Skip to main content

Markets Are Moral Spaces

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
Do Markets Corrupt Our Morals?

Abstract

This chapter argues that markets function better when participants are virtuous, although markets could function without especially virtuous actors. Additionally, we show that market participants tend to be virtuous. Deirdre McCloskey has forcefully and convincingly made the same point that markets are compatible with and depend on virtuous behavior. The bourgeois virtues are both bourgeois (i.e. born of markets) and virtuous (i.e. exhibiting the very virtues we have long admired). Beyond exhibiting the seven virtues that McCloskey highlighted (love, faith, hope, courage, temperance, prudence, and justice), we show that people in market societies tend to be more altruistic, are less likely to be materialistic and corrupt, and are more likely to be cosmopolitan as well as trusting and trustworthy.

This chapter borrows from Storr (2009), Langrill and Storr (2012), and Choi and Storr (2017).

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 29.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 37.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    A ducat contains 3.5 grams of gold and would have been worth about $161 in December 2010. As such, 3000 ducats would approximately be worth over $480, 000 today.

  2. 2.

    Shakespeare’s account of Shylock, for instance, is obviously full of negative ethnic stereotypes. Shakespeare offensively depicted Shylock as the greedy Jew who values his wealth more than his own daughter. Shylock is despised and insulted by his Christian enemies, who repeatedly refer to him as “a kind of devil” (II.ii. 23), “the very devil” (II.ii. 26–27), “the devil ... in the likeness of a Jew” (III.i. 19–20), a “cruel devil” (IV.i. 224), a “damn’d, in execrable dog” (IV.i. 130), and an “inhuman wretch” (IV.i. 4). Throughout the play, Shylock is rarely referred to by name; he is simply the Jew. As literary critic Harold Bloom (1998) wrote, “[o]ne would have to be blind, deaf, and dumb not to recognise that Shakespeare’s grand, equivocal comedy The Merchant of Venice is nevertheless a profoundly anti-Semitic work.” The extent of the anti-Semitism in this play is perhaps best described by the fact that Nazi Germany popularly used The Merchant of Venice as propaganda (Gross 1993).

    Shakespeare’s anti-Semitism was nothing unique in his time. Moneylending was one of the few occupations available to Jews in the European Middle Ages and onward, as Christians were forbidden from practicing usury (Ferguson 2008). Jews were also excluded from other fields of work. Christian kings, for instance, banned Jews from owning farm land. And craft guilds tended to refuse to admit Jews as artisans (Gross 1975).

  3. 3.

    In many ways, the play is a cautionary tale. “This play helps us understand,” Page et al. (2017: 39) wrote, “the ramifications of making business decisions based on self-interest, passion, jealousy, revenge, and greed, and how assessments of risk and return can become distorted.” A key question is whether or not this kind of distorted decision-making is typical. It is perhaps telling that a 2016 YouGov poll found that The Merchant of Venice was the fifth most popular Shakespeare play (Dahlgreen 2016). That the Merchant of Venice has remained popular for centuries and that the play continues to resonate with audiences and readers may indicate that the play captures something that people believe is true about market activity.

  4. 4.

    Freedman (2009: 181) explained that,

    [Shylock’s] worship of money is the natural result of his social stigmatization. Shylock is far from unfeeling. The moral revealed to Portia’s suitor—‘all that glitters is not gold’—does not elude him. However, as he clings to money in order to define his sense of self, mercenary damage usurps emotional loss: ‘my ducats, my daughter’, he wails, more concerned that Jessica has disappeared with his riches than that she has disappeared. Shylock’s usury is idolatrous because he can’t distinguish money-lending (the sign of his identity) from everything he holds dear (his true identity). He worships his profession with the devotion due to his God and the emotion due to his daughter.

  5. 5.

    For instance, in recent years, think of the unsavory behavior of various characters in The Social Network, The Wolf of Wall Street, and Iron Man in their pursuit of (greater) wealth. Similarly, the protagonist of The Greatest Showman, P.T. Barnum, could be viewed as a variant of Adam Smith’s ([1759] 1982) story of the poor man’s son.

  6. 6.

    Boyle and Kelly (2012) argued that the representations of business people have changed with the advent of reality television shows that feature businesses and business people.

  7. 7.

    Aristotle (NE VI.12) distinguished between the prudence as a virtue (phronesis) which is a virtue of practical reason and mere prudence or cleverness (deinotes). Market participants clearly rely on deinotes. Admittedly, it is more controversial to claim that markets rely on and reward phronesis. See Yuengert (2012) for a helpful discussion of how an Aristotelian conception of practical wisdom compares with the ways that economics tend to account for prudence.

  8. 8.

    See Nelson (1992) for an argument in favor of ascribing a central role to prudence in our virtue ethics. See also Russell (2009) for his discussion of phronesis.

  9. 9.

    See Sen (1986), Griswold (1999), Hanley (2009), and Viganò (2017a, b) for a discussion of Smith’s treatment of prudence.

  10. 10.

    On the other hand, Smith ([1759] 1982: 216) explained, “When combined with other vices, however, [imprudence] aggravates in the highest degree the infamy and disgrace which would otherwise attend them.” “As prudence combined with other virtues, constitutes the noblest; so imprudence combined with other vices, constitutes the vilest of all characters” (Ibid.: 217).

  11. 11.

    Smith ([1759] 1982: 213) described that “[f]or reputation in his profession he is naturally disposed to rely a good deal upon the solidity of his knowledge and abilities; and he does not always think of cultivating the favour of those little clubs and cabals.”

  12. 12.

    Note that the argument here is not that people in market societies are more reliant on prudence (defined as deinotes or phronesis) than people in nonmarket societies. Instead, the argument here is simply that prudence is not incompatible with, and in fact is critical to, life in market societies.

  13. 13.

    Arguably, even those studies that downplay the role of rationality in bringing about market efficiency do so by assuming and enforcing at least a “basic” level of rationality. Becker (1962: 8), for instance, argued that “households may be irrational and yet markets quite rational.” Deploying a market experiment where human participants were replaced by zero-intelligence programs subject to a budget constraint, Gode and Sunder (1993) similarly found that markets can function well even when the individual participants are not rational. Stated another way, zero-intelligence traders submitting random bids and offers in a double auction would converge toward the predicted prices and quantities. Markets, it seems, might survive and even achieve allocative efficiency without prudent market participants. But it is important to note that Gode and Sunder imposed a budget constraint (i.e. buyers could not spend more than their budgets and sellers could not accept offers below their costs). As such, these traders could not be completely imprudent. Additionally, while markets can survive imprudent market participants, it is unlikely that imprudent market participants could survive (let alone thrive) in the market. Moreover, while we might achieve allocative efficiency with only minimally prudent market participants, we suspect that the market is unlikely to achieve dynamic efficiency or even productive efficiency if all of the market participants were completely imprudent.

  14. 14.

    See also Forsythe et al. (1992) and Forsythe et al. (1999).

  15. 15.

    As Martin and Storr (2012: 787–788) wrote, “contrary to much of the literature on the relationship between discourse and social change which tends to focus on discourse as an artifact rather than a driver of change, we argue … that a change in talk not only tends to accompany but often precedes dramatic social transformation.”

  16. 16.

    Similarly, Joseph Schumpeter explained that the successful entrepreneur is likely to be intuitive and a leader. According to Schumpeter ([1911] 1983: 85),

    Carrying out a new plan and acting according to a customary one are things as different as making a road and walking along it. … [I]n economic life action must be taken without working out all the details of what is to be done. Here the success of everything depends upon intuition, the capacity of seeing things in a way which afterwards proves to be true, even though it cannot be established at the moment, and of grasping the essential fact, discarding the unessential, even though one can give no account of the principles by which this is done.

    Success also depends on the entrepreneur leading “the means of production into new channels” (Ibid.: 89). “Economic leadership,” Schumpeter (Ibid.: 88) explained, “must hence be distinguished from ‘invention.’ As long as they are not carried into practice, inventions are economically irrelevant.”

  17. 17.

    Additionally, the bourgeois virtues are not always balanced in all people at all times in commercial society. For instance, greed is a vice that develops when prudence alone is not checked by or balanced with other virtues. Selfish individuals may succeed on some margins in the market, but will suffer from missed profit opportunities and lead unfulfilling lives. An interesting example of missed profit opportunities is discussed by Ingram and Roberts (2000) who showed that hotel managers could incur losses by not being friends with their competitors. Love alone could lead to the vice of lust, but alloyed with prudence evokes trust and reciprocity. Hope unrestrained by other virtues transforms a principled business person into a common street thug. A man with courage, without restraint of other virtues, is too easily swayed by pride, envy, and greed. Justice, alone, can morph into anger but produces the bourgeois virtue of honesty when combined with faith and courage.

  18. 18.

    Again, we are not claiming here that undesirable behavior and vices never occur in a market setting. There are countless instances where promises of higher quality goods and services are unfulfilled and where cheating and fraud happen. But, it is important to remember that the market, just like the community, is a space where people interact with one another (Storr 2008). As such, as spaces of social interactions, people can and do behave and treat each other poorly in both the market and the community; morally corrupt behavior and principles are not uniquely linked to the market.

  19. 19.

    Interestingly, the U.S. Trust (2016) study proposed that the wealthy might also be a mechanism through which our culture could be preserved because the wealthy view fine art as a profitable investment strategy. Twenty-two percent of the respondents collect fine art, over half of whom believe that fine art is an asset that will maintain (if not increase) its value over time.

  20. 20.

    The Nike advertisement with Colin Kaepernick and Proctor & Gamble’s Gillette advertisement were not without controversy (e.g. Abad-Santos 2018; Hsu 2019; Murphy 2019; Scott 2018; Tiffany 2019; Wang and Siegel 2018). We should clarify that we do not mention these advertisements here to add to the debates and conversations fueled by the advertisements. Instead, we mention these advertisements here to merely communicate that companies do sometimes publicly take stances on social issues, occasionally with some risk.

  21. 21.

    Interestingly, CAF 2017 World Giving Index also reveals that citizens of market and nonmarket societies help strangers at roughly the same frequency; on average, 51.2% of the respondents in market societies self-reported having helped a stranger in the past month while 49% of the respondents in nonmarket societies self-reported doing so. In short, people in market and nonmarket societies apparently help strangers equally, but people in market societies appear to donate more money and more frequently than people in nonmarket societies. One possible reason for this phenomenon is that those living in market societies have more disposable income than those in nonmarket societies and can afford to donate more.

  22. 22.

    We want to note that, fortunately, the majority of the residents in both market and nonmarket societies view avoiding fares on public transport, stealing, cheating on taxes, and bribery as unjustifiable actions.

  23. 23.

    See Arrow (1972) for a modification and extension of Becker’s model. See also Marshall (1974) for a survey of the literature on the economics of racial discrimination and a critique of Becker’s model of discrimination. Ikeda (2018) offered a useful extension to Becker’s model noting that markets not only mean that individuals pay a price for discrimination, but also empowers entrepreneurs to discover past errors that they and others have made, including errors in assessing the productivity of different racial groups.

  24. 24.

    Despite his clear predications about the connection between discrimination and wages, Becker’s (1957) model remained empirically untested for decades (to the best of our knowledge). Charles and Guryan (2008) speculated that Arrow (1972) may have contributed to this occurrence. Arrow (Ibid.: 192) criticized that Becker’s model of discrimination “predicts the absence of the phenomenon it was designed to explain” because it states that prejudiced employers would ultimately be driven out of the market for sacrificing profits in exchange for indulging their prejudiced preferences. Charles and Guryan (2007, 2008) do attempt to empirically examine Becker’s model. Charles and Guryan (2007) demonstrated that racial discrimination and its resultant wage gap could survive perfect competition scenarios; in other words, even if the market drove out racist employers, the prejudiced tastes and the resultant wage gap can persist so long as racist employers can transfer their tastes into their new market role as employees. Charles and Guryan (2008), however, tested and confirmed Becker’s key predictions about the relationship between prejudice and wages.

  25. 25.

    While statistically no different, on average, less people in market societies also mentioned that they would not want to have foreign workers as neighbors (20.26%) than those in nonmarket societies (24.55%).

  26. 26.

    This is interestingly contrasted by views on the importance of equal gender rights for a democracy. Seventy-three percent of the respondents from market societies and 72.8% of those from nonmarket societies agreed that women having equal rights as men is an essential characteristic of a democracy (see Appendix for the definition of the variable and how we calculated our statistics). While equal gender political rights are just as important for those living in nonmarket societies as it is for those living in market societies, it appears as if people living in nonmarket societies do not believe women deserve the same access to economic opportunities, nor economic success, as men.

  27. 27.

    More specifically, Sweden scored the maximum score in Personal Freedom Index categories of Women’s Security and Safety—Equal Inheritance Rights, Women’s Freedom of Movement, and Women’s Parental Rights.

Bibliography

  • Abad-Santos, A. 2018. Why the Social Media Boycott Over Colin Kaepernick Is a Win for Nike. Vox, September 6. https://www.vox.com/2018/9/4/17818148/nike-boycott-kaepernick

  • Abderholden, F.S. 2017. Dairy Queen Ending Franchise Agreement with Zion Store After Racial Slur Incident. Chicago Tribune, January 7. http://www.chicagotribune.com/suburbs/lake-county-news-sun/news/ct-lns-dairy-queen-racial-slurs-zion-st-0107-20170106-story.html

  • Abrams, R. 2018. Starbucks to Close 8,000 U.S. Stores for Racial-Bias Training After Arrests. The New York Times, April 17. https://www.nytimes.com/2018/04/17/business/starbucks-arrests-racial-bias.html

  • Aghion, P., Y. Algan, P. Cahuc, and A. Schleifer. 2010. Regulation and Distrust. The Quarterly Journal of Economics 125 (3): 1015–1049.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Akerlof, G.A. 1970. The Market for ‘Lemons’: Quality Uncertainty and the Market Mechanism. The Quarterly Journal of Economics 84 (3): 488–500.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Al Jazeera. 2018. Hong Kong Actor Chow Yun-fat Vows to Donate His Entire Fortune. December 24. https://www.aljazeera.com/news/2018/12/hong-kong-actor-chow-yun-fat-vows-donate-entire-fortune-181224142911854.html

  • Algan, Y., and P. Cahuc. 2010. Inherited Trust and Growth. American Economic Review 100 (5): 2060–2092.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Al-Ubaydli, O., D. Houser, J. Nye, M.P. Paganelli, S.X. Pan, and F. Krueger. 2013. The Causal Effect of Market Priming on Trust: An Experimental Investigation Using Randomized Control. PLoS One 8 (3): e55968.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Andreoni, J. 1995. Cooperation in Public-Goods Experiments: Kindness or Confusion? American Economic Review 85 (4): 891–904.

    Google Scholar 

  • Aquinas, T. [1485] 1918. Summa Theologica. Translated by the English Dominican Province. London: Burns, Oates & Washbourne.

    Google Scholar 

  • Aristotle. [340 BC] 1984, 2013. Nicomachean Ethics. Translated by Robert Bartlett and Susan Collins. Chicago and London: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Armah, A.K. [1968] 1988. The Beautyful Ones Are Not Yet Born. Johannesburg: Heinemann.

    Google Scholar 

  • Arrow, K.J. 1972. Gifts and Exchanges. Philosophy & Public Affairs 1 (4): 343–362.

    Google Scholar 

  • Banfield, E. 1958. The Moral Basis of a Backward Society. New York: Free Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bates, J. 2018. IHOP Apologizes for Waitress Who Asked Group of Black Teens to Pay Upfront. ABC News, March 18. https://abcnews.go.com/US/ihop-apologizes-waitress-asked-group-black-teens-pay/story?id=53739093

  • Becker, G.S. 1962. Irrational Behavior and Economic Theory. Journal of Political Economy 70 (1): 1–13.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • ———. [1957] 1971. The Economics of Discrimination: An Economic View of Racial Discrimination. Chicago and London: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Berggren, N., and H. Jordahl. 2006. Free to Trust: Economics Freedom and Social Capital. Kyklos 59 (2): 141–169.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Berggren, N., and T. Nilsson. 2013. Does Economic Freedom Foster Tolerance? Kyklos 66 (2): 177–207.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bicchieri, C. 2006. The Grammar of Society: The Nature and Dynamics of Social Norms. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bicchieri, C., and E. Xiao. 2009. Do the Right Thing: But Only If Others Do So. Journal of Behavioral Decision Making 22 (2): 191–208.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bill & Melinda Gates Foundation. 2018. Foundation Fact Sheet. https://www.gatesfoundation.org/Who-We-Are/General-Information/Foundation-Factsheet

  • Boettke, P.J. 2007. Deirdre McCloskey’s the Bourgeois Virtues: Ethics for an Age of Commerce. Economic Affairs 27 (1): 83–85.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Boren, C. 2014. Clippers Owner Donald Sterling Banned for Life from NBA. The Washington Post, April 29. https://www.washingtonpost.com/news/early-lead/wp/2014/04/29/clippers-owner-donald-sterling-banned-for-life-from-nba/?utm_term=.9d139a71c246

  • Boyle, R., and L.W. Kelly. 2012. The Television Entrepreneurs: Social Change and Public Understanding of Business. London/New York: Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Boyle, R., and M. Magor. 2008. A Nation of Entrepreneurs? Television, Social Change and the Rise of the Entrepreneur. International Journal of Media & Cultural Politics 4 (2): 125–144.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bloom, H. 1998. Shakespeare: The Invention of the Human. New York: The Berkley Publishing Group.

    Google Scholar 

  • Callon, M., and F. Muniesa. 2005. Peripheral Vision: Economic Markets as Calculative Collective Devices. Organization Studies 26 (8): 1229–1250.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Carden, A., and L. Verdon. 2010. When Is Corruption a Substitute for Economic Freedom? The Law and Development Review 3 (1): 40–63.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Carlyle, T. [1843] 2014. In The Selected Works of Thomas Carlyle, ed. F.R. Ludovico. Bibliotheca Cakravarti Foundation.

    Google Scholar 

  • Carnegie, A. [1889] 2006. In The “Gospel of Wealth” Essays and Other Writings, ed. D. Nasaw. New York: Penguin.

    Google Scholar 

  • Chafuen, A., and E. Guzmàn. 2000. Economic Freedom and Corruption. In 2000 Index of Economic Freedom, ed. G. O’Driscoll, K. Holmes, and M. Kirkpatrick, 51–63. Washington, DC: The Heritage Foundation.

    Google Scholar 

  • Charities Aid Foundation. 2016. CAF World Giving Index: A Global View of Giving Trends. https://www.cafonline.org/about-us/publications/2016-publications/caf-world-giving-index-2016

  • Charity Aid Foundation. 2017. CAF World Giving Index 2017: A Global View of Giving Trends. https://www.cafonline.org/docs/default-source/about-us-publications/cafworldgivingindex2017_2167a_web_210917.pdf?sfvrsn=ed1dac40_10

  • Charles, K.K., and J. Guryan. 2007. Prejudice and The Economics of Discrimination. NBER Working Paper, no. 13661.

    Google Scholar 

  • ———. 2008. Prejudice and Wages: An Empirical Assessment of Becker’s The Economics of Discrimination. Journal of Political Economy 116 (5): 773–809.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Choi, S.G., and V.H. Storr. 2017. Markets as Moral Training Grounds. In Annual Proceedings of the Wealth and Well-Being of Nations Volume IX, ed. W. Palmer. Wisconsin: Beloit College Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Conlin, M., M. Lynn, and T. O’Donoghue. 2003. The Norm of Restaurant Tipping. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization 52 (3): 297–321.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dahlgreen, W. 2016. Shakespeare 400 Years on: Every Play Ranked by Popularity. YouGov, April 22. https://yougov.co.uk/topics/lifestyle/articles-reports/2016/04/22/shakespeare-400

  • Davidson, J. 2015. The 10 Richest People of All Time. Money, July 30. http://money.com/money/3977798/the-10-richest-people-of-all-time-2/

  • Ellis, L., K.M. Beaver, and J. Wright. 2009. Handbook of Crime Correlates. Amsterdam: Academic Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ensminger, J. 2004. Market Integration and Fairness: Evidence from Ultimatum Dictator, and Public Good Experiments in East Africa. In Foundations of Human Sociality: Economic Experiments and Ethnographic Evidence from Fifteen Small-Scale Societies, ed. J. Henrich, R. Boyd, S. Bowles, C. Camerer, E. Fehr, and H. Gintis, 356–382. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Fehr, E., and J.A. List. 2004. The Hidden Costs and Returns of Incentives—Trust and Trustworthiness Among CEOs. Journal of the European Economic Association 2 (5): 743–771.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fehr, E., and U. Fischbacher. 2004a. Social Norms and Human Cooperation. Trends in Cognitive Sciences 8 (4): 185–190.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • ———. 2004b. Third-party Punishment and Social Norms. Evolution and Human Behavior 25 (2): 63–87.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fehr, E., and S. Gächter. 1999. Collective Action as a Social Exchange. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization 39 (4): 341–369.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ferguson, N. 2008. The Money-lender’s Plight. National Post, December 10. https://www.pressreader.com/canada/national-post-latest-edition/20081210/281908769002240

  • Fike, R. 2018. Impact of Economic Freedom and Women’s Well-Being. Vancouver: Fraser Institute.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fischbacher, U., S. Gächter, and E. Fehr. 2001. Are People Conditionally Cooperative? Evidence from a Public Goods Experiment. Economics Letters 71 (3): 397–404.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Forsythe, R., F.D. Nelson, G.R. Neumann, and J. Wright. 1992. Anatomy of an Experimental Political Stock Market. American Economic Review 82: 1142–1161.

    Google Scholar 

  • Forsythe, R., T.A. Rietz, and T.W. Ross. 1999. Wishes, Expectations and Actions: A Survey on Price Formation in Election Stock Markets. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization 39 (1): 83–110.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Freedman, L. 2009. The Narrative of Consumption: Greed and Literature. In Greed, ed. A. Brassey and S. Barber, 170–187. London: Palgrave Macmillan.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Friedman, D., and D. McNeill. 2013. Morals and Markets: The Dangerous Balance. New York: Springer.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Fukuyama, F. 1995. Trust: The Social Virtues and the Creation of Prosperity. New York: Free Press Paperbacks.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gode, D.K., and S. Sunder. 1993. Allocative Efficiency of Markets with Zero-Intelligence Traders: Market as a Partial Substitute for Individual Rationality. Journal of Political Economy 101 (1): 119–137.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Goel, R.K., and M.A. Nelson. 2005. Economic Freedom Versus Political Freedom: Cross-Country Influences on Corruption. Australian Economic Papers 44 (2): 121–133.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Graeff, P., and G. Mehlkop. 2003. The Impact of Economic Freedom on Corruption: Different Patterns for Rich and Poor Countries. European Journal of Political Economy 19 (3): 605–620.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Griswold, C.L., Jr. 1999. Adam Smith and the Virtues of Enlightenment. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gross, N. 1975. Economic History of the Jews. New York: Schocken Books.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gross, J. 1993. THEATER; Shylock and Nazi Propaganda. The New York Times, April 4. https://www.nytimes.com/1993/04/04/theater/theater-shylock-and-nazi-propaganda.html

  • Guiso, L., P. Sapienza, and L. Zingales. 2004. The Role of Social Capital in Financial Development. American Economic Review 94 (3): 526–556.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • ———. 2009. Cultural Biases in Economic Exchange? The Quarterly Journal of Economics 124 (3): 1095–1131.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Güliz, G., and R.W. Belk. 1996. Cross-cultural Differences in Materialism. Journal of Economic Psychology 17 (1): 55–77.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hanley, R.P. 2009. Adam Smith and the Character of Virtue. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Hartman, K.B. 2006. Television and Movie Representations of Salespeople: Beyond Willy Loman. The Journal of Personal Selling & Sales Management 26 (3): 283–292.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hayek, F.A. 1942. Scientism and the Study of Society. Part I. Economica 9 (35): 267–291.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Henrich, J., R. Boyd, S. Bowles, C. Camerer, E. Fehr, H. Gintis, and R. McElreath. 2001. In Search of Homo Economicus: Behavioral Experiments in 15 Small-Scale Societies. American Economic Review 91 (2): 73–78.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Henrich, J., R. Boyd, S. Bowles, C. Camerer, E. Fehr, and H. Gintis. 2004. Foundations of Human Sociality: Economics Experiments and Ethnographic Evidence from Fifteen Small Scale Societies. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Henrich, J., R. Boyd, S. Bowles, C. Camerer, E. Fehr, H. Gintis, R. McElreath, M. Alvard, A. Barr, J. Ensminger, N.S. Henrich, K. Hill, F. Gil-White, M. Gurven, F.W. Marlowe, J.Q. Patton, and D. Tracer. 2005. ‘Economic Man’ in Cross-cultural Perspective: Behavior Experiments in 15 Small Scale Societies. Behavioral and Brain Sciences 25 (6): 795–855.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Herrmann, B., C. Thöni, and S. Gächter. 2008. Antisocial Punishment Across Societies. Science 319 (5868): 1362–1367.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Herz, H., and D. Taubinsky. 2017. What Makes a Price Fair? An Experimental Study of Transaction Experience and Endogenous Fairness Views. Journal of the European Economic Association 16 (2): 316–352.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Higgins, T. 2017. George Soros Just Gave Almost 80 Percent of His Wealth to His Charity. CNBC, October 17. https://www.cnbc.com/2017/10/17/philanthropist-george-soros-donates-most-of-his-net-worth-to-charity.html

  • Hsu, T. 2019. Gillette Ad With a #MeToo Edge Attracts Support and Outrage. The New York Times, January 15. https://www.nytimes.com/2019/01/15/business/gillette-ad-men.html

  • Ikeda, S. 2018. The Nature and Limits of Gary Becker’s Theory of Racial Discrimination. The Review of Austrian Economics 31 (4): 403–417.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Inglehart, R., C. Haerpfer, A. Moreno, C. Welzel, K. Kizilova, J. Diez-Medrano, M. Lagos, P. Norris, E. Ponarin, B. Puranen, et al., eds. 2014. World Values Survey: Round Six-Country-Pooled Datafile Version. Madrid: JD Systems. www.worldvaluessurvey.org/WVSDocumentationWV6.jsp.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ingram, P., and P.W. Roberts. 2000. Friendships Among Competitors in the Sydney Hotel Industry. American Journal of Sociology 106 (2): 387–423.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Johnson, N.D., and A.A. Mislin. 2011. Trust Games: A Meta-analysis. Journal of Economic Psychology 32: 865–889.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kincaid, J. 1988. A Small Place. New York: Farrar Straus and Giroux.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kirzner, I.M. 1999. Creativity and/or Alertness: A Reconsideration of the Schumpeterian Entrepreneur. The Review of Austrian Economics 11 (1–2): 5–17.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Knack, S., and P. Keefer. 1997. Does Social Capital Have an Economic Payoff? A Cross-Country Investigation. The Quarterly Journal of Economics 112 (4): 1251–1288.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Koblin, J. 2018. After Racist Tweet, Roseanne Barr’s Show Is Canceled by ABC. New York Times, May 29. https://www.nytimes.com/2018/05/29/business/media/roseanne-barr-offensive-tweets.html

  • Krupka, E., and R.A. Weber. 2009. The Focusing and Informational Effects of Norms on Pro-social Behavior. Journal of Economic Psychology 30 (3): 307–320.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • La Porta, R., F. Lopez-de-Silanes, A. Shleifer, and R.W. Vishny. 1997. Trust in Large Organizations. American Economic Review 87 (2): 333–338.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lamming, G. 1970. In the Castle of My Skin. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Langrill, R., and V.H. Storr. 2012. The Moral Meaning of Markets. Journal of Markets and Morality 15 (2): 347–362.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lavoie, D., and E. Chamlee-Wright. 2000. Culture and Enterprise: The Development, Representation and Morality of Business. London/New York: Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lichter, S.F., L.S. Lichter, and S. Rothman. 1991. Watching America. Upper Saddle River: Prentice Hall.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lichter, S.F., L.S. Lichter, and A. Amundson. 1997. Does Hollywood Hate Business or Money? Journal of Communication 47 (1): 68–84.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Llosa, M.V. 2008. The War of the End of the World. London: Macmillan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mandeville, B. [1714, 1732] 1988. The Fable of the Bees or Private Vices, Publick Benefits. With Commentary by F.B. Kaye. Indianapolis: Liberty Fund.

    Google Scholar 

  • Marshall, R. 1974. The Economics of Racial Discrimination: A Survey. Journal of Economic Literature 12 (3): 849–871.

    Google Scholar 

  • Martin, N., and V.H. Storr. 2012. Talk Changes Things: The Implications of McCloskey’s Bourgeois Dignity for Historical Inquiry. The Journal of Socio-Economics 41 (6): 787–791.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Marx, K. [1821] 1994. Karl Marx: Selected Writings, ed. L.H. Simon. Indianapolis: Hackett Publishing.

    Google Scholar 

  • McCloskey, D.N. 1998. Bourgeois Virtues and the History of P and S. The Journal of Economic History 58 (2): 297–317.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • ———. 2003. Why Economists Should Not Be Ashamed of Being the Philosophers of Prudence. Eastern Economic Journal 28: 551–556.

    Google Scholar 

  • ———. 2006. The Bourgeois Virtues: Ethics for an Age of Commerce. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • ———. 2010. Bourgeois Dignity: Why Economics Can’t Explain the Modern World. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • ———. 2016. Bourgeois Equality: How Ideas, Not Capital or Institutions, Enriched the World. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mehta, J., C. Starmer, and R. Sugden. 1994. The Nature of Salience: An Experimental Investigation of Pure Coordination Games. American Economic Review 84 (3): 658–673.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mises, L. [1920] 1935. Economic Calculation in the Socialist Commonwealth. In Collectivist Economic Planning: Critical Studies on the Possibilities of Socialism by N.G. Pierson, Ludwig von Mises, Gerog Halm, and Enrico Barone, ed. F.A. Hayek, 87–130. London: Routledge & Kegan Paul Ltd.

    Google Scholar 

  • Misztal, B. 1996. Trust in Modern Societies: The Search for the Bases of Social Order. Cambridge: Polity Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mueller, J. 1999. Capitalism, Democracy, and Ralph’s Pretty Good Grocer. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Murphy, N. 2019. Gillette Advert Against ‘Toxic Masculinity’ Faces Backlash for ‘Attacking Men’. The Mirror, January 15. https://www.mirror.co.uk/news/us-news/gillette-advert-metoo-faces-backlash-13858189

  • Naughton, M. 2017. Practical Wisdom as the Sine Qua Non Virtue for the Business Leader. In Handbook of Virtue Ethics in Business and Management, ed. A.J.G. Sison, G.R. Beabout, and I. Ferrero. Amsterdam: Springer Netherlands.

    Google Scholar 

  • Nelson, D.M. 1992. The Priority of Prudence: Virtue and Natural Law in Thomas Aquinas and the Implications for Modern Ethics. University Park: Pennsylvania State University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Neumayer, E., and I. De Soysa. 2007. Globalisation, Women’s Economic Rights and Forced Labour. The World Economy 30 (10): 1510–1535.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • ———. 2011. Globalization and the Empowerment of Women: An Analysis of Spatial Dependence Via Trade and Foreign Direct Investment. The World Development 39 (7): 1065–1075.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Oliven, K., and T.A. Rietz. 2004. Suckers Are Born but Markets Are Made: Individual Rationality, Arbitrage, and Market Efficiency on an Electronic Futures Market. Management Science 50 (3): 336–351.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Page, R.A., S.K. Andoh, and R.A. Smith. 2017. Classical Literature Gives Life to Business Paradox and Systems Integration. Administrative Issues Journal 7 (2): 23–46.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Paldam, M. 2002. The Cross-country Pattern of Corruption: Economics, Culture and the Seesaw Dynamics. European Journal of Political Economy 18 (2): 215–240.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Plato. [350 BC] 1997. Plato: Complete Works. Translated by J.M. Cooper and D. S. Hutchinson, ed. Indianapolis: Hackett Publishing.

    Google Scholar 

  • Putnam, R.D. 1993. Making Democracy Work: Civic Traditions in Modern Italy. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • ———. 2000. Bowling Alone: The Collapse and Revival of American Community. New York/Philadelphia: Simon and Schuster.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ratnapala, S. 2003. Moral Capital and Commercial Society. The Independent Review 8 (2): 213–233.

    Google Scholar 

  • Russell, D.C. 2009. Practical Intelligence and the Virtues. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Sandel, M.J. 2012. What Money Can’t Buy: The Moral Limits of Markets. London: Macmillan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Schumpeter, J.A. [1911] 1983. The Theory of Economic Development: An Inquiry into Profits, Capital, Credit, Interest, and the Business Cycle. New Brunswick: Transaction Publishers.

    Google Scholar 

  • Scott, R. 2015. Which Companies Match Gifts Most? Forbes, May 21. https://www.forbes.com/sites/causeintegration/2015/05/21/which-companies-match-gifts-most/

  • Scott, E. 2018. The Most Powerful Brand in Sports Follows the Most Powerful Man in the World into the Anthem Protest Debate. The Washington Post, September 4. https://www.washingtonpost.com/politics/2018/09/04/most-powerful-brand-sports-follows-most-powerful-man-world-into-anthem-protest-debate/?utm_term=.f3a808578a22

  • Sen, A. 1986. Adam Smith’s Prudence. In Theory and Reality in Development, ed. S. Lall and F. Stewart, 28–37. London: Palgrave Macmillan.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Shakespeare, W. [1564–1616] 1994. The Merchant of Venice. London: Pearson Longman.

    Google Scholar 

  • Shang, J., and R. Croson. 2006. The Impact of Social Comparisons on Nonprofit Fund Raising. In Experiments Investigating Fundraising and Charitable Contributors, ed. R.M. Isaac and D.D. David, 143–156. Bingley: Emerald Group Publishing Limited.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Shen, C., and J.B. Williamson. 2005. Corruption, Democracy, Economic Freedom, and State Strength: A Cross-national Analysis. International Journal of Comparative Sociology 46 (4): 327–345.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shleifer, A., and R.W. Vishny. 1993. Corruption. The Quarterly Journal of Economics 108 (3): 599–617.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shugerman, E. 2018. David Hogg, Laura Ingraham Advertisers Dropped. Independent, March 30. https://www.independent.co.uk/news/world/americas/david-hogg-laura-ingraham-advertisers-drop-fox-news-show-hulu-tripadvisor-nestle-expedia-a8282101.html

  • Smith, A. [1776] 1981. An Inquiry into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations. Indianapolis: Liberty Fund.

    Google Scholar 

  • ———. [1759] 1982. The Theory of Moral Sentiments. Indianapolis: Liberty Fund.

    Google Scholar 

  • Solomon, R.C. 1992. Ethics and Excellence: Cooperation and Integrity in Business. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Storr, V.H. 2008. The Market as a Social Space: On the Meaningful Extraeconomic Conversations That Can Occur in Markets. The Review of Austrian Economics 2 (2–3): 135–150.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • ———. 2009. Why the Market? Markets as Social and Moral Spaces. Journal of Markets and Morality 12 (2): 277–296.

    Google Scholar 

  • Stroup, M.D. 2008. Separating the Influence of Capitalism and Democracy on Women’s Well-being. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization 67 (3–4): 560–572.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • ———. 2011. Does Economic Freedom Promote Women’s Well-being? In Economic Freedom of the World: 2011 Annual Report, ed. J.D. Gwartney, R. Lawson, and J.C. Hall. Vancouver: Fraser Institute.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sugden, R. 1995. A Theory of Focal Points. The Economic Journal 105 (430): 533–550.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tabellini, G. 2008. Institutions and Culture. Journal of the European Economic Association 6 (2–3): 255–294.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Teague, M., R. Fike, and V.H. Storr. 2018. Markets, Money and Materialism. Working Paper.

    Google Scholar 

  • The New York Times. 1937. Rockefeller Gifts Total $540,853,632. The New York Times, May 24. http://movies2.nytimes.com/books/98/05/17/specials/rockefeller-gifts.html

  • The Straits Times. 2018. Chow Yun Fat Vows to Donate Fortune After He Dies. The Strait Times, December 24. https://www.straitstimes.com/lifestyle/entertainment/chow-yun-fat-vows-to-donate-fortune-after-he-dies

  • Theberge, L.J., ed. 1981. Crooks, Conmen and Clowns: Businessmen on T.V. Entertainment. Washington, DC: The Media Institute.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tiffany, K. 2019. Why Gillette’s Toxic Masculinity Ad Is Annoying Both Sexists and Feminists. Vox, January 15. https://www.vox.com/the-goods/2019/1/15/18184072/gillette-toxic-masculinity-ad-super-bowl-feminism

  • Tracer, D.P. 2004. Market Integration, Reciprocity, and Fairness in Rural Papua New Guinea: Results from a Two-Village Ultimatum Game Experiment. In Foundations of Human Sociality: Economic Experiments and Ethnographic Evidence from Fifteen Small-Scale Societies, ed. J. Henrich, R. Boyd, S. Bowles, C. Camerer, E. Fehr, and H. Gintis, 232–259. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Transparency International. 2011. Corruption Perceptions Index 2011. Berlin: Transparency International. https://www.corruptionwatch.org.za/wp-content/uploads/migrated/Corruption-perecptions-index-2011-report_0.pdf.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tu, Q., and E. Bulte. 2010. Trust, Market Participation and Economics Outcomes: Evidence from Rural China. World Development 38 (8): 1179–1190.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • U.S. Trust. 2016. 2016 US Trust Insights on Wealth and Worth Survey: Key Findings. http://doingmorethatmatters.com/wp-content/uploads/2016/09/US_Trust-Wealth-and-Worth-Study-2016.pdf

  • Usbourne, S. 2015. The world’s Most Generous Billionaires: Mark Zuckerberg Isn’t the Only One to Give Away a Large Chunk of His Fortune. Independent, December 2. https://www.independent.co.uk/news/business/analysis-and-features/the-worlds-most-generous-billionaires-mark-zuckerberg-isnt-the-only-one-to-give-away-a-large-chunk-a6758066.html

  • Vásquez, I., and T. Porcnik. 2015. The Human Freedom Index: A Global Measurement of Personal, Civil, and Economic Freedom. Vancouver: Fraser Institute.

    Google Scholar 

  • Viganò, E. 2017a. Adam Smith’s Theory of Prudence Updated with Neuroscientific and Behavioral Evidence. Neuroethics 10 (2): 215–233.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • ———. 2017b. Not Just an Inferior Virtue, nor Self-Interest: Adam Smith on Prudence. Journal of Scottish Philosophy 15 (1): 125–143.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wang, A.B., and R. Siegel. 2018. Trump: Nike ‘Getting Absolutely Killed’ with Boycotts Over Colin Kaepernick’s ‘Just Do It’ Campaign. The Washington Post, September 5. https://www.washingtonpost.com/business/2018/09/04/people-are-destroying-their-nike-gear-protest-colin-kaepernicks-just-do-it-campaign/?utm_term=.535518198759

  • Williams, J. 2004. Entertaining the Nation: A Social History of British Television. Stroud: Sutton Publishing.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wilson, J.W. 1987. The Truly Disadvantaged: The Inner City, the Underclass, and Public Policy. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Yuengert, A. 2012. Approximating Prudence: Aristotelian Practical Wisdom and Economic Models of Choice. London: Palgrave Macmillan.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Zak, P. 2008. Moral Markets: The Critical Role of Values in the Economy. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Zak, P., and S. Knack. 2001. Trust and Growth. The Economic Journal 111 (470): 295–321.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2019 The Author(s)

About this chapter

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this chapter

Storr, V.H., Choi, G.S. (2019). Markets Are Moral Spaces. In: Do Markets Corrupt Our Morals?. Palgrave Macmillan, Cham. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-030-18416-2_5

Download citation

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-030-18416-2_5

  • Published:

  • Publisher Name: Palgrave Macmillan, Cham

  • Print ISBN: 978-3-030-18415-5

  • Online ISBN: 978-3-030-18416-2

  • eBook Packages: Economics and FinanceEconomics and Finance (R0)

Publish with us

Policies and ethics