Skip to main content

Social Security Knowledge

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
Consumer Knowledge and Financial Decisions

Part of the book series: International Series on Consumer Science ((ISCS))

  • 1319 Accesses

Abstract

Knowledge is an important resource for citizens in a democracy, but it is often in short supply when it comes to aspects of public policy. This chapter explores what Americans know about Social Security, a large federal social insurance program in the United States. Statistical analyses reveal that individual characteristics are strongly related to knowledge about Social Security and knowing program facts predicts preferences toward reform options.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 84.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 109.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD 109.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    The question and answers are interpreted as the legal incidence of the Social Security tax (i.e., it is literally paid by workers and employers), not the economic incidence (i.e., the employee pays it all, directly, and indirectly through lower wages).

  2. 2.

    Economists might argue that while this is true in nominal or real (i.e., inflation adjusted) terms, it might not be true according to present discounted value (i.e., the benefit of a stream of future payments discounted to reflect the time value of money and investment risk). Thus, this fact is contestable, but the mass public is more likely to encounter the perspective that appears in the mass media (e.g., Morin & Russakoff (2005) state “…most [people] incorrectly believe that retirees, on average, retirees receive less in benefits than they contribute to the system” p. A01).

  3. 3.

    The statistical simulations are for a respondent who takes on the modal or mean values of each independent variable (i.e., a white, female, Independent, moderate, employed, non-southerner, registered voter, rural, non-AARP member who is not on Social Security but who has the average values of income, education, and age).

References

  • Baggette, J., Shapiro, R. Y., & Jacobs, L. J. (1995). Social Security – An update. Public Opinion Quarterly, 59(Autumn), 420–442.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Barabas, J. (2004a). Social Security. In J. G. Geer (Ed.), Public opinion and polling around the world (pp. 344–352). Santa Barbara, CA: ABC-CLIO.

    Google Scholar 

  • Barabas, J. (2004b). Virtual deliberation: knowledge from online interaction versus ordinary discussion. In P. Shane (Ed.), Democracy online (pp. 239–252). New York: Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Barabas, J. (2004c). How deliberation affects policy opinions. American Political Science Review, 98(4), 687–701.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Barabas, J. (2006). Rational exuberance: The stock market and public support for Social Security privatization. Journal of Politics, 68(1), 50–61.

    Google Scholar 

  • Barabas, J., & Jerit, J. (2009). Estimating the causal effects of media coverage on policy-specific knowledge. American Journal of Political Science, 53(1), 73–89.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Burtless, G. (2010). Do workers prepare rationally for retirement? In A. Drolet, N. Schwarz, & C. Yoon (Eds.), The aging consumer: Perspectives from psychology and economics (pp. 103–130). New York: Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Campbell, A. (2003). How policies make citizens: Senior political activism and the American welfare state. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Chan, S., & Stevens, A. H. (2008). What you don’t know can’t help you: Pension knowledge and retirement decision-making. Review of Economics and Statistics, 90(2), 253–266.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Converse, P. E. (1990). Popular representation and the distribution of political information. In J. A. Ferejohn & J. H. Kuklinski (Eds.), Information and democratic processes (pp. 369–388). Urbana: University of Illinois Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cook, F. L., Barabas, J., & Page, B. I. (2002). Invoking public opinion: policy elites and Social Security. Public Opinion Quarterly, 66(2), 235–264.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cook, F. L., & Barrett, E. J. (1992). Support for the American Welfare State: The views of Congress and the Public. New York: Columbia University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cook, F. L., & Czaplewski, M. (2009). Public opinion on Social Insurance: The American Experience. In L. Rogne, C. Estes, B. Grossman, B. Hollister, & E. Solway (Eds.), Social Insurance and Social Justice: Social Security, Medicare, and the campaign against entitlements (pp. 250–278). New York: Springer.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cook, F. L., & Jacobs, L. R. (2002). Assessing assumptions about Americans’ attitudes about Social Security: Popular claims meet hard data. In P. Edelman & D. Salisbury (Eds.), The future of Social Insurance (pp. 82–110). Washington: Brookings Institution Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cook, F. L., Jacobs, L. J., & Kim, D. (2010). Trusting what you know: Information, knowledge, and confidence in Social Security. The Journal of Politics, 72(2), 397–412.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Delli Carpini, M. X., & Keeter, S. (1996). What Americans know about politics and why it matters. New Haven: Yale University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Downs, A. (1957). An economic theory of democracy. New York: Harper.

    Google Scholar 

  • Geer, J. G. (1996). From tea leaves to opinion polls: A theory of democratic leadership. New York: Columbia University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Geithner, T. F., Sebelius, K., Solis, H. L., Astrue, M. F., & Fichtner, J. J. (2009, May 12). The 2009 annual report of the board of trustees of the Federal Old-Age and Survivors Insurance and Federal Disability Insurance Trust Funds. Washington, DC: U.S. Government Printing Office.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gilens, M. (1999). Why Americans hate welfare. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gilens, M. (2001). Political ignorance and collective policy preferences. American Political Science Review, 95(June), 379–396.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gramlich, E. M. (1998). Is it time to reform Social Security? Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Jacobs, L. R., Cook, F. L., & Delli Carpini, M. X. (2009). Talking together: Public deliberation and political participation in America. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Jacobs, L. R., & Shapiro, R. Y. (1998a). Is Washington disconnected from public thinking about Social Security? Public Perspective, 9(June/July), 54–57.

    Google Scholar 

  • Jacobs, L. R., & Shapiro, R. Y. (1998b). Myths and misunderstandings about public opinion toward Social Security. In R. D. Arnold, M. J. Graetz, & A. H. Munnell (Eds.), Framing the social security debate values, politics, and economics (pp. 355–388). Washington: Brookings Institution Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Jerit, J. (2009). How predictive appeals affect policy opinion. American Journal of Political Science, 53(2), 411–426.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jerit, J., & Barabas, J. (2006). Bankrupt rhetoric: How misleading information affects knowledge about Social Security. Public Opinion Quarterly, 70(3), 278–303.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jerit, J., Barabas, J., & Bolsen, T. (2006). Citizens, knowledge, and the information environment. American Journal of Political Science, 50(April), 266–282.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • King, G., Honaker, J., Joseph, A., & Scheve, K. (2001). Analyzing incomplete political science data: an alternative algorithm for multiple imputation. American Political Science Review, 95(1), 49–69.

    Google Scholar 

  • King, G., Tomz, M., & Wittenberg, J. (2000). Making the most of statistical analyses: improving interpretation and presentation. American Journal of Political Science, 44(April), 347–361.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kuklinski, J. H., Quirk, P. J., Jerit, J., Schwieder, D., & Rich, R. F. (2000). Misinformation and the currency of democratic citizenship. Journal of Politics, 62(3), 790–816.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kunda, Z. (1990). The case for motivated reasoning. Psychological Bulletin, 108(3), 480–498.

    Article  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  • Liebman, J. B., & Luttmer, E. F. P. (2009). The perception of Social Security incentives for labor supply and retirement: The media voter knows more than you’d think. Unpublished Manuscript, Harvard Kennedy School and NBER.

    Google Scholar 

  • Long, J. S. (1997). Regression models for categorical and limited dependent variables. Thousand Oaks, CA: Sage.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lupia, A. (2007). How elitism undermines the study of voter competence. Critical Review, 18, 217–232.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lusardi, A., & Mitchell, O. (2007). Baby boomer retirement security: The role of planning, financial literacy, and housing wealth. Journal of Monetary Economics, 54(1), 205–224.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mastrobuoni, G. (2006). Do better-informed workers make better retirement choices? A test based on the Social Security statement. Unpublished Manuscript, Collegio Carlo Alberto.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mitchell, O. (1988). Worker knowledge of pension provisions. Journal of Labor Economics, 6(1), 21–39.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Morin, R., & Russsakoff, D. (2005, February 10). Social security problems not a crisis, most say. Washington Post, p. A01.

    Google Scholar 

  • Page, B. I. (2000). Is social security reform ready for the American public? In S. Burke, E. Kingson, & U. Reinhardt (Eds.), Social security and Medicare: individual versus collective risk and responsibility (pp. 183–207). Washington: Brookings Institution Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Prior, M., & Lupia, A. (2008). Money, time, and political knowledge: distinguishing quick recall and political learning skills. American Journal of Political Science, 52(1), 168–182.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shapiro, R. Y., & Smith, T. W. (1985). The polls – Social security. Public Opinion Quarterly, 49(4), 561–572.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shaw, G. M., & Mysiewicz, S. E. (2004). Trends: Social security and Medicare. Public Opinion Quarterly, 68(3), 394–423.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stolberg, S. G. (2005, February 6). “Political jitters and Social Security.” New York Times, Sect. 4, p. 2.

    Google Scholar 

  • Stolberg, S. G., & Hulse, C. (2005, February 4). “Cool reception on Capitol Hill to Social Security plan.” New York Times, Sect. A, p. 14.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Jason Barabas .

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

Appendix

Appendix

Tables 14.1 and 14.2 show which factors are statistically significant (in bold type) at or near conventional levels (  p  <  0.10, two-tailed) as well as those that are not. Positive entries indicate that the factor increases the probability of knowing a fact while negative coefficients signal the opposite. However, the direction of the coefficient is most important for variables that are statistically significant; in the other instances, it is not possible to be sure that the relationships are any different from zero.

Table 14.1 Statistical analyses predicting knowledge of social security program structure and operating details
Table 14.2 Statistical analyses predicting knowledge of social security privatization reform plan

With all of the statistical analyses presented in the chapter, the claims are probably better cast as associational rather than causal because the data are cross-sectional. In other words, surveys represent a diverse population, but with cross-sectional data analyses it is not always possible to be certain that one variable causes another. A strong case for causality is especially hard to sustain when it comes to the effects of knowledge on policy attitudes. However, there are some linkages, such as the relationship between static demographic factors like race or gender in which we can be fairly safe in predicting that the relationship goes from these factors to knowledge and not the other way around. Nevertheless, even in this situation it is still possible that an omitted relevant factor exists.

Due to space limitations, the output of the statistical models predicting Social Security reform preferences is not shown. The policy preference models opinions control for whether people knew the program was not going bankrupt in addition to the socio-demographic influences in Tables 14.1 and 14.2. The ideology and partisanship are not highly correlated (Pearson’s r  <  0.49), but the substantive conclusions hold if the ideology terms are removed.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2011 Springer Science+Business Media, LLC

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Barabas, J. (2011). Social Security Knowledge. In: Lamdin, D. (eds) Consumer Knowledge and Financial Decisions. International Series on Consumer Science. Springer, New York, NY. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-1-4614-0475-0_14

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics