Skip to main content

Incentive and Strategic Contracting: Implications for the Franchise Decision

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
Game Theory and Business Applications

Abstract

We examine theoretical predictions and econometric evidence concerning franchise contracting and sales-force compensation and discuss a number of factors that ought to influence the contracts that are written between principals and agents. For each factor, we construct the simplest theoretical model that captures what we view as its essence. The comparative statics from the theoretical exercise are then used to organize our discussion of the empirical evidence, where the evidence is taken from published studies that have attempted to assess each factor’s effect on the power of agent incentives. We also discuss theoretical issues and empirical results pertaining to a few topics that have been addressed in the literature but that do not fit easily into our simple modeling framework. Finally, we discuss a few recent models with endogenous prices. Unfortunately, the evidence that relates to strategic or game-theoretic agency models is scanty. Nevertheless, we discuss the findings from the few relevant studies that we have been able to uncover.

*This chapter is a revised and updated version of Lafontaine and Slade (2001), which was entitled “Incentive Contracting and the Franchise Decision” published in the earlier edition of this volume. This revision builds on some of our recent work, most notably Lafontaine and Slade (2007 and 2012).

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 129.00
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 169.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD 169.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

References

  • Ackerberg, D., & Botticini, M. (2002). Endogenous matching and the empirical deter- minants of contract form. Journal of Political Economy, 110, 564–591.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Affuso, L. (2002). An empirical study on contractual heterogeneity within the firm: The ‘Vertical Integration Franchise Contracts’ mix. Applied Economics, 34, 931–944.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Agrawal, D., & Lal, R. (1995). Contractual arrangements in franchising: An empirical investigation. Journal of Marketing Research, 32, 213–221.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Alchian, A. A., & Demsetz, H. (1972). Production, information costs, and economic organization. American Economic Review, 62, 777–795.

    Google Scholar 

  • Allen, D. W., & Lueck, D. (1992). Contract choice in modern agriculture: Cropshare versus cash rent. Journal of Law and Economics, 35, 397–426.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Allen, D. W., & Lueck, D. (1995). Risk preferences and the economics of contracts. American Economic Review, 85, 447–451.

    Google Scholar 

  • Anderson, E. (1985). The salesperson as outside agent or employee: A transaction cost analysis. Marketing Science, 4, 234–254.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Anderson, E., & Oliver, R. L. (1987). Perspectives on behavior-based versus outcome-based salesforce-control systems. Journal of Marketing, 51, 76–88.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Anderson, E., & Schmittlein, D. (1984). Integration of the sales force: An empirical examination. Rand Journal of Economics, 15, 385–395.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Argyres, N., & Bercovitz, J. (2011). The impacts of efficiency and bargaining power on contract structure: Evidence from franchising. Working paper, University of Washington, St. Louis.

    Google Scholar 

  • Arruñada, B., Garicano, L., & Vázquez, L. (2001). Contractual allocation of decision rights and incentives: The case of automobile distribution. Journal of Law, Economics and Organization, 15, 56–73.

    Google Scholar 

  • Athey, S., & Stern, S. (1998) An empirical framework for testing theories about complementarities in organizational design NBER Working Paper 6600, http://kuznets.fas.harvard.edu/~athey/testcomp0498.pdf

  • Barron, J. M., & Umbeck, J. R. (1984). The effects of different contractual arrangements: The case of retail gasoline. Journal of Law and Economics, 27, 313–328.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Berto Villas-Boas, S. (2007). Vertical relationships between manufacturers and retailers: Inference with limited data. Review of Economic Studies, 74, 625–652.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bhattacharyya, S., & Lafontaine, F. (1995). Double-sided moral hazard and the nature of share contracts. RAND Journal of Economics, 26, 761–781.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Blair, R. D., & Kaserman, D. L. (1994). A note on incentive incompatibility under franchising. Review of Industrial Organization, 9, 323–330.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Blair, R. D., & Lafontaine, F. (1999). Will Khan foster or hinder franchising? An economic analysis of maximum resale price maintenance. Journal of Public Policy in Marketing, 18, 25–36.

    Google Scholar 

  • Blair, R. D., & Lafontaine, F. (2005). The economics of franchising. New York: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Blass, A., & Carlton, D. W. (2001). The choice of organizational form in gasoline retailing and the cost of laws that limit that choice. Journal of Law and Economics, 44, 511–524.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bonanno, G., & Vickers, J. (1988). Vertical separation. Journal of Industrial Economics, 36, 257–266.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bonnet, C., & Dubois, P. (2008). Inference on vertical contracts between manufacturers and retailers allowing for nonlinear pricing and resale price main- tenance. RAND Journal of Economics, 41, 139–164.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bradach, J. L. (1997). Using the plural form in the management of restaurant chains. Administrative Science Quarterly, 42, 276–303.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brenkers, R., & Verboven, F. (2006). Liberalizing a distribution system: The European car market. Journal of the European Economic Association, 4, 216–251.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brickley, J. A. (1999). Incentive conflicts and contractual restraints: Evidence from franchising. Journal of Law and Economics, 37, 745–774.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brickley, J. A. (2002). Royalty rates and upfront fees in share contracts: Evidence from franchising. Journal of Law, Economics and Organization, 18, 511–535.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brickley, J., & Dark, F. (1987). The choice of organizational form: The case of franchising. Journal of Financial Economics, 18, 401–420.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brickley, J. A., Dark, F. H., & Weisbach, M. S. (1991). An agency perspective on franchising. Financial Management, 20, 27–35.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Carmichael, H. L. (1983). The agent-agents problem: Payment by relative output. Journal of Labor Economics, 1, 50–65.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Carney, M., & Gedajlovic, E. (1991). Vertical integration in franchise systems: Agency theory and resource explanations. Strategic Management Journal, 12, 607–629.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Caves, R. E., & Murphy, W. F. (1976). Franchising: Firms, markets, and intangible assets. Southern Economic Journal, 42, 572–586.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Coase, R. (1937). The nature of the firm. Economica, 4, 386–405.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Coughlan, A. T. (1985). Competition and cooperation in marketing channel choice: theory and application. Marketing Science, 4, 110–129.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Coughlan, A. T., & Narasimhan, C. (1992). An empirical analysis of sales-force compensation plans. Journal of Business, 65, 93–121.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Crocker, K. J., & Masten, S. E. (1996). Regulation and administered contracts revisited: Lessons from transaction-cost economics for public utility regulation. Journal of Regulatory Economics, 9, 5–39.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Crocker, K. J., & Reynolds, K. J. (1992). The efficiency of incomplete contracts: An empirical analysis of air force engine procurement. RAND Journal of Economics, 24, 126–146.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dant, R. P., Kaufmann, P. J., & Paswan, A. K. (1992). Ownership redirection in franchised channels. Journal of Public Policy and Marketing, 11, 33–44.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dnes, A. W. (1992). Franchising: A case-study approach. Aldershot: Ashgate Publishing.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dnes, A. W. (1993). A case study analysis of franchise contracts. Journal of Legal Studies, 22, 367–393.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Emerson, R. W. (2011). Discriminating between members of the same network: American statutes and cases mimeo. Gainesville: University of Florida.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gal-Or, E. (1995). Maintaining quality standards in franchise chains. Management Science, 41, 1774–1792.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gagné, R., Sigué, S. P., & Zaccour, G. (1998). Droit d’entrée et taux de redevance dans les franchises d’exploitation au Québec. L’Actualité économique, 74, 651–668.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Garen, J. E. (1994). Executive compensation and principal-agent theory. Journal of Political Economy, 102, 1175–1199.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Godes, D. (2004). Contracting under endogenous risk. Quantitative Marketing and Economics, 2, 321–345.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Grossman, S. J., & Hart, O. D. (1986). The costs and benefits of ownership: A theory of vertical and lateral integration. Journal of Political Economy, 94, 691–719.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hart, O. D., & Moore, J. (1990). Property rights and the nature of the firm. Journal of Political Economy, 98, 1119–1158.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Holmstrom, B. (1979). Moral hazard and observability. Bell Journal of Economics, 10, 74–91.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Holmstrom, B. (1982). Moral hazard in teams. Bell Journal of Economics, 13, 324–340.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Holmstrom, B., & Milgrom, P. (1987). Aggregation and linearity in the provision of intertemporal incentives. Econometrica, 55, 303–328.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Holmstrom, B., & Milgrom, P. (1991). Multitask principal-agent analyses: Incentive contracts, asset ownership, and job design. Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization, 7, 24–51.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Holmstrom, B., & Milgrom, P. (1994). The frm as an incentive system. American Economic Review, 84, 972–991.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ichniowski, C., Shaw, K. L., & Prennushi, G. (1997). The effects of human resource management practices on productivity: evidence from the steel industry. American Economic Review, 87, 291–313.

    Google Scholar 

  • Jensen, M., & Murphy, K. (1990). Performance pay and top-management Incentives. Journal of Political Economy, 98, 225–264.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • John, G., & Weitz, B. A. (1988). Forward integration into distribution: an empirical test of transaction cost analysis. Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization, 4, 337–355.

    Google Scholar 

  • John, G. & Weitz, B. (1989). Salesforce Compensation: An Empirical Investigation of Factors Related to Use of Salary Versus Incentive Compensation, Journal of Marketing Research, 26, 1–14

    Google Scholar 

  • Joseph, K., & Kalwani, M. U. (1995). The impact of environmental uncertainty on the design of sales force compensation plans. Marketing Letters, 6, 183–197.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Joskow, P. (1988). Asset specificity and the structure of vertical relationships: Empirical evidence. Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization, 4, 95–117.

    Google Scholar 

  • Joskow, P. (2010). Vertical integration, aymposium in honor of oliver williamson. Antitrust Bulletin, 55(3), 545–586.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kalnins, A. (2004). Hamburger prices and spatial econometrics. Journal of Economics and Management Strategy, 12, 591–616.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kalnins, A., & Lafontaine, F. (2004). Multi-unit ownership in franchising: Evidence from the fast-food industry in Texas. RAND Journal of Economics, 35, 747–761.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kaplan, S. N. (1994). Top executive rewards and firm performance: A comparison of Japan and the U.S. Journal of Political Economy, 102, 510–546.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kaufmann, P. J. (1999). Franchising and the choice of self-employment. Journal of Business Venturing, 14, 345–362.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kaufmann, P. J., & Lafontaine, F. (1994). Costs of control: The source of economic rents for McDonald’s franchisees. Journal of Law and Economics, 37, 417–543.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kehoe, M. R. (1996). Franchising, agency problems, and the cost of capital. Applied Economics, 28, 1485–1493.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Klein, B. (1980). Transaction cost determinants of ‘Unfair’ contractual arrangements. American Economic Review, 70, 356–362.

    Google Scholar 

  • Klein, B. (1988). Vertical integration as organizational ownership: The fisher body – general motors relationship revisited. Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization, 4, 199–213.

    Google Scholar 

  • Klein, B. (1995). The economics of franchise contracts. Journal of Corporate Finance, 2, 9–37.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Klein, B., Crawford, R., & Alchian, A. (1978). Vertical integration, appropriable rents, and the competitive contracting process. Journal of Law and Economics, 21, 297–326.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Knight, F. (1921). Risk, uncertainty, and profit. Chicago: Houghton Mifflin.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kosová, R., & Lafontaine, F. (2012). Much ado about chains: A research agenda. International Journal of Industrial Organization, 30, 303–308.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lafontaine, F. (1992). Agency theory and franchising: Some empirical results. RAND Journal of Economics, 23, 263–283.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lafontaine, F. (1993). Contractual arrangements as signaling devices: Evidence from franchising. Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization, 9, 256–289.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lafontaine, F., & Bhattacharyya, S. (1995). The role of risk in franchising. Journal of Corporate Finance, 2, 39–74.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lafontaine, F., & Oxley, J. E. (2004). International franchising practices in Mexico: Do franchisors customize their contracts? Journal of Economics and Management Strategy, 13, 95–123.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lafontaine, F., & Raynaud, E. (2002). Residual claims and self enforcement as incentive mechanisms in franchise contracts: Substitute or complements. In E. Brousseau, & Glachant, J. M. (Eds.), The economics of contract in prospect and retrospect. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, UK.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lafontaine, F., & Shaw, K. L. (1999). The dynamics of franchise contracting: Evidence from panel data. Journal of Political Economy, 107, 1041–1080.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lafontaine, F., & Shaw, K. L. (2005). Targeting managerial control: Evidence from franchising. RAND Journal of Economics, 36, 131–150.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lafontaine, F., & Sivadasan, J. (2009). Within-firm labor productivity across countries: A case study. In R. Freeman & K. L. Shaw (Eds.), International differences in the business practices and productivity of multinational firms: A case-based approach (pp. 137–172). Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Lafontaine, F., & Slade, M. E. (1996). Retail contracting and costly monitoring: Theory and evidence. European Economic Review Papers and Proceedings, 40, 923–932.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lafontaine, F., & Slade, M. (2001). Incentive contracting and the franchising decision. In K. Chatterjee & W. Samuelson (Eds.), Game theory and business applications (Firstth ed., pp. 133–188). Boston: Kluwer Academic.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lafontaine, F., & Slade, M. (2007). Vertical integration and firm boundaries: The evidence. Journal of Economic Literature, 45, 629–685.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lafontaine, F., & Slade, M. (2012). Inter-firm contracts: The evidence. In R. Gibbons & J. Roberts (Eds.), Handbook of organizational economics. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lal, R. (1990). Improving channel coordination through franchising. Marketing Science, 9, 299–318.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lazear, E. P. (1996). Performance pay and productivity. NBER Working paper #5672.

    Google Scholar 

  • Leegin Creative Leather Products, Inc. v. PSKS, Inc., 551 U.S. 877 (2007).

    Google Scholar 

  • Leffler, K. B., & Rucker, R. R. (1991). Transaction costs and the efficient organization of production: A study of timber-harvesting contracts. Journal of Political Economy, 99, 1060–1087.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lin, S. F., Thomas, C., & Kalnins, A. (2011). In-house and arm’s length: Productivity heterogeneity and variation in organizational form. New York: Mimeo, Columbia U.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lo, D., Ghosh, M., & Lafontaine, F. (2011). The incentive and selection roles of salesforce compensation contracts. Journal of Marketing Research, 48, 781–798.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lutz, N. A. (1995). Ownership rights and incentives in franchising. Journal of Corporate Finance, 2, 103–130.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Macher, J. T., & Richman, B. D. (2008). Transaction cost economics: An assessment of empirical research in the social sciences. Business and Politics, 10, 1–63.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Maness, R. (1996). Incomplete contracts and the choice between vertical integration and franchising. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 31, 101–115.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Martin, R. E. (1988). Franchising and risk management. American Economic Review, 78, 954–968.

    Google Scholar 

  • Maruyama, M., & Yamashita, Y. (2010). The logic of franchise contracts: Em- pirical results for Japan. Japan and the World Economy, 22, 183–192.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Masten, S. E. (1984). The organization of production: Evidence from the aerospace industry. Journal of Law and Economics, 27, 403–417.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mathewson, F., & Winter, R. (1985). The economics of franchise contracts. Journal of Law and Economics, 28, 503–526.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mathewson, F., & Winter, R. (1994). Territorial restrictions in franchise contracts. Economic Inquiry, 32, 181–192.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mazzeo, M. (2004). Retail contracting and organizational form: Alternatives to chain affiliation in the motel industry. Journal of Economics and Manage-ment Strategy, 13, 599–615.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • McAfee, R. P., & Schwartz, M. (1994). Multilateral vertical contracting: Opportunism, nondiscrimination, and exclusivity. American Economic Review, 84, 210–230.

    Google Scholar 

  • McGuire, T. W., & Staelin, R. (1983). An industry equilibrium analysis of downstream vertical integration. Marketing Science, 2, 161–192.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Michael, S. C., & Moore, H. J. (1995). Returns to franchising. Journal of Corporate Finance, 2, 133–156.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Milgrom, P., & Roberts, J. (1992). Economics organization and management. Englewoods Cliffs: Prentice-Hall.

    Google Scholar 

  • Minkler, A. (1990). An empirical analysis of a firm’s decision to franchise. Economics Letters, 34, 77–82.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Minkler, A., & Park, T. A. (1994). Asset specificity and vertical integration. Review of Industrial Organization, 9, 409–423.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mirrlees, J. A. (1976). The optimal structure of incentives and authority within an organization. Bell Journal of Economics, 7, 105–131.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Monteverde, K., & Teece, D. (1982). Supplier switching costs and vertical integration in the automobile industry. Bell Journal of Economics, 13, 206–213.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Muris, T. J., Scheffman, D. T., & Spiller, P. T. (1992). Strategy and transaction costs: The organization of distribution in the carbonated soft drink industry. Journal of Economics and Management Strategy, 1, 83–128.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Murphy, K. (1984). Incentives, learning, and compensation: A theoretical and empirical investigation of managerial labor contracts. RAND Journal of Economics, 17, 59–76.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Norton, S. W. (1988). An empirical look at franchising as an organizational form. Journal of Business, 61, 197–217.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pénard, T., Raynaud, E., & Saussier, S. (2003). Franchise mix as a stable organization form? An empirical analysis using french data. Journal of Marketing Channel, 10(3/4), 5–32.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pinkse, J., & Slade, M. E. (1998). Contracting in space: An application of spatial statistics to discrete-choice models. Journal of Econometrics, 85, 125–154.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Prendergast, C. (2002). The tenuous trade-off between risk and incentives. Journal of Political Economy, 110(5), 1071–1102.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rao, R. C., & Srinivasan, S. (1995). Why are royalty rates higher in service-type franchises. Journal of Economics and Management Strategy, 4, 7–31.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rey, P., & Stiglitz, J. (1995). The role of exclusive territories in producers’ competition. RAND Journal of Economics, 26, 431–451.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rindfleisch, A., & Heide, J. B. (1997). Transaction cost analysis: Past, present and future applications. Journal of Marketing, 61, 30–54.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Romano, R. E. (1994). Double moral hazard and resale price maintenance. RAND Journal of Economics, 25, 455–466.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rubin, P. (1978). The theory of the firm and the structure of the franchise contract. Journal of Law and Economics, 21, 223–233.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Scott, F. A. (1995). Franchising vs. company ownership as a decision variable of the firm. Review of Industrial Organization, 10, 69–81.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sen, K. C. (1993). The use of initial fees and royalties in business format franchising. Managerial and Decision Economics, 14, 175–190.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shelanski, H. A., & Klein, P. G. (1995). Empirical research in transaction cost economics: A review and assessment. Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization, 11, 335–361.

    Google Scholar 

  • Shepard, A. (1993). Contractual form, retail price, and asset characteristics. Rand Journal of Economics, 24, 58–77.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Slade, M. E. (1996). Multitask agency and contract choice: An empirical assessment. International Economic Review, 37, 465–486.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Slade, M. E. (1998). Strategic motives for vertical separation: Evidence from retail gasoline. Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization, 14, 84–113.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Smith, R. L., II. (1982). Franchise regulation: An economic analysis of state restrictions on automobile distribution. Journal of Law and Economics, 25, 125–157.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • State Oil Co. v. Khan, 522 u.s. 3(1997).

    Google Scholar 

  • Stiglitz, J. E. (1974). Incentives and risk-sharing in sharecropping. Review of Economic Studies, 41, 219–255.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Thompson, R. S. (1994). The franchise life cycle and the penrose effect. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 24, 207–218.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Umanath, N. S., Ray, M. R., & Campbell, T. L. (1993). The impact of perceived environmental uncertainty and perceived agent effectiveness on the composition of compensation contracts. Management Science, 39, 32–45.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • U.S. Department of Commerce (1998). Franchising in the economy, 1986–1988, prepared by Andrew Kostecka.

    Google Scholar 

  • Vazquez, L. (2005). Up-front franchise fees and ongoing variable payments as substitutes: An agency perspective. Review of Industrial Organization, 26, 445–460.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Vickers, J. (1985). Delegation and the theory of the firm. Economic Journal, 95, 138–147.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Williams, D. L. (1998). Why do entrepreneurs become franchisees? An empirical analysis of organizational choice. Journal of Business Venturing, 14, 103–124.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Williamson, O. E. (1971). The vertical integration of production: Market failure considerations. American Economic Review, 61, 112–123.

    Google Scholar 

  • Williamson, O. E. (1979). Transaction cost economics: The governance of contractual relations. Journal of Law and Economics, 22, 233–262.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Williamson, O. E. (1983). Credible commitments: Using hostages to support exchange. American Economic Review, 73, 519–540.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wimmer, B. S., & Garen, J. E. (1997). Moral hazard, asset specificity, implicit bonding, and compensation: The case of franchising. Economic Inquiry, 35, 544–554.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zanarone, G. (2009). Vertical restraints and the law: Evidence from automobile franchising. Journal of Law and Economics, 52, 691–700.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Francine Lafontaine .

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

Algebraic Derivations

Algebraic Derivations

In each case below, the agent (A) maximizes his certainty-equivalent income, \( E(y)-(r/2)Var(y) \), whereas the principal (P) maximizes the expected total surplus—expected output minus the agent’s cost of effort minus the agent’s risk premium—\( E(q)-{a^2}/2-(r/2)Var(y) \). With one exception, noted below, the agent’s compensation is given by \( S(q)=\alpha q+W \). The cases differ according to the specification of the function that maps effort into output, \( q=f(a,\varepsilon, \Theta ) \).

1.1 Risk

$$ q=a+\varepsilon . $$
$$ A:\quad \mathop{\max}\limits_a \left[ {\alpha a+W-\frac{{{a^2}}}{2}-\frac{r}{2}{\alpha^2}{\sigma^2}} \right]. $$

The resulting first-order condition (foc) is: a = α. Substituting the agent’s effort choice into the principal’s problem yields:

$$ P:\quad \mathop{\max}\limits_{\alpha } \left[ {\alpha -\frac{{{\alpha^2}}}{2}-\frac{r}{2}{\alpha^2}{\sigma^2}} \right], foc: 1-\alpha -r\alpha {\sigma^2}=0, $$
$$ {\alpha^{*}}=\frac{1}{{1+r{\sigma^2}}}, $$
$$ \frac{{d{\alpha^{*}}}}{dr }=-\frac{{{\sigma^2}}}{{{\Gamma^2}}}<0, \frac{{d{\alpha^{*}}}}{{d{\sigma^2}}}=-\frac{r}{{{\Gamma^2}}}<0,\;\;\;\mathrm{where}\;\;\;\Gamma =1+r{\sigma^2}. $$

1.2 Agent Effort

$$ q=\eta a+\varepsilon . $$
$$ A:\quad \mathop{\max}\limits_a \left[ {\alpha \eta a+W-\frac{{{a^2}}}{2}-\frac{r}{2}{\alpha^2}{\sigma^2}} \right], foc: a=\alpha \eta . $$
$$ P:\quad \mathop{\max}\limits_{\alpha } \left[ {{\eta^2}\alpha -\frac{{{\alpha^2}{\eta^2}}}{2}-\frac{r}{2}{\alpha^2}{\sigma^2}} \right], foc: {\eta^2}-\alpha {\eta^2}-r\alpha {\sigma^2}=0, $$
$$ {\alpha^{*}}=\frac{{{\eta^2}}}{{{\eta^2}+r{\sigma^2}}}, $$
$$ \frac{{d{\alpha^{*}}}}{{d\eta }}=\frac{{2\eta r{\sigma^2}}}{{{\Gamma^2}}}>0,\;\;\;\mathrm{where}\;\;\;\Gamma =\left( {{\eta^2}+r{\sigma^2}} \right). $$

1.3 Outlet Size

$$ q=\eta a+(\gamma +\varepsilon )k. $$
$$ A:\quad \mathop{\max}\limits_a \left[ {\alpha (\eta a+\gamma k)+W-\frac{{{a^2}}}{2}-\frac{r}{2}{\alpha^2}{\sigma^2}{k^2}} \right], foc: a=\alpha \eta . $$
$$ P:\quad \mathop{\max}\limits_{\alpha } \left[ {{\eta^2}\alpha -\frac{{{\alpha^2}{\eta^2}}}{2}-\frac{r}{2}{\alpha^2}{\sigma^2}{k^2}} \right], foc: {\eta^2}-\alpha {\eta^2}-r\alpha {\sigma^2}{k^2}=0, $$
$$ {\alpha^{*}}=\frac{{{\eta^2}}}{{{\eta^2}+r{\sigma^2}{k^2}}}, $$
$$ \frac{{d{\alpha^{*}}}}{dk }=-\frac{{2{\eta^2}r{\sigma^2}k}}{{{\Gamma^2}}}<0,\;\;\;\mathrm{where}\;\;\;\Gamma ={\eta^2}+r{\sigma^2}{k^2}. $$

1.4 Costly Monitoring

This result is derived in Lafontaine and Slade (1996).

1.5 Franchisor Effort

$$ q=\eta a+\theta b+\varepsilon . $$

This problem has two incentive constraints:

$$ A:\quad \mathop{\max}\limits_a \left[ {\alpha (\eta a+\theta b)+W-\frac{{{a^2}}}{2}-\frac{r}{2}{\alpha^2}{\sigma^2}} \right], foc: a=\alpha \eta . $$
$$ P:\quad \mathop{\max}\limits_b \left[ {(1-\alpha )(\eta a+\theta b)-\frac{{{b^2}}}{2}} \right], foc: b=(1-\alpha )\theta . $$

The franchisor chooses α to maximize total surplus, equal to \( \eta a+\theta b-\frac{{{a^2}}}{2}-\frac{{{b^2}}}{2}-\frac{r}{2}{\alpha^2}{\sigma^2}, \) subject to the two incentive constraints. After substituting, we have:

$$ \mathop{\max}\limits_{\alpha } \left[ {\alpha {\eta^2}+(1-\alpha ){\theta^2}-\frac{{{\alpha^2}{\eta^2}}}{2}-\frac{{{{{(1-\alpha )}}^2}{\theta^2}}}{2}-\frac{r}{2}{\alpha^2}{\sigma^2}} \right], $$
$$ foc:{\eta^2}-{\theta^2}-\alpha {\eta^2}+(1-\alpha ){\theta^2}-r\alpha {\sigma^2}=0, $$
$$ {\alpha^{*}}=\frac{{{\eta^2}}}{{{\eta^2}+{\theta^2}+r{\sigma^2}}}, $$
$$ \frac{{d{\alpha^{*}}}}{{d\theta }}=-\frac{{2{\eta^2}\theta }}{{{\Gamma^2}}}<0, \frac{{d{\alpha^{*}}}}{{d\eta }}=\frac{{2\eta ({\theta^2}+r{\sigma^2})}}{{{\Gamma^2}}}>0,\;\;\;\mathrm{where}\;\;\;\Gamma =\left( {{\eta^2}+{\theta^2}+r{\sigma^2}} \right). $$

1.6 Multiple Tasks

$$ q=a+\varepsilon,\quad \varepsilon \sim N(0,\varSigma ),\quad C(a)=\frac{{{a^T}a}}{2}, $$

where q, a, and ε are vectors, as is α. However, W remains a scalar.

$$ A:\quad \mathop{\max}\limits_a \left[ {{\alpha^T}a+W-\frac{{{a^T}a}}{2}-\frac{{r{\alpha^T}\varSigma \alpha }}{2}} \right],\quad foc: a=\alpha . $$

After substituting, we have:

$$ P:\quad \mathop{\max}\limits_{\alpha } \left[ {{\alpha^T}j-\frac{{{\alpha^T}\alpha }}{2}-\frac{{r{\alpha^T}\varSigma \alpha }}{2}} \right], foc: j-\alpha -r\varSigma \alpha =0. $$

Hence, \( {\alpha^{*}}={{(I+r\varSigma )}^{-1 }}j, \) where j is a vector of ones. When n = 2, this becomes

$$ \alpha_i^{*}=\frac{{1+r{\sigma_{jj }}-r{\sigma_{12 }}}}{{(1+r{\sigma_{11 }})(1+r{\sigma_{22 }})-{r^2}\sigma_{12}^2}}. $$

Setting \( {\sigma_{11 }}={\sigma_{22 }}={\sigma^2} \) yields:

$$ \alpha_i^{*}=\frac{{1+r{\sigma^2}-r{\sigma_{12 }}}}{{{{{(1+r{\sigma^2})}}^2}-{r^2}\sigma_{12}^2}}=\frac{1}{{1+r({\sigma^2}+{\sigma_{12 }})}} $$

so that

$$ \frac{{d\alpha_i^{*}}}{{d{\sigma_{12 }}}}=-\frac{r}{{{{{(1+r({\sigma^2}+{\sigma_{12 }}))}}^2}}}<0. $$

1.7 Spillovers Within Chains

$$ q=1-p-\mu \bar{p}+a+\varepsilon . $$

where \( \bar{p} \) is the price at another outlet in the same chain.

$$ A:\quad \mathop{\max}\limits_a \left[ {\alpha (1-p-\mu \bar{p}+a)+W-\frac{{{a^2}}}{2}-\frac{r}{2}{\alpha^2}{\sigma^2}} \right],\quad foc: a=\alpha . $$

The principal chooses p =\( \bar{p} \) and α to

$$ P:\quad \mathop{\max}\limits_{{p,\alpha }} \left[ {\left( {1-(1+\mu )p+\alpha } \right)p-\frac{{{\alpha^2}}}{2}-\frac{r}{2}{\alpha^2}{\sigma^2}} \right], $$
$$ \mathop{foc}\limits_p: 1-2(1+\mu )p+\alpha =0, {p^{*}}=\frac{{1+\alpha }}{{2(1+\mu )}}, $$
$$ \mathop{foc}\limits_{\alpha }: p-\alpha -r\alpha {\sigma^2}=0. $$

Substituting for p yields:

$$ {\alpha^{*}}=\frac{1}{{2(1+r{\sigma^2})(1+\mu )-1}}, $$
$$ \frac{{d{\alpha^{*}}}}{{d\mu }}=-\frac{{2(1+r{\sigma^2})}}{{{\Gamma^2}}}<0\;\;\;\mathrm{where}\;\;\;\Gamma =2\left( {1+r{\sigma^2}} \right)(1+\mu )-1. $$

1.8 Product Substitution

$$ q=1-p+\delta \bar{p}+a+\varepsilon $$

where \( \bar{p} \) is now the price at a rival chain.

$$ A:\quad \mathop{\max}\limits_a \left[ {\alpha (1-p+\delta \bar{p}+a)+W-\frac{{{a^2}}}{2}-\frac{r}{2}{\alpha^2}{\sigma^2}} \right],\quad foc: a=\alpha . $$
$$ P:\quad \mathop{\max}\limits_{{p,\alpha }} \left[ {\left( {1-p+\delta \bar{p}+\alpha } \right)p-\frac{{{\alpha^2}}}{2}-\frac{r}{2}{\alpha^2}{\sigma^2}} \right], $$
$$ \mathop{foc}\limits_p: 1-2p+\delta \bar{p}+\alpha =0. $$

Using symmetry to set p =\( \bar{p} \) yields:

$$ {p^{*}}=\frac{{1+\alpha }}{{2-\delta }}. $$
$$ \mathop{foc}\limits_{\alpha }: p-\alpha -r\alpha {\sigma^2}=0. $$

Substituting for p yields:

$$ {\alpha^{*}}=\frac{1}{{(1+r{\sigma^2})(2-\delta )-1}}, $$
$$ \frac{{d{\alpha^{*}}}}{{d\delta }}=-\frac{{(1+r{\sigma^2})}}{{{\Gamma^2}}}>0,\;\;\;\mathrm{where}\;\;\;\Gamma =\left( {1+r{\sigma^2}} \right)(2-\delta )-1. $$

1.9 Strategic Delegation of the Pricing Decision

$$ q=1-p+\delta \bar{p}+a+\varepsilon, $$

where \( \bar{p} \) is again the price at a rival chain. In this case, the agent is compensated by residual claims after he pays a royalty ρ per unit to the franchisor, as well as a franchise fee F. Thus we have:

$$ A:\quad \mathop{\max}\limits_{a,p } \left[ {(p-\rho )(1-p+\delta \bar{p}+a)-F-\frac{{{a^2}}}{2}-\frac{r}{2}{{{(p-\rho )}}^2}{\sigma^2}} \right] $$
$$ \mathop{foc}\limits_a: a=p-\rho, $$
$$ \mathop{foc}\limits_p: 1-2p+\delta \bar{p}+a+\rho -r(p-\rho ){\sigma^2}=0. $$

Substituting for a yields:

$$ p=\frac{{1+\delta \bar{p}+r\rho {\sigma^2}}}{{1+r{\sigma^2}}}, $$
$$ \frac{dp }{{d\bar{p}}}=\frac{\delta }{\Gamma}>0, \frac{dp }{{d\delta }}=\frac{\bar{p}}{\Gamma}>0,\ \frac{dp }{dr }=\frac{{{\sigma^2}(\rho -1-\delta \bar{p})}}{{{\Gamma^2}}}<0, $$
$$ \frac{dp }{{d{\sigma^2}}}=\frac{{r(\rho -1-\delta \bar{p})}}{{{\Gamma^2}}}<0,\ \frac{dp }{{d\rho }}=\frac{{r{\sigma^2}}}{\Gamma}>0, $$

where \( \Gamma =1+r{\sigma^2}. \) Using symmetry to set p =\( \bar{p} \) yields:

$$ p_D^{*} =\frac{{1+r\rho {\sigma^2}}}{{1-\delta+r{\sigma^2}}} \\ =\frac{1}{{1-\delta}}\;\;\;\;\mathrm{when}\;\;\;r{\sigma^2}=0.\\$$

By contrast, under vertical integration, assuming that a = 0 and ρ = 0, we have

$$ \begin{array}{llll} p_D^{*} & =\frac{{1+r\rho {\sigma^2}}}{{1-\delta +r{\sigma^2}}} \hfill \\ & =\frac{1}{{1-\delta }}\;\;\;\;\mathrm{when}\;\;\;r{\sigma^2}=0. \hfill \\ \end{array} $$

Setting p =\( \bar{p} \) yields \( p_I^{*}=\frac{1}{{2-\delta }} <1< \frac{1}{{1-\delta }}=p_D^{*}. \) Thus \( p_I^{*}<p_D^{*} \) when \( r{\sigma^2} \) is small.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2014 Springer Science+Business Media New York

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Lafontaine, F., Slade, M.E. (2014). Incentive and Strategic Contracting: Implications for the Franchise Decision. In: Chatterjee, K., Samuelson, W. (eds) Game Theory and Business Applications. International Series in Operations Research & Management Science, vol 194. Springer, Boston, MA. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-1-4614-7095-3_6

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics