Skip to main content

The Recent Growth Boom in Developing Economies: A Structural-Change Perspective

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
The Palgrave Handbook of Development Economics

Abstract

Growth has accelerated in a wide range of developing countries over the last couple of decades, resulting in an extraordinary period of convergence with the advanced economies. We analyze this experience from the lens of structural change—the reallocation of labor from low- to high-productivity sectors. Patterns of structural change differ greatly in the recent growth experience. In contrast to the East Asian experience, none of the recent growth accelerations in Latin America, Africa or South Asia was driven by rapid industrialization. Beyond that, we document that recent growth accelerations were based on either rapid within-sector labor productivity growth (Latin America) or growth-increasing structural change (Africa), but rarely both at the same time. The African experience is particularly intriguing, as growth-enhancing structural change appears to have come typically at the expense of declining labor productivity growth in the more modern sectors of the economy. We explain this anomaly by arguing that the forces that promoted structural change in Africa originated on the demand side, through either external transfers or increase in agricultural incomes. In contrast to Asia, structural change was the result of increased demand for goods and services produced in the modern sectors of the economy rather than productivity improvements in these sectors.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 189.00
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 249.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD 249.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    Lance Taylor, probably the most prominent modern-day structuralist, along with Ocampo and Rada analyzed these issues at length in their book Growth Policy in Developing Countries: A Structuralist Approach (2010).

  2. 2.

    See for example Klasen and Blades (2013).

  3. 3.

    Using LSMS-ISA data, McCullough (2015) finds that correcting for hours worked reduces the gap between labor productivity in agriculture and in other activities significantly, but she provides no explanation for the large difference between her results and the results of Gollin et al. (2014).

  4. 4.

    We use Africa in this chapter to refer to the 11 sub-Saharan African countries included in the GGDC Database.

  5. 5.

    Figure 9.1 excludes government services.

  6. 6.

    The RPA also fell in Nigeria, but this is driven solely by extremely high productivity in the oil sector without any meaningful structural changes.

  7. 7.

    Post-2014 data from WDI indicate that four of our African countries (MWI, NGA, ZAF and ZMB) have experienced either negative or almost zero growth rates on average during 2015–2016.

  8. 8.

    Data for per capita GDP in 2015–2016 are available in the WDI. Including 2015–2016 does not change the patterns revealed in the last column of Table 9.3. However, it is true that between 2014 and 2016, the growth rate was lower in some countries and turned negative in Argentina, Brazil, Malawi, Nigeria and South Africa.

  9. 9.

    The decomposition of structural change into agriculture and nonagriculture was not shown in Fig. 9.4.

  10. 10.

    Timmer et al. (2015) have pointed earlier that sectors that expanded their employment shares tended to have productivity growth rates below those of shrinking sectors over the 1990–2010 period. The same point is also made in starker form in the African context in de Vries et al. (2015).

  11. 11.

    The general case, but with homothetic preferences, is derived in a similar model in Dani Rodrik (2016). For the case of non-homothetic preferences, see Kiminori Matsuyama (1992). However, Matsuyama assumes the price elasticity of demand for manufacturing is unity, which implies that an increase in manufacturing productivity leaves manufacturing employment unchanged. Our assumption of price elastic demand for the modern good produces a different result, as explained in the text.

References

  • Aghion, P., & Howitt, P. (1992). A model of growth through creative destruction. Econometrica, 60(2), 323–351.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • de Vries, G. J., Timmer, M. P., & de Vries, K. (2015). Structural transformation in Africa: Static gains, dynamic losses. The Journal of Development Studies, 51(6), 674–688.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Diao, X., Harttgen, K., & McMillan, M. (2017). The changing structure of Africa’s economies. World Bank Economic Review, 31(2), 412–433. https://academic.oup.com/wber/article-lookup/doi/10.1093/wber/lhw070.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Duarte, M., & Restuccia, D. (2010). The role of the structural transformation in aggregate productivity. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 125(1), 129–173.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gollin, D., Lagakos, D., & Waugh, M. E. (2014). The agricultural productivity gap. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 129(2), 939–993.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Grossman, G. M., & Helpman, E. (1991). Innovation and growth in the global economy. Cambridge, MA: The MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hausmann, R., Pritchett, L., & Rodrik, D. (2005). Growth accelerations. Journal of Economic Growth, 10(4), 303–329.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jones, B. F., & Olken, B. A. (2008). The anatomy of start-stop growth. Review of Economics and Statistics, 90(3), 582–587.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Klasen, S., & Blades, D. (2013). Special issue: Measuring income, wealth, inequality, and poverty in sub Saharan Africa: Challenges, issues, and findings. Review of Income and Wealth, 59(s1), S1–S200.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kuznets, S. (1955). Economic growth and income inequality. American Economic Review, 45(March), 1–28.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lewis, A. W. (1954). Economic development with unlimited supplies of labor. The Manchester School, 22, 139–191.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Matsuyama, K. (1992). Agricultural productivity, comparative advantage, and economic growth. Journal of Economic Theory, 58, 317–334.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • McCullough, E. B. (2015). Labor productivity and employment gaps in sub-Saharan Africa. In World Bank policy research working paper 7234. Washington, DC: World Bank.

    Google Scholar 

  • McMillan, M., & Rodrik, D. (2011). Globalization, structural change, and productivity growth. NBER Working Paper 17143. Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of Economic Research.

    Google Scholar 

  • McMillan, M., Rodrik, D., & Sepulveda, C. (2017). Structural change, fundamentals, and growth: A framework and country studies. Washington, DC: International Food Policy Research Institute (forthcoming).

    Google Scholar 

  • Mundlak, Y., Butzer, R., & Larson, D. F. (2012). Heterogeneous technology and panel data: The case of the agricultural production function. Journal of Development Economics, 99(1), 139–149.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ocampo, J. A., Rada, C., & Taylor, L. (2009). Growth policy in developing countries: A structuralist approach. New York: Columbia University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Prebisch, R. (1950). The economic development of Latin America and its principal problems. Economic Commission for Latin America. New York: United Nations Department of Economic Affairs, Lake Success.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rodrik, D. (2014). The past, present, and future of economic growth. In Franklin Allen and others, Towards a better global economy: Policy implications for citizens worldwide in the 21st century. Oxford/New York: Oxford University Press.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rodrik, D. (2016, March). Premature deindustrialization. Journal of Economic Growth, 21(1), 1–33.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Singer, H. W. (1950, May). The distribution of gains between investing and borrowing countries. The American Economic Review, 40(2), 473–485.

    Google Scholar 

  • Solow, R. M. (1956). A contribution to the theory of economic growth. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 70(1), 65–94.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Timmer, M. P., & de Vries, G. J. (2007). A cross-country database for sectoral employment and productivity in Asia and Latin America, 1950–2005. Groningen growth and development centre research memorandum 98. Groningen: University of Groningen.

    Google Scholar 

  • Timmer, M. P., & de Vries, G. J. (2009). Structural change and growth accelerations in Asia and Latin America: A new Sectoral data set. Cliometrica, 3(2), 165–190.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Timmer, M. P., de Vries, G. J., & de Vries, K. (2015). Patterns of structural change in developing countries. In J. Weiss & M. Tribe (Eds.), Routledge handbook of industry and development (pp. 65–83). London: Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wei, S., & Zhang, X. (2011). Sex ratios, entrepreneurship and economic growth in the People’s Republic of China. NBER Working Paper 16800. Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of Economic Research.

    Google Scholar 

  • World Bank. (2017). World development indicators. Download of dataset from http://databank.worldbank.org/data/reports.aspx?source=world-development-indicators. Accessed 6 Jan 2017.

Download references

Acknowledgments

We acknowledge Peixun Fang for excellent research assistance. Diao and McMillan gratefully acknowledge the support of the CGIAR’s research program Policies, Institutions and Markets (PIM) led by the International Food Policy Research Institute. We also thank Jose Antonio Ocampo for helpful comments.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Dani Rodrik .

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

Appendix: Methodological Notes on Growth Decompositions

Appendix: Methodological Notes on Growth Decompositions

Equation (9.2) in Sect. 2indicates that the growth decomposition is an accounting exercise which can have various economic interpretations. Besides Eq. (9.2), there are a few different ways to decompose economywide labor productivity. In general, we are facing three sets of choices: (1) which weights to use, (2) whether to use annual data or simply period end points and (3) how to annualize the growth rates. While aggregate labor productivity growth rates are little affected by these choices, they could influence the magnitude of labor productivity growth rates within sector and from structural change. The difference in results among the three choices disappears only in the limit where the length of a period is infinitely short.

The following discussion explains how different choices could possibly affect the magnitude of growth in both the within and between components of the growth decomposition. A few examples based on the GGDC data are also provided. We then explain our preferred methodology for decomposing labor productivity growth into its within and between components.

Equation (9.6) is a starting point that describes a change in economywide labor productivity in a given period of (t-k, t) with k years:

$$ {y}^t-{y}^{t-k}=\varDelta {y}^t=\sum \limits_i{y}_i^t{\theta}_i^t-\sum \limits_i{y}_i^{t-k}{\theta}_i^{t-k} $$
(9.6)

where \( {y}^t \) and \( {y}^{t-k} \) are economywide labor productivity at time t and t-k respectively, \( {y}_i^t \) and \( {y}_i^{t-k} \) are sector i’s labor productivity at t and t-k, \( {\theta}_i^t=\frac{L_i^t}{L^t} \) and \( {\theta}_i^{t-k}=\frac{L_i^{t-k}}{L^{t-k}} \) are share of labor (L) employed in sector i at t and t-k, and \( t>k. \)

By rearranging (9.6), we can express the growth decomposition as

$$ \varDelta {y}^t=\sum \limits_i{\theta}_i^{t-k}\varDelta {y}_i^t+\sum \limits_i{y}_i^t\varDelta {\theta}_i^t $$
(9.7)

or

$$ \varDelta {y}^t=\sum \limits_i{\theta}_i^t\varDelta {y}_i^t+\sum \limits_i{y}_i^{t-k}\varDelta {\theta}_i^t $$
(9.8)

where \( \varDelta {y}_i^t={y}_i^t-{y}_i^{t-k} \) and \( \varDelta {\theta}_i^t={\theta}_i^t-{\theta}_i^{t-k}. \) Equation (9.7) is identical to Eq. (9.2) in Sect. 2 and is the version of the decomposition most commonly used in the literature (as in McMillan and Rodrik 2011, and de Vries et al. 2015).

In (9.7), weights in the “within term” are sectors’ labor shares at the beginning of the period (start-point weight) and weights in the “between term” are sectors’ labor productivity at the end of the period (end-point weight). In (9.8), weights are the opposite of those in (9.8), that is, the within term uses end-point weights and the between term uses start-point weights. Both \( \varDelta {y}_i^t \) and \( \varDelta {\theta}_i^t \) can be positive or negative for a given sector, while \( \sum \varDelta {\theta}_i^t=0. \)

Assuming \( \varDelta {y}_i^t\ne 0 \) and \( \varDelta {\theta}_i^t\ne 0, \) for a given sector i, there are four possibilities for combined \( \varDelta {y}_i^t \) and \( \varDelta {\theta}_i^t \) with different signs, that is, (a) \( \varDelta {y}_i^t>0 \) & \( \varDelta {\theta}_i^t<0, \) (b) \( \varDelta {y}_i^t>0 \) & \( \varDelta {\theta}_i^t>0, \) (c) \( \varDelta {y}_i^t<0 \) & \( \varDelta {\theta}_i^t>0, \) and (d) \( \varDelta {y}_i^t<0 \) & \( \varDelta {\theta}_i^t<0. \) Under different situations, the choice of the weights affects the magnitudes of the two components at the sector level. We consider each case below.

  • Case (a): \( {y}_i^t>{y}_i^{t-k} \) and \( {\theta}_i^t<{\theta}_i^{t-k}. \) This is commonly seen for i = agriculture among developing countries.

    In this case, sector i positively contributes to within-sector growth and negatively contributes to growth from structural change. Moreover, since \( {\theta}_i^{t-k}\varDelta {y}_i^t>{\theta}_i^t\varDelta {y}_i^t \) and \( \mid {y}_i^t\varDelta {\theta}_i^t\mid >\mid {y}_i^{t-k}\varDelta {\theta}_i^t\mid \), compared to Eq. (9.8), Eq. (9.7) could overstate the contribution of sector i’s (agricultural) within-sector productivity growth and hence also overstate the negative contribution of this sector to structural change.

  • Case (b): \( {y}_i^t>{y}_i^{t-k} \) and \( {\theta}_i^t>{\theta}_i^{t-k}. \) This is commonly seen among East Asian countries for i = manufacturing.

    In this case, \( {\theta}_i^{t-k}\varDelta {y}_i^t<{\theta}_i^t\varDelta {y}_i^t \) and \( {y}_i^t\varDelta {\theta}_i^t>{y}_i^{t-k}\varDelta {\theta}_i^t. \) Compared to Eq. (9.8), Eq. (9.7) could understate the contribution of sector i’s (manufacturing) within-sector productivity growth and overstate the contribution of this sector to structural change.

  • Case (c): \( {y}_i^t<{y}_i^{t-k} \) and \( {\theta}_i^t>{\theta}_i^{t-k}. \) We have seen this in this chapter in the case of African countries for many nonagricultural sectors.

    In this case, \( \varDelta {y}_i^t<0, \)\( \mid {\theta}_i^{t-k}\varDelta {y}_i^t\mid <\mid {\theta}_i^t\varDelta {y}_i^t\mid \), but \( {y}_i^t\varDelta {\theta}_i^t<{y}_i^{t-k}\varDelta {\theta}_i^t, \) which implies that Eq. (9.7) could understate both the negative contribution of sector i to within-sector productivity changes and its positive contribution from structural change in comparison with Eq. (9.8).

  • Case (d): \( {y}_i^t<{y}_i^{t-k} \) and \( {\theta}_i^t<{\theta}_i^{t-k}, \) which is a rare case, but we do see it in Hong Kong for the construction sector for the period 1990–2010 in the GGDC data.

    Because both \( \varDelta {y}_i^t<0 \) and \( \varDelta {\theta}_i^t<0 \), \( \mid {\theta}_i^{t-k}\varDelta {y}_i^t\mid >\mid {\theta}_i^t\varDelta {y}_i^t\mid \) and \( \mid {y}_i^t\varDelta {\theta}_i^t\mid <\mid {y}_i^{t-k}\varDelta {\theta}_i^t\mid, \) Eq. (9.7) could overstate sector i’s negative contribution within sector and understate the negative contribution to structural change in comparison with Eq. (9.8).

The discussion of these four cases is for individual sectors. There is never a situation where all sectors of a country follow a single case, and thus, combined effects across sectors often produce ambiguity. In general, there is less concern for which equation should be used when productivity gaps across sectors are small or changes in employment structure over time are modest. In the examples shown in Fig. 9.18, however, it is clear that the choice between these two equations affects the decomposition in the African and Latin American country groups significantly, while there is little effect for the high-income country group or for Asian countries.

Fig. 9.18
A double bar chart measures the values of minus 5 to 40 for high income, Asia, LAC, and Africa have 2 categories, within and between. Asia has the highest within data from the E q A 2 and E q A 3 at around 3.0, while Africa has the highest between data at 19.0 from the E q A 3.

Comparison of two methods in Eqs. (9.7) and (9.8) for labor productivity growth in 2000–2010 (percentages)

Source: Authors’ calculations using GGDC data

We have checked the robustness of the main findings discussed in the body of the chapter by comparing them with the results when we use Eq. (9.8) instead of Eq. (9.7). As expected, we get a somewhat different quantitative decomposition into the between and within terms. But we still have a negative correlation between the magnitudes of the within and between terms. In addition, Latin America’s growth acceleration is due overwhelmingly to the improvement in the within terms, while Africa’s is due to the between terms, as discussed.

The second and third choices related to the growth decomposition exercise are whether we just calculate changes in labor productivity growth within sector and from structural change in a given period (e.g., over ten years) as shown in Eq. (9.7) or (9.8), or whether we compute their annual growth rates. Reporting annual growth rates in labor productivity growth within sector and from structural change has the advantage that we can relate these to annual growth rates in GDP as we do in Table 9.4 of this chapter. A commonly used method is to first get the changes in within and between terms across sectors over an entire period, and then annualize them to get an average annual growth rate. This method is used by McMillan and Rodrik (2011) and de Vries et al. (2015). One advantage of this method is that we only need value added and employment data across sectors at two data points (two years). The disadvantage is that when time series data are available, this method simply ignores all the data between the initial and end points in a growth decomposition analysis. Again, when sectoral labor productivity and shares of employment do not fluctuate over time and follow a monotonic trend in growth (a trend either up or down) during the period in question, different methods of annualizing matter little. Indeed, we do not see much difference for the two different methods of annualizing the data for the high-income and Asian country groups, but there are some differences for African countries (Fig. 9.19).

Fig. 9.19
A stacked bar graph plots the values of minus 0.5 to 3.0 for Africa, B, L A C, India, and Asia with 2 conditions annualized for period growth and the average for year by year growth. Each country has 2 conditions for within and between.

Comparison of different approaches to annualize labor productivity growth rate in 2000–2010 (percentages). (Note: Equation (9.2) is used in both approaches)

Source: Authors’ calculations using GGDC data

In this chapter, we focus on recent growth accelerations in African and Latin American countries. Therefore, we decided to use a year-by-year calculation using the weights defined in Eq. (9.7) but to calculate each year’s growth rate for the within and between components at sector level across countries as follows:

$$ {g}_y^t=\sum \limits_i{\theta}_i^{t-1}{\pi}_i^{t-1}{g}_{y_i}^t+\sum \limits_i\varDelta {\theta}_i^t{\pi}_i^{t-1}\left(1+{g}_{y_i}^t\right). $$
(9.9)

where \( {g}_y^t=\frac{\varDelta {y}^t}{y^{t-1}}, \)\( {g}_{y_i}^t=\frac{\varDelta {y}_i^t}{y_i^{t-1}}, \) and \( {\pi}_i^t \) is relative labor productivity for sector i defined as \( {\pi}_i^t=\frac{y_i^t}{y^t}. \) We then calculate the average annual growth rates for the within and between terms in a given period (e.g., over ten years) for each sector by taking a simple average as follows:

$$ {\overline{g}}_i^{within}=\frac{1}{10}\sum \limits_{10}^{t=1}{\theta}_i^{t-1}{\pi}_i^{t-1}{g}_{y_i}^t $$

and

$$ {\overline{g}}_i^{between}=\frac{1}{10}\sum \limits_{10}^{t=1}\varDelta {\theta}_i^t{\pi}_i^{t-1}\left(1+{g}_{y_i}^t\right) $$

where \( {\overline{g}}_i^{within} \) and \( {\overline{g}}_i^{between} \) are the average labor productivity growth rates of sector i within sector and from structural change in a given ten-year period, and where both \( {\overline{g}}_i^{within} \) and \( {\overline{g}}_i^{between} \) are measured as fractions of the average annual growth rate of economywide labor productivity in this period. Thus, the annual economywide labor productivity growth rate and its two components in this given period are defined as follows:

$$ \overline{g}=\sum \limits_i{\overline{g}}_i^{within}+\sum \limits_i{\overline{g}}_i^{between} $$
(9.10)

Tables 9.9 and 9.10 present \( \overline{g}, \)\( \sum \limits_i{\overline{g}}_i^{within}, \) and \( \sum \limits_i{\overline{g}}_i^{between} \) at the country level, while the details for \( {\overline{g}}_i^{within} \) and \( {\overline{g}}_i^{between} \) at the sector level across countries can be obtained from the authors upon request.

Table 9.9 Labor productivity growth within sector and due to structural change, before and during growth accelerations—LAC, Africa and India (ten years in each period, annual average)
Table 9.10 Labor productivity growth within sector and due to structural change, before and during growth accelerations—Asia (ten years in each period, annual average)

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2019 The Author(s)

About this chapter

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this chapter

Diao, X., McMillan, M., Rodrik, D. (2019). The Recent Growth Boom in Developing Economies: A Structural-Change Perspective. In: Nissanke, M., Ocampo, J.A. (eds) The Palgrave Handbook of Development Economics. Palgrave Macmillan, Cham. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-030-14000-7_9

Download citation

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-030-14000-7_9

  • Published:

  • Publisher Name: Palgrave Macmillan, Cham

  • Print ISBN: 978-3-030-13999-5

  • Online ISBN: 978-3-030-14000-7

  • eBook Packages: Economics and FinanceEconomics and Finance (R0)

Publish with us

Policies and ethics