham

  • Print ISBN: 978-3-030-73143-4

  • Online ISBN: 978-3-030-73144-1

  • eBook Packages: Economics and FinanceEconomics and Finance (R0)

Publish with us

Policies and ethics