Skip to main content

The Emergence of Flexible Network Governance under the WTO Regime

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
Building Telecom Markets

Part of the book series: The Political Economy of the Asia Pacific ((PEAP))

  • 607 Accesses

Abstract

During the postliberalization process, flexible network governance emerged as an alternative model for steering the institutional arrangements that govern the market, while recurrent patterns of behavior in the market decreased. Centralized network governance in mobile telecommunications was no longer effective; greater flexibility was needed in working with the private sector in order to elicit its continued cooperation, coordinate efforts, and negotiate interests. As competition among incumbent players grew and advanced mobile technology (e.g., IMT-2000) appeared, flexible network governance emerged. The mobile industry’s competitive crisis, under the WTO regime, and the selection of the 3G technology standard are described as manifestations of the change toward flexible network governance. This study also focuses on the processes in which the interests of the state and private actors were structured in the mobile market and on how these interests and the relationship between them changed with liberal market development and the advancement of technology.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 84.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 109.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD 109.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    The U.S. government is able to take disciplinary actions, including the levying of retaliatory tariffs and a ban on the purchase of telecom equipment from Korea, unless an agreement with Korea is reached within 1 year after its designation of Korea as a PFC.

  2. 2.

    Interview in 2001. In the early negotiations that ended in 1992, the United States brought the government procurement code onto the agenda and partially succeeded in imposing nondiscriminatory concessions on government procurement. Since then, Korea and the U.S. government have conducted annual meetings to observe agreements.

  3. 3.

    The Reference Paper deals with the prevention of anti-competitive behavior, nondiscriminatory interconnection, nondiscriminatory universal service obligations, transparent licensing processes, and independent regulatory institutions (Takigawa 1998: 45).

  4. 4.

    International trade in telecommunications takes two forms (Blouin 2000: 136): cross-border supply and commercial presence. Cross-border trade (i.e., international phone calls) is the most important mode of international transaction in telecommunications services. The second form of telecommunications services trade is through foreign investment to provide commercial investment to establish a commercial presence.

  5. 5.

    In the WTO, the MIC stressed the importance of conflict resolution in trade through multilateral rules. Dispute Settlement Understanding in the WTO gave the MIC new leverage over the United States and other countries in trade disputes.

  6. 6.

    Interview in 2001.

  7. 7.

    This is not to say that technology caused either the deregulation or the ministry’s reorganization. The digital technology provided the technical possibility for the crisis of the existing telecom regime. Actors’ decisions, as influenced by the prevailing regime, played a more determinant role.

  8. 8.

    Interview in 2001.

  9. 9.

    In Europe, the term Personal Communication Network (PCN) was coined for a system that was foreseen to bring universal mobility in communications. In contrast to Europe, the United States chose to use the term Personal Communication Service (PCS) to address the new technological concept. Similar to PCN, PCS was expected to be independent of local wired telephone networks, filling gaps in existing communication services and creating new markets.

  10. 10.

    Interview in 2002.

  11. 11.

    Telecommunications manufacturing in Korea had been carried out by chaebols. Since the early 1990s, the government encouraged them to specialize in self-chosen areas. Four chaebols (Daewoo, Hyundai, LG Group, and Samsung) chose to focus their activities in the telecommunications equipment and operator markets. Korean chaebols jointly developed the TDX public switching and CDMA mobile digital technologies in the late 1980s and early 1990s, respectively.

  12. 12.

    In 1995, chaebols accounted for 16 percent of Korean GNP (Chang 2001: 8).

  13. 13.

    KT, the primary operator in Korea, has faced international long-distance competition since DACOM entered the market in 1991.

  14. 14.

    Remember that KT used to own a public mobile carrier, KMT, and had sold it to the SK Group in 1993. KT still had 13.4 percent ownership in SKT as of April 2001.

  15. 15.

    The license allocated in Hansol was subsequently purchased in 2000 by KTF under the name KTF.

  16. 16.

    By the end of 1997, LG Group had 55 sister companies with around 300 offices and subsidiaries in 120 countries. LGIC manufactured a wide range of telecommunications equipment in its divisions, such as mobile communications systems, including CDMA, PCS, and WLL, terminals and customer support equipment, switching and transmission systems, and information systems.

  17. 17.

    LGT had 366,045 subscribers by the end of 1997, which had grown to about two million by the end of 1998. The company launched a CDMA wireless data access service in March 1998.

  18. 18.

    Given that SKT and Shinsegi were authorized to provide all types of cellular services, both firms were allowed by the government to provide PCS services. For example, SKT received 10 MHz of the higher-frequency spectrum to launch PCS services in 1997, with a network trial system in 1996. Initially, SKT tried to use PCS in urban areas and exploit the doubling of total frequency allocation (i.e., 10 MHz at each 800 MHz and 1.8 MHz) to raise capacity.

  19. 19.

    This is based on the exchange rate of U.S.$1 = KW 1,000.

  20. 20.

    The government abolished handset subsidies in June 2000. One of the reasons for this was to address the deteriorating balance of trade payments since domestic handset makers use a significant percentage of imported components from Japan and the United States.

  21. 21.

    With the tremendous amount of subsidies, the service companies were running at a loss. Between 1997 and 2000, service providers had maintained a 30–50 percent subsidy of their total sale. The subsidy was prohibited in 2000.

  22. 22.

    SKT used Samsung, Lucent, and LG Electronics for its 2G service. Meanwhile, KTF used Samsung, Lucent, and Hynix (previously Hyundai Electronics) for its IS-95B equipment. On the other hand, LGT has mainly used LE Electronics’ equipment for both 2G services.

  23. 23.

    Interconnection issues for mobile cellular refer to the technical, financial, and commercial arrangements for connecting mobile networks to fixed-line as well as other mobile cellular networks. Interconnection payments form a large portion of a mobile company’s operating costs. The arrangements for interconnection pricing affect the relative amounts that fixed-line and mobile operators share. For example, SKT’s cellular network connects with PSTN networks such as Korea Telecom and Hanaro Telecom. These networks are connected to the international gateways of Korea Telecom, Onse Telecom, and DACOM. Interconnection revenues arose when KT or other mobile companies paid SKT for calls made between the PSTN and cellular networks as well as between the cellular networks.

  24. 24.

    Interview with an expert in a company in 2001.

  25. 25.

    This is based on the average exchange rate of U.S.$1 = KW 1,270 in 2001.

  26. 26.

    For a more detailed explanation of the transition of interconnection charges, refer to Hwang (1999: 322–328).

  27. 27.

    Interconnection between mobile networks (mobile-to-mobile, M–M calls) is typically less of an issue than between mobile and fixed operators (L–M or M–L calls). Interconnection pricing between two different mobile networks is often based on the sender-keeps-all principle.

  28. 28.

    According to the 1997 plan, SKT received 65 percent of the charge made by the fixed operator to its customer. For PCS operators, the rate was set at 70 percent. For SKT, traffic coming in from the fixed-line network netted the company around KW 94 per minute, 65 percent of the KW 144 charged to the fixed-line customer. For a call from SKT going into the fixed network, SKT paid around KW 10.5 per minute (SKT, internal document).

  29. 29.

    This is based on the SKT internal report “The Transition of Interconnection Charges” (2001).

  30. 30.

    According to the ministerial order, a provider with more than 30 percent market share was subject to the MIC’s approval (Hwang 1999: 108–109). This decision resulted in tariff regulation only on KT in wired service (local, long-distance, and international telephone) and SKT in the wireless market.

  31. 31.

    Although the development of digital technology sparked the transformation of the industry and its governing regime, it would be a mistake to argue that the technological advancements were the only cause of the ensuing changes in governance.

  32. 32.

    For an assessment of the WTO agreement on telecommunications services, refer to Fredebeul-Krein and Freytag (1997).

  33. 33.

    Before 1997, every telecom service carrier, including mobile carriers, had no alternative but to rely on KT’s local network to reach telephone end users. This made it possible to prevent possible abuses and anti-competitive behavior of other carriers by using its exclusive position as the owner of the network.

  34. 34.

    Under the Subsidies Agreement in the WTO, a subsidy was prohibited if it was contingent on export performance (export subsidies) or on the use of domestic over imported goods (import substitution subsidies) (http://www.wto.org, “WTO subsidies agreement”).

  35. 35.

    Under the agreement, actions can only be taken against subsidies that are “specific.” A specific subsidy is one that is only given to one company, or to a special group of companies. Hence, if the government does not designate a special industry or firm, the problem of “specificity” does not occur.

  36. 36.

    The restriction on foreign ownership was based on the Foreign Capital Inducement Act, which was under the jurisdiction of the MOFE.

  37. 37.

    The IMF memorandum deals with three major areas: macroeconomic policy, financial sector restructuring, and corporate sector restructuring. The final section postulates liberalization of trade and capital, restructuring corporate governance, labor market reform, and enhancement of transparency of the government’s economic data.

  38. 38.

    Debt-to-equity ratios for major chaebols reached an average of 300 percent in 1996 (The Weekly Chosun, January 1, 1998:98–99).

  39. 39.

    Interview in 2001.

  40. 40.

    This liberalization commitment is offered to all service providers from any member nation of the WTO on a nondiscriminatory basis. The Most Favored Nations (MFN) rule in the WTO requires a country to offer the same level of benefits to all members of the WTO (Choi and Lee 2000). However, MFN does not forbid countries from undertaking competition policy measures whose practical impact may vary from carrier to carrier.

  41. 41.

    In 2001, the foreign share limit on telecom service providers, such as SKT, was capped at 49 percent. In August 2001, the foreign ownership of SKT was 46.5 percent.

  42. 42.

    In addition to offering cellular and iridium global mobile satellite services, SKT launched the 011 wireless data service in August 1998 and the 011 Cybernet service in April 1999. This allowed Internet and email access via the cellular handset. The company inaugurated its NETSGO multimedia online service with Internet access in August 1998. SK formed a new subsidiary, SK Telelink, in June 1998, which began offering international phone service in that year. In partnership with AT&T, MCI WorldCom, and KDD, SK Telelink claimed to offer international services up to 64 percent cheaper than those of other operators in Korea (http://www.sktelelcom.co.kr).

  43. 43.

    Packet-based technologies are superior to circuit-switched networks for data transmission, as they offer always-on, spectrum-efficient, and higher-speed mobile connectivity.

  44. 44.

    The transmission speed of the earlier IS-95A service was 9.6–28 kbps, but this speed went up to 14.4–64 kbps with the IS-95B service, and to 144 kbps with the IS-95C service. IS-95C allowed higher graphics content, with color LCD screens available, as well as higher transmission speed.

  45. 45.

    The dial-up industry includes Chollian (DACOM), Edunet, Hitel, Nownuri (Thrunet), Unitel, and Netsgo. Netsgo, part of SKT, has been competing not just with other ISP carriers such as Chollian and Unitel but also against pure portals such as Daum and Yahoo! The intense competition and lack of growth in this market resulted in poor business prospects, largely as a result of the huge migration of customers to broadband service.

  46. 46.

    SKT, for example, positioned the mobile commerce card as an all-purpose card for use in conducting financial transactions and serving as an ID, transportation, and medical card. SKT entered into an alliance with leading financial companies, including Korea Exchange Bank, LG Capital, and Samsung Card, to provide mobile commerce card services. The mobile commerce card has greater transaction storage capacity than the current magnetic-strip cards. SKT subscribers were able to use their handsets for mobile commerce more efficiently with the card.

  47. 47.

    WAP (Wireless Application Protocol) is a license-free protocol for wireless communications that enables the creation of mobile telephone services and the reading of Internet pages from a mobile phone. It was first developed by Ericsson, Motorola, and Nokia (ITU 1999: 28).

  48. 48.

    In June 1999, for example, LGT introduced its EZ Internet service, based on the WAP platform, providing Web Personal Information Manager (PIM) services and allowing users to access Internet Web sites using its WAP phones.

  49. 49.

    This is based on the exchange rate of U.S.$1 = KW 1,160 in 1999.

  50. 50.

    As of June 2000, SKT had taken a 52.6 percent stake in Shinsegi Telecom. Vodafone was the next-largest shareholder, with an 11.7 percent stake. Other minority shareholders of Shinsegi included Samsung SDI, LG Electronics, and Qualcomm.

  51. 51.

    The Fair Trade Commission officially approved the acquisition of Shinsegi, on condition that the combined market share of SKT and Shinsegi would be lowered to below 50 percent by June 2001. This was the condition recommended to the FTC by the MIC in 2000. Failure to meet this condition would result in a maximum fine of KW 11.3 billion (about U.S.$1 million) per day until the condition was met.

  52. 52.

    The OECD reported that telecom carriers’ revenues increased 20.44 percent annually between 1992 and 1997. In 1997, 38.35 percent of total revenues were from the mobile sector (OECD 1999).

  53. 53.

    In the past, chaebols’ financial position and importance in the Korean economy forced the Korean state “into the role of lender of last resort” for the financial problems of the chaebols because the bankruptcy of a chaebol “would threaten not only the financial but the economic stability of the country” (Woo-Cumings 1991: 149).

  54. 54.

    The process of licensing 3G service was first published in an article, “Political Economy of IMT-2000 Technology Standard Disputes” (Jho 2003b).

  55. 55.

    SKT and its subsidiary invested KW 985.2 billion in March 2001 for a 61.6 percent stake in SKT-IMT2000.

  56. 56.

    In the paired two-way spectrum, W-CDMA would be used to provide wide-area cellular coverage and high-mobility services. In the one-way unpaired spectrum, TD-CDMA would be used to provide low-mobility, local, and in-building types of services. Ericsson and Nokia developed the W-CDMA standard and are its main proponents, while Alcatel, Siemens, and Nortel are the main supporters of TD-CDMA. The two groups agreed that they would not be able to come to a consensus without compromise and have formed an alliance proposing their joint recommendation via the ETSI to the ITU. Although these five firms were the main proponents of the two different technologies, the consensus decision was based on a proposal submitted by a larger group of manufacturers, including Bosch, Italtel, Motorola, and Sony.

  57. 57.

    As WTO agreements were finalized in 1997, it was difficult for the government to mandate a technology standard because of possible conflicts with other countries.

  58. 58.

    Interview in 2002.

  59. 59.

    In wireless telecommunications equipment, Korean companies production and design of CDMA Samsung achieved the top position in the worldwide CDMA market accounting for more than 50 percent of market share. In the combined market of CDMA and GSM of 2002, Samsung ranked 4th in worldwide phone sales (Lee and Lee 2004). By 2003, Korea had become a market leader in the CDMA telecom markets.

  60. 60.

    Meanwhile, LGIC [LG Information and Communications, later LG Electronics (LGE)], which boosted research efforts on W-CDMA, tried to persuade the MIC and telecom carriers to adopt the W-CDMA technology.

  61. 61.

    Manufacturers, in general, did not want to take a strong public position that could jeopardize their existing and future business relationships in domestic and international markets. However, potential opportunities for manufacturers in Asian and American markets affected a country’s choice of standard. It was clear that Samsung had a good presence in the CDMA market, exporting CDMA handsets and networks to 2G international markets. The technology standard in the Korean 3G market had important implications for other countries that were the main targets for Korean manufacturers. Samsung and LGIC wanted to expand their share of the growing Asian market with China’s potential market.

  62. 62.

    The strain between SKT and KT was acute; each company tried to force the other to take CDMA2000. In an interview in 2000, a high-level official in KT said, “Should at least one company need to adopt CDMA2000 for the sake of national interest, it should be the one that has the most extensive infrastructure in the CDMA technology and that has more than 50 percent share of the mobile telecom [market],” in a clear reference to SKT. An official at SKT stated, “As far as technology standards are concerned, we are firm on W-CDMA. If the government needs to have a company adopting CDMA2000, it should use a state-owned company, meaning Korean Telecom” (interview in 2000).

  63. 63.

    Interviews in 2002.

  64. 64.

    For example, as of September 2000, Japan Telecom, NTT DoCoMo in Japan, Suomen 2G, Alands Mobiltelefon in Finland, BT Cellnet, Vodafone in the United Kingdom, TIM, Andala Hutchison, Wind in Italy, and Airtel in Spain have chosen W-CDMA as their technology standard for 3G services (Ericsson Korea Ltd. 2000: 518).

  65. 65.

    A fourth-generation telecommunications standard would be ten times faster and offer an even richer variety of wireless multimedia services than the current third-generation service. The technology would promise a data transmission speed of up to 20 Mbps, a speed at which services comparable to those on a standard PC can be provided. Under the proposed plan, the biggest steps are the introduction of unified mobile phone handsets that incorporate existing multiple standards. The government and the industry plan to introduce so-called multimode handsets that would enable consumers to use all radio frequencies with a single handset. For this service, network operators and equipment makers would have to adhere to a code of conduct setting common standards in such areas as batteries, antennas, and handsets.

  66. 66.

    Interviews in 2002.

  67. 67.

    For example, Telecel, a mobile operator in Zambia, converted its network from CDMA to GSM primarily because roaming was constricted, since all its neighbors were using the latter system.

  68. 68.

    The revenues of the Korean mobile service companies are based on domestic subscribers in the market. Since they compete with each other to increase market share in the same Korean market, the Korean companies are threatened more by competition from their Korean rivals than from Western companies. The general pattern has been for Korean companies threatened by Korean rivals to form alliances with them. Forming alliances with foreign firms gave critical opportunities for the Korean firms to increase their subscriber base into the foreign market and thus increase their stock value.

  69. 69.

    Interview in 2002.

  70. 70.

    Interview in 2002.

  71. 71.

    Interview in 2002.

  72. 72.

    Interview in 2002.

  73. 73.

    Although Hanaro desired to enter the 3G market with the CDMA2000 standard, it was generally agreed that it was not capable of pursuing its business in terms of technological capability and network operation experience.

  74. 74.

    SKT merged with Shinsegi. SKT’s acquisition of Shinsegi Telecom served as the impetus for KTF to take over Hansol, which had problems of inferior subscriber quality and weak growth potential. KTF also merged with Hansol PCS in 2001 and moved from a disunified mobile system to what might be referred to as a duopoly. As a result, two vertically integrated telecom companies came to control the front market of mobile communications.

  75. 75.

    Interview in 2002.

  76. 76.

    The LG consortium, which was led mainly by LG Telecom, had a total of 1,049 companies, including Hanaro Telecom, Powercom, Thrunet, and 15 other operators, mobile handset makers and equipment manufacturers, such as LGE, Sewon Telecom, Hyundai Syscom, and Kisan Telecom, wireless content and Internet firms, distribution firms, network builders, and business base builders. In the end, SKT and KT opted for W-CDMA, while LG alone took up CDMA2000.

  77. 77.

    Statistic was released by the Bank of Korea, accessed through the government website (http://www.itstat.go.kr).

  78. 78.

    In January 2005, KT, SKT, and Hanaro Telecom were selected as the WiBro providers; however, Hanaro Telecom returned the license and therefore only KT and SKT provided the WiBro service. In October 2005, KT utilized the WiBro system established in Seoul to simultaneously provide high-speed Internet, broadcasting, and Internet phone services.

  79. 79.

    In the United States, although research-focused agencies (NIH, NASA) exist, there is no central government department that is in charge of the R&D budget, and it is formulated based on a bottom-up structure.

  80. 80.

    According to a Financial News article that included an interview with an anonymous former high-ranking official of the Korean Communications Commission, WiBro technology development was meant not to promote domestic service but to increase exports of related equipment and cell phones to the overseas market.

  81. 81.

    The contents were researched and organized based on KCC (2010b).

  82. 82.

    The user agreement approval system had been introduced to prevent unfair telecommunication service fees or conditions from being implemented by a dominant market provider and to protect the telecommunication service user because of the nature of the telecommunications industry, which makes it easy for oligopolies to be created. In addition, the service fees and conditions in the user agreements must be decided according to the existing Telecommunications Business Law, and this user agreement needed to be reported to the commission.

  83. 83.

    However, there were benefits such as paying only the production costs of the network in regard to interconnection and facility provision payments.

  84. 84.

    Wholesale provision is a policy that induces the key telecommunications service providers to provide their own telecommunications services or partially or fully support the facilities needed to provide the service when requested by another telecommunications service provider.

  85. 85.

    A set of “pro-competitive principles” in the WTO created obligations for how national regulators would protect new entrants from anti-competitive behavior by incumbents with dominant market power.

References

  • Ahn S-k (2009) An analysis of performance and growth success factors of national R&D projects: focused on the next generation growth engine program. KISTEP, Seoul

    Google Scholar 

  • Anchordoguy M (2000) Japan’s software industry: a failure of institutions? Res Pol 29(3):391–480

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Antonelli C (1997) Technological change and multinational growth in international telecommunications services. In: Noam EM, Wolfson AJ (eds) Globalism and localism in telecommunications. Elsevier, Amsterdam, pp 269–288

    Google Scholar 

  • Archibugi D, Michie J (eds) (1997) Technology, globalization and economic performance. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Bedell P (1999) Wireless crash course. McGraw-Hill, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Best M (1990) The new competition. Polity Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Bianchi P, Labory S (2006) From ‘Old’ industry policy to ‘New’ industrial development policies. In: Bianchi P, Labory S (eds) International handbook on industrial policy. Edward Elgar, Northampton, MA, pp 3–27

    Google Scholar 

  • Bickers KN (1991) Transformation in the governance of the American telecommunications industry. In: Campbell JL, Rogers Hollingsworth J, Lindberg LN (eds) Governance of the American Economy, vol 5. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, pp 77–107

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Blouin C (2000) The WTO agreement on basic telecommunications: a reevaluation. Telecomm Pol 24(2):135–142

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Campbell JL, Rogers Hollingsworth J, Lindberg LN (eds) (1991) Governance of the American economy, vol 5. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Chang D-J (2001) “Corporate Governance” (in Korean). Unpublished paper presented at the conference on business environment and management strategy in the 21st Century

    Google Scholar 

  • Cho S, Choi S-K, Kim Y-K (1995) “Development of Telecommunications Market Structure for Global Market” (in Korean). KISDI, Seoul (95–3)

    Google Scholar 

  • Choi B-I, Lee G-S (2000) A comprehensive analysis of major trade issues and multilateral agreements in telecommunication (in Korean). Research Institute of Information Society, Seoul

    Google Scholar 

  • Chu Y-W (2009) Eclipse or reconfigured? South Korea’s developmental state and challenges of the global knowledge economy. Econ Soc 38(2):278–303

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Council for IMT-2000 Technology Standard (CITS) (2000) Final report of commission for IMT-2000 technology standard (in Korean). CITS, Seoul

    Google Scholar 

  • Electronics and Telecommunications Research Institute (ETRI) (2001) IMT-2000: report on technology and market (in Korean). Electronics and Telecommunications Research Institute, Seoul

    Google Scholar 

  • Ericsson Korea Ltd (2000) Prospect on IMT-2000 technology. In: Council for IMT-2000 Technology Standard (CITS) (ed) Final report of commission for IMT-2000 technology standard (in Korean). CITS, Seoul, pp 509–529

    Google Scholar 

  • Forge S, Bohlin E (2008) Managed innovation in Korea in telecommunication: moving towards 4G mobile at a national level. Telematics and Informatics 25(4):292–309

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fredebeul-Krein M, Freytag A (1997) Telecommunications and WTO discipline. Telecomm Pol 21(6):477–491

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gandal N (2002) Compatibility, standardization and network effects: some policy implications. Oxf Rev Econ Pol 18(1):80–91

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Goto A, Wakasugi R (1988) Technology policy. In: Komiya R, Okuno M, Suzumura K (eds) Industrial policy in Japan. Academic Press, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Hana Finance Institute (2010) Overview of telecommunication market. Hana Financial Group, Seoul

    Google Scholar 

  • Hayashi S (2010) The developmental state in the Era of globalization: beyond the Northeast Asian model of political economy. Pac Rev 23(1):45–69

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hills J (1986) Deregulating telecoms: competition and control in the United States, Japan, and Western Europe. Cornell University Press, Ithaca, NY

    Google Scholar 

  • Hwang C-J (1999) Understanding of Korean telecommunications law and policy (in Korean). Kyobo-Mungo, Seoul

    Google Scholar 

  • Hwang C-S (2003) “Information Policy Structure and Issue of Korea” (in Korean). Korean Telecomm Pol Rev 10(2):99–120

    Google Scholar 

  • International Telecommunications Union (ITU) (1999) World telecommunications development report: mobile cellular. International Telecommunications Union, Geneva

    Google Scholar 

  • Jayasuriya K (2001) Globalization and the changing architecture of the state: the regulatory state and the politics of negative co-ordination. J Eur Publ Pol 8(1):101–123

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jordana J, Sancho D (2005) Policy network and market opening: telecommunications liberalization in Spain. Eur J Polit Res 44(4):519–546

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Keil T (2002) De-facto standardization through alliance: lessons from Bluetooth. Telecomm Pol 26(3–4):205–213

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kim D-Y (2002) The politics of market liberalization: a comparative study of the South Korean and Philippine telecommunication service industries. Contemp Southeast Asia 24(2):337–370

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kim H-K (2008) “The Changing Politics of Government Regulatory Bodies: Case Analysis on Korea Communications Commission” (in Korean). In: Proceedings of the 2008 KAPA winter conference, Korean Association for Public Administration, Seoul, pp 1–22

    Google Scholar 

  • KISTEP (2008) “The Characteristics of R&D Budget Process in the United States and Its Implications” (in Korean). KISTEP R&D Focus 5:1–28

    Google Scholar 

  • Korea Communications Commission (KCC) (2009) In: Proceedings of the 52nd Korean communications commission conference, Korean Communications Commission, Seoul 30 Oct 2009

    Google Scholar 

  • Korea Communications Commission (KCC) (2010a) In: Proceedings of the 6th Korean communications commission conference, Korean Communications Commission, Seoul, 9 Feb 2010

    Google Scholar 

  • Korea Communications Commission (KCC) (2010b) Annual report 2010. Korean Communications Commission, Seoul

    Google Scholar 

  • Korea Communications Commission (KCC) (2011) In: Proceedings of the 73rd Korean communications commission conference, Korean Communications Commission, Seoul, 16 Dec 2011

    Google Scholar 

  • Korea Information Society Development Institute (KISDI) (1999) “A General Survey of Telecommunication Services” (in Korean). Korea Information Society Development Institute, Seoul

    Google Scholar 

  • Korea Information Society Development Institute (KISDI) (2001) A study on policy frameworks for wireless and data service (in Korean). Korea Information Society Development Institute, Seoul

    Google Scholar 

  • Korea Information Society Development Institute (KISDI) (2011) A study on the promotion policy of Wipro service in Korea mobile market (in Korean). Korea Information Society Development Institute, Seoul

    Google Scholar 

  • Kramer R, NiShúilleabháin A (1997) Investment drivers for global telecommunications: investment structure and structural trends in multinational services. In: Noam EM, Wolfson AJ (eds) Globalism and localism in telecommunications. Elsevier, Oxford, pp 257–268

    Google Scholar 

  • Kurisaki Y (1997) The globalism of public telecommunications operators—toward a new framework of telecommunications policy. In: Noam EM, Wolfson AJ (eds) Globalism and localism in telecommunications. Elsevier, Oxford, pp 361–373

    Google Scholar 

  • Lee J-H, Park K-D (2011) “East Asia’s Liberalization on Telecommunications Markets and Its Market Competition Models” (in Korean). Korean Pol Stud Rev 20(2):383–410

    Google Scholar 

  • Lee SH, Yoo T (2007) Government policy and trajectories of radical innovation in dirigiste states: a comparative analysis of national innovation systems in France and Korea. Technol Anal Strateg Manag 19(4):451–470

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lynn L (1982) How Japan innovates: a comparison with the US in the area of oxygen steelmaking. Westview Press, Boulder, CO

    Google Scholar 

  • Merrill L (1997) The Asia-pacific phone book, first quarter review. Merrill Lynch, New York, pp 103–104

    Google Scholar 

  • Ministry of Information and Communications (MIC) (1995) “Method for Requesting a License in Facility-Based Service Providers” (in Korean). Ministry of Information and Communications, Republic of Korea, Seoul

    Google Scholar 

  • Ministry of Information and Communications (MIC) (1998) Annual report (in Korean). Ministry of Information and Communications, Republic of Korea, Seoul

    Google Scholar 

  • Ministry of Information and Communications (MIC) (2000a) 2000 statistical indicators on telecommunications (in Korean). Ministry of Information and Communications, Republic of Korea, Seoul

    Google Scholar 

  • Ministry of Information and Communications (MIC) (2000b) Annual report on electronic communications (in Korean). Ministry of Information and Communications, Republic of Korea, Seoul

    Google Scholar 

  • Ministry of Information and Communications (MIC) (2000c) Policy direction for 2GHz IMT-2000 operator selection procedure (in Korean). MIC and ETRI: the second public hearing on IMT-2000 operator selection procedure (July 6)

    Google Scholar 

  • Ministry of Information and Communications (MIC) (2007) ICT standardization annual report (in Korean). Ministry of Information and Communications, Republic of Korea, Seoul

    Google Scholar 

  • Muramatsu M (1991) MPT and telecommunications innovation. In: Wilks S, Wright M (eds) The promotion and regulation of industry in Japan. St. Martin’s Press, New York, pp 286–308

    Google Scholar 

  • Nelson R, Winter S (1982) An evolutionary theory of economic change. Harvard University Press, Cambridge, MA

    Google Scholar 

  • Nelson R, Wright G (1992) The rise and fall of American technological leadership: the postwar Era in historical perspective. J Econ Lit 30(4):1931–1964

    Google Scholar 

  • Noam EM (1994) Beyond liberalization: from the network of networks to the system of systems. Telecomm Pol 18(4):286–294

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development (OECD) (1999) Communications outlook 1999. Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development, Paris

    Google Scholar 

  • Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development (OECD) (2000) Regulatory reform in Korea. OECD review of regulatory reform. Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development, Paris

    Google Scholar 

  • Park J-W (2000) “A Study on the Effect of Side Payment in the Mobile Telecom Market” (in Korean). Korean Acad Soc Ind Organ 7(2):1–35

    Google Scholar 

  • Perez C (1983) Structural change and the assimilation of new technologies in the economic and social system. Futures 15(5):357–375

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Powell WW (2001) Patterns in western enterprise. In: DiMaggio P (ed) The twenty-first century firm: changing economic organization in international perspective. Princeton University Press, Princeton, NJ, pp 33–68

    Google Scholar 

  • Rosenau JN (1995) Governance in the 21st century. Global Govern 1(1):13–43

    Google Scholar 

  • Roth A, Singh S (2000) Doomed telecommunications mergers: the emergence of a two-tiered industry structure. Monitor company white paper, Monitor Company Group, Cambridge, MA

    Google Scholar 

  • Samuels RJ (1987) The business of the Japanese state: energy markets in comparative and historical perspective. Cornell University Press, Ithaca, NY

    Google Scholar 

  • Seok W-H, Lee K-S, Song Y-K (2011) “Current Status and Prospect of WiBro Market” (in Korean). Electron Telecomm Trend 26(4):165–174

    Google Scholar 

  • Shin J-S, Chang H-J (2003) Restructuring Korea Inc. Routledge, London

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Smith PL, Staple G (1994) Telecommunications sector reform in Asia: toward a new pragmatism. World Bank Discussion Papers 232. The World Bank, Washington, DC, pp 26–29

    Google Scholar 

  • Strange S (1996) The retreat of the state. Cambridge University Press, New York

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Strange S (1998) States and markets. Continuum, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Streeck W, Schmitter PC (eds) (1985) Private interest government: beyond market and state. Sage Publications, Beverly Hills, CA

    Google Scholar 

  • Sung K-J (1997a) “Agreement on the Basic Telecommunications in WTO and Consolidation of Domestic Institutions in Korea” (in Korean). MIC, Research Assignment for Telecommunications, Seoul

    Google Scholar 

  • Sung L (1997b) Standards competition in wireless: regionalism vs. globalism, the case of the third generation mobile communications systems. In: Noam EM, Wolfson AJ (eds) Globalism and localism in telecommunications. Elsevier, Amsterdam, pp 323–341

    Google Scholar 

  • Takigawa T (1998) The impact of the WTO telecommunications agreement on US and Japanese telecommunications regulations. J World Trade 32(6):33–55

    Google Scholar 

  • Telecommunications Technology Association (TTA) (2008) The handbook of ICT standardization. TTA, Kyonggi

    Google Scholar 

  • Thatcher M (2002) Analyzing regulatory reform in Europe. J Eur Publ Pol 9(6):859–872

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Vogel SK (1996) Freer markets, more rules: regulatory reform in advanced industrial countries. Cornell University Press, Ithaca, NY

    Google Scholar 

  • Weiss L (2000) Developmental state in transition: adapting, dismantling, innovating, and normalizing. Pac Rev 13(1):21–55

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wilks S, Wright M (eds) (1991) The promotion and regulation of industry in Japan. St. Martin’s Press, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Williamson O (1985) The economic institutions of capitalism. Free Press, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Winters J (1996) Power in motion. Cornell University Press, Ithaca, NY

    Google Scholar 

  • Winters J (1999) The determinants of financial crisis in Asia. In: Pempel TJ (ed) The politics of the Asian economic crisis. Cornell University Press, Ithaca, NY, pp 79–100

    Google Scholar 

  • Woo-Cumings M (Jung-en) (1991) Race to the swift: STATE and finance in Korean industrialization. Columbial University Press, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Zysman J (1983) Governments, markets, and growth. Cornell University Press, Ithaca, NY

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2014 Springer Science+Business Media New York

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Jho, W. (2014). The Emergence of Flexible Network Governance under the WTO Regime. In: Building Telecom Markets. The Political Economy of the Asia Pacific. Springer, New York, NY. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-1-4614-7888-1_6

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics