Skip to main content

Animal Disease and the Industrialization of Agriculture

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
Health and Animal Agriculture in Developing Countries

Part of the book series: Natural Resource Management and Policy ((NRMP,volume 36))

Abstract

Descartes’ perspective that animals are machines, and perhaps little more, is a matter of great ethical disquiet in contemporary society (Cottingham 1978). Sweeping developments in the life sciences since about 1950 have provided technical insights on how to control life and growth in ways that have made the animal-as-machine analogy more real. The moral principles and economic tradeoffs at issue have become more clearly defined, in large part because production sciences and the systems they support demand clear definition of the production environment. Animal disease confounds control efforts, and also belies the attitude that an animal’s technical performance can be abstracted from its environs.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 84.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Hardcover Book
USD 109.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    The precise mechanisms through which sub-therapeutic antibiotics affect performance are unclear (Proctor 2010). They may inhibit bacteria as sources of sub-clinical disease, or suppress gut bacteria that prevent food absorption, or some combination thereof. Under any of these settings, non-use of antibiotics increases intra-herd performance variability.

  2. 2.

    Consider a square animal feedlot with side of length \( l \) and perimeter \( 4l \). If animal stocking density is 1 per unit area then animal capacity per lot is \( Q = {l^2} \) so that \( l = {Q^{{0.5}}} \). With annual maintenance cost per unit side length as \( 0.25z \), total annual maintenance cost is \( zl = z{Q^{{0.5}}} \) or \( z{Q^{{ - 0.5}}} \) per animal. Maintenance cost per animal is decreasing in scale.

  3. 3.

    Throughout, all functions are assumed to be twice continuously differentiable whenever differentiability is found to be convenient for analysis.

  4. 4.

    Hardin’s (1968) “Tragedy of the Commons” pastoral example notes that common grazing “ … may work reasonably satisfactorily for centuries because tribal wars, poaching, and disease keep the numbers of both man and beast well below the carrying capacity of the land.” But when these problems are solved “ … the inherent logic of the commons remorselessly generates tragedy.” In this, he didn’t view the disease externality environment to be the same as that of an over-exploiting resource and nor do we. But both problems involve unaccounted for negative spillovers so that the formal presentation of both problems can be similar, where the technology in (5.1) is very similar to the commons analysis in, e.g., p. 27 of Gibbons (1992).

  5. 5.

    See pp. 47–52 in Vives (1999) for details on uniqueness and stability in non-cooperative games.

  6. 6.

    Capital-labor substitution is but one aspect of the profound effects that uniformity-promoting technologies can have in protein and other bulk commodity markets. Other aspects, dealt with elsewhere, are their effects on the efficient extent of value added processing and technological experimentation (Hennessy et al. 2004; Hennessy 2007).

  7. 7.

    Antibiotics also increase feed conversion efficiency and so reduce feed costs. We might reduce \( \tau \) by saved feed costs to accommodate this effect, and the result could be negative in which case feed cost savings alone would justify technology adoption. This effect is not related to the industrialization phenomenon as we study it here. For the sake of focus, we ignore it.

  8. 8.

    Knife-edge cases of indifference, such as when \( \Theta \alpha = \varsigma \), are ignored as the implications warrant no additional comments.

  9. 9.

    As we shall show, technical complementarity does not imply economic complementarity. An increase in biosecurity price \( r \) may increase the optimum level of scale.

  10. 10.

    The derivatives are partial to acknowledge that an optimally chosen value of \( z \) will indeed depend on \( v \). So a total derivative with respect to \( v \) would account for this indirect effect.

  11. 11.

    Of course, (5.27) does not imply that \( {\hbox{d}}{z^{*}}/{\hbox{d}}v > 0 \) as scale effects need to be considered.

  12. 12.

    The condition is satisfied whenever \( {v_2} > {v_1} \) and \( {G_z}(z;{v_2}) \) is larger than \( {G_z}(z;{v_1}) \) in the monotone likelihood ratio sense, an ordering widely used in information economics (p. 485 in Mas-Colell et al. 1995). Note that \( z \) can be a concretely defined quantity, as with veterinarian hours per 1,000 animals. So too can \( v \), perhaps as a government animal public health infrastructure metric at the national level. A rich data set would allow for statistical tests on condition (5.28).

  13. 13.

    See p. 254 in Greger (2007) for a brief review of evidence on the hypothesis.

  14. 14.

    To obtain a better sense for the responses developed upon in discussions to this point, bear in mind that these are market equilibrium responses where output price is endogenous and equal to unit cost.

  15. 15.

    Were \( r = 0 \), which we rule out as both unrealistic and uninteresting, then \( \bar{B}( \cdot ) = {Q^{{{\beta_1}}}} \). The scale and biosecurity choice variables would be separable and \( {Q^{*}} = 0 \). This is the classical setting whereby an infinity of firms each produce an infinitesimal amount, and no long-run equilibrium actually exists (p. 337 in Mas-Colell et al. 1995).

References

  • Athey, S. ‘Monotone Comparative Statics Under Uncertainty’, Quarterly Journal of Economics,Vol. 117 (1, February, 2002) pp. 187–223.

    Google Scholar 

  • Beach, R.H., Poulos, C. and Pattanayak, S.K. ‘Farm Economics of Bird Flu’, Canadian Journal of Agricultural Economics, Vol. 55 (4, December, 2007) pp. 471–483.

    Google Scholar 

  • Besanko, D., Dranove, D., Shanley, M. and Schaefer, S. Economics of Strategy, 3 rd edn. (Hoboken NJ: John Wiley & Sons, 2004).

    Google Scholar 

  • Chandler, A.D. ‘Organizational Capabilities and the Economic History of the Industrial Enterprise’, Journal of Economic Perspectives, Vol. 6 (3, Summer, 1992) pp. 79–100.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ciftci, I. and Ercan, A. ‘Effects of Diets of Different Mixing Homogeneity on Performance and Carcass Traits of Broilers’, Journal of Animal and Feed Sciences, Vol. 12 (1, 2003) pp. 163–171.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cottingham, J. “A Brute to the Brutes?’: Descartes’ Treatment of Animals’, Philosophy, Vol. 53 (206,October, 1978) pp. 551–559.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dolberg, F., GuerneBleich, E. and McLeod, A. Summary of Project Results and Outcomes.Food and Agriculture Organization of the United Nations.Final report on the project TCP/RAS/3010(E) ‘Emergency Regional Support for Post Avian Influenza Rehabilitation’, Rome, February 2005.

    Google Scholar 

  • Echenique, F. ‘Finding all Equilibria in Games of Strategic Complements’, Journal of Economic Theory, Vol. 135 (1, July, 2007) pp. 514–532.

    Google Scholar 

  • Finlay, M.R. ‘Hogs, Antibiotics, and the Industrial Environments of Postwar Agriculture’, in S. R. Schrepfer and P. Scranton (eds), Industrializing Organisms: Introducing Evolutionary History,pp. 237–260 (London: Routledge, 2004).

    Google Scholar 

  • Galor, O. and Moav, O. ‘Natural Selection and the Origin of Economic Growth’, Quarterly Journal of Economics,Vol. 117 (4, November, 2002) pp. 1122–1191.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gibbons, R. Game Theory for Applied Economists (Princeton NJ: Princeton University Press, 1992).

    Google Scholar 

  • Graham, J.P., Boland, J.J. and Silbergeld, E. ‘Growth Promoting Antibiotics in Food Animal Production: An Economic Analysis’, Public Health Reports, Vol. 122 (January/February, 2007) pp. 79–87.

    Google Scholar 

  • Greger, M. ‘The Human/Animal Interface: Emergence and Resurgence of Zoonotic Infectious Diseases’, Critical Reviews in Microbiology,Vol. 33 (4, 2007) pp. 243–299.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hardin, G. ‘The Tragedy of the Commons’, Science, Vol. 162 (13 December, 1968) pp. 1243–1248.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hayes, D.J. and Jensen, H.H. Lessons from the Danish Ban on Feed-Grade Antibiotics, Food Control (Ames, Iowa: Center for Agricultural and Rural Development, Briefing Paper 03-BP 41, June 2003).

    Google Scholar 

  • Hennessy, D.A. ‘Slaughterhouse Rules: Animal Uniformity and Regulating for Food Safety in Meat Packing’, American Journal of Agricultural Economics,Vol. 87 (3, August, 2005) pp. 600–609.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hennessy, D.A., Roosen, J. and Jensen, H.H. ‘Infectious Disease, Productivity, and Scale in Open and Closed Animal Production Systems’, American Journal of Agricultural Economics,Vol. 87 (4, November, 2005) pp. 900–917.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hennessy, D.A. ‘Informed Control over Inputs and Extent of Industrial Processing’, Economics Letters,Vol. 94 (3, March, 2007) pp. 372–377.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hennessy, D.A., Miranowski, J.A. and Babcock, B.A. ‘Genetic Information in Agricultural Productivity and Product Development’, American Journal of Agricultural Economics,Vol. 86 (1, February, 2004) pp. 73–87.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ifft, J., Roland-Holst and Zilberman, D. ‘Production and Risk Prevention Response of Free Range Chicken Producers in Viet Nam to Highly Pathogenic Avian Influenza Outbreaks’, American Journal of Agricultural Economics,Vol. 93 (2, January, 2011) pp. 490–497.

    Google Scholar 

  • Key, N., McBride, M. and Mosheim, R. ‘Decomposition of Total Factor Productivity Change in the U.S. Hog Industry’, Journal of Agricultural and Applied Economics, Vol. 40 (1, April, 2008) pp. 137–149.

    Google Scholar 

  • Li, P.J. ‘Exponential Growth, Animal Welfare, Environmental and Food Safety Impact: The Case of China’s Livestock Production’, Journal of Agricultural and Environmental Ethics, Vol. 22 (3, June, 2009) pp. 217–240.

    Google Scholar 

  • MacDonald, J.M. and McBride, W.D. The Transformation of U.S. Livestock Agriculture: Scale, Efficiency, and Risks (Washington DC: U.S. Department of Agriculture, Electronic Information Bulletin 43, January 2009).

    Google Scholar 

  • Madsen, T.G. and Pedersen, J.R. ‘Broiler Flock Uniformity’, Feedstuffs, Vol. 82 (31, August 2, 2010) pp. 12–13.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mankiw, N.G. and Whinston, M.D. ‘Free Entry and Social Inefficiency’, Rand Journal of Economics, Vol. 17 (Spring 1986) pp. 48–58.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mas-Colell, A., Whinston, M.D. and Green J.R. Microeconomic Theory (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 1995).

    Google Scholar 

  • Milgrom, P. and Roberts, J. (1990a) ‘The Economics of Modern Manufacturing – Technology, Strategy, and Organization’, American Economic Review,Vol. 80(3, June, 1990) pp. 511–528.

    Google Scholar 

  • Milgrom, P. and Roberts, J. (1990b) ‘Rationalizability, Learning, and Equilibrium in Games with Strategic Complementarities’, Econometrica, Vol. 58 (6, November, 1990) pp. 1255–1277.

    Google Scholar 

  • Miller, G.Y., McNamara, P.E. and Singer, R.S. ‘Stakeholder Position Paper: Economist’s Perspectives on Antibiotic Use in Animals’, Preventive Veterinary Medicine, Vol. 73 (February 24, 2006) pp. 163–168.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mortensen, S., Stryhn, H., Sgaard, R., Boklund, A., Stärk, K. D. C., Christensen, J. and Willeberg, P. ‘Risk Factors for Infection of Sow Herds with Porcine Reproductive and Respiratory Syndrome (PRRS) Virus’, Preventive Veterinary Medicine, Vol. 53 (February 14, 2002) pp. 83–101.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mosheim, R. and Knox Lovell, C.A. ‘Scale Economies and Inefficiency of U.S. Dairy Farms’, American Journal of Agricultural Economics, Vol. 91 (August 2009) pp. 777–794.

    Google Scholar 

  • Proctor, M. ‘Antibiotic Use Risk Unlikely’, Feedstuffs, Vol. 82 (19, May 10, 2010) p. 9.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rose, N. and Madec, F. ‘Occurrence of Respiratory Disease Outbreaks in Fattening Pigs: Relation with the Features of a Densely and a Sparsely Populated Pig Area in France’, Veterinary Research,Vol. 33 (2, March-April, 2002) pp. 179–190.

    Google Scholar 

  • Smil, V. Feeding the World: A Challenge for the Twenty-First Century (Cambridge, MA: MIT Press, 2000).

    Google Scholar 

  • Steinfeld, H., Mooney, H.A., Schneider, F. and Neville, L.E., eds. Livestock in a Changing Landscape: Drivers, Consequences, and Responses, Vol. 1 (Washington, D.C.: Island Press, 2010).

    Google Scholar 

  • Trostle, R. Global Agricultural Supply and Demand: Factors Contributing to the Recent Increase in Food Commodity Prices (Washington DC: U.S. Department of Agriculture, Economic Research Service report WRS-0801, July 2008).

    Google Scholar 

  • Vandekerchove, D., De Herdt, P., Laevens, H. and Pasmans, F. ‘Risk Factors Associated with Colibacillosis Outbreaks in Caged Layer Flocks’, Avian Pathology, Vol. 33 (3, June, 2004) pp. 337–342.

    Google Scholar 

  • Vandeman, A.M. ‘Management in a Bottle: Pesticides and the Deskilling of Agriculture’, Review of Radical Political Economics, Vol. 27 (3, September, 1995), pp. 49B59.

    Google Scholar 

  • Vives, X. Oligopoly Pricing: Old Ideas and New Tools (Cambridge, MA: MIT Press, 1999).

    Google Scholar 

  • World Bank. Enhancing Control of Highly Pathogenic Avian Influenza in Developing Countries through Compensation (Washington DC: The International Bank for Reconstruction and Development, World Bank, 2006).

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to David A. Hennessy .

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

Appendix

Appendix

Second-order conditions: Compute

$$ {T_{{QQ}}}( \cdot ) = \frac{{{{\bar{B}}_{{QQ}}}( \cdot )}}{{G( \cdot )}}\ >\ 0,\quad {T_{{zz}}}( \cdot ) = - \frac{{{G_{{zz}}}( \cdot )\bar{B}( \cdot )}}{{{{[G( \cdot )]}^2}}} \ >\ 0, $$
(5.29)

where optimality conditions \( {T_Q}( \cdot ) = 0 \) and \( {T_z}( \cdot ) = 0 \) have been applied. The cross-derivative for the average cost function is \( {T_{{Qz}}}( \cdot ) = {\bar{J}_Q}( \cdot )r/G( \cdot )\ < \ 0 \), where optimality condition (5.26a) and computation \( {\bar{J}_Q}( \cdot ) = [Q{J_Q}( \cdot ) - J( \cdot )]/{Q^2}\mathop{ = }\limits^{\rm{sign}} {J_Q}( \cdot ) - \bar{J}( \cdot ) \ < \ 0 \) have been applied. Finally,

$$ \Phi \equiv {T_{{QQ}}}( \cdot ){T_{{zz}}}( \cdot ) - {[{T_{{Qz}}}( \cdot )]^2} = - \overbrace{{\frac{{{G_{{zz}}}(z)\bar{B}( \cdot ){{\bar{B}}_{{QQ}}}( \cdot )}}{{{{[G( \cdot )]}^3}}}}}^{{ < 0}} - \overbrace{{\frac{{{{[{{\bar{J}}_Q}( \cdot )]}^2}{r^2}}}{{{{[G( \cdot )]}^2}}}}}^{{ > 0}}. $$
(5.30)

Convexity on \( T( \cdot ) \) requires \( \Phi \ >\ 0 \). If cost parameter \( r \ > \ 0 \) is small (i.e., the biosecurity innovation has been well developed) or economies of scale are small (i.e., \( |{\bar{J}_Q}(Q)| \) is small) then \( \Phi \ > \ 0 \) is likely. Otherwise (5.30) may be violated, so that discontinuous scale and input responses result from a small parameter change. Henceforth we assume \( \Phi\ > \ 0 \).

Subsidy and innovation: Define \( H( \cdot ) = G( \cdot ) - {G_z}( \cdot )z\ > \ 0 \) where \( H( \cdot )\ >\ 0 \) is due to \( {G_z}( \cdot ) \ < \ G( \cdot )/z \) on \( z \geq 0 \) whenever \( G( \cdot ) \) is increasing and concave in \( z \) with \( G(0;v)\ >\ 0 \). Using (5.26a, b):

$$ {T_{{Qr}}}( \cdot ) = \frac{{{{\bar{J}}_Q}( \cdot )z}}{{G( \cdot )}} \ < \ 0,\quad {T_{{zr}}}( \cdot ) = \frac{{\bar{J}( \cdot )H( \cdot )}}{{{{[G( \cdot )]}^2}}} \ > \ 0. $$
(5.31)

Differentiate system (5.26a, b) completely with respect to \( (Q,z,r) \) and then invert to obtain:

$$ \frac{{{\text{d}}{Q^{*}}}}{{{\text{d}}r}} = \frac{{{T_{{Qz}}}{T_{{zr}}} - {T_{{zz}}}{T_{{Qr}}}}}{\Phi } = \overbrace{{\frac{{{{\bar{J}}_Q}( \cdot )r\bar{J}( \cdot )H( \cdot )}}{{{{[G( \cdot )]}^3}\Phi }}}}^{{ < 0}} + \overbrace{{\frac{{{{\bar{J}}_Q}( \cdot )\bar{B}( \cdot ){G_{{zz}}}( \cdot )z}}{{{{[G( \cdot )]}^3}\Phi }}}}^{{ > 0}}, $$
$$ \frac{{{\text{d}}{Q^{*}}}}{{{\hbox{d}}r}} = \frac{{{T_{{Qz}}}{T_{{zr}}} - {T_{{zz}}}{T_{{Qr}}}}}{\Phi } = \overbrace{{\frac{{{{\bar{J}}_Q}( \cdot )r\bar{J}( \cdot )H( \cdot )}}{{{{[G( \cdot )]}^3}\Phi }}}}^{{ < 0}} + \overbrace{{\frac{{{{\bar{J}}_Q}( \cdot )\bar{B}( \cdot ){G_{{zz}}}( \cdot )z}}{{{{[G( \cdot )]}^3}\Phi }}}}^{{ > 0}}. $$
(5.32)

Both expressions are indeterminate in sign without further information. Plausible functional forms are readily identified such that both derivatives are positive.

For the own-price response, \( - {T_{{QQ}}}{T_{{zr}}}/\Phi \ <\ 0 \) characterizes the direct effect. The indirect effect, through the effect on \( Q \), is \( {T_{{Qz}}}{T_{{Qr}}}/\Phi \ >\ 0 \). This is because an increase in scale lowers the unit cost of the biosecurity input due to scale economies emphasizing that input’s cost. For the scale response, the direct effect is represented by \( - {T_{{zz}}}{T_{{Qr}}}/\Phi \ >\ 0 \). The indirect effect on scale when mediated through the biosecurity input is \( {T_{{Qz}}}{T_{{zr}}}/\Phi\ < \ 0 \).

External effects. Differentiate system (5.26a, b) completely with respect to \( (Q,z,v) \) and then use the optimality conditions:

$$ \left( {\begin{array}{*{20}{c}} {\frac{{{{\bar{B}}_{{QQ}}}( \cdot )}}{{G( \cdot )}}} & {\frac{{{{\bar{J}}_Q}( \cdot )r}}{{G( \cdot )}}} \\ {\frac{{{{\bar{J}}_Q}( \cdot )r}}{{G( \cdot )}}} & { - \frac{{{G_{{zz}}}( \cdot )\bar{B}( \cdot )}}{{{{[G( \cdot )]}^2}}}} \\ \end{array} } \right)\left( {\begin{array}{*{20}{c}} {\frac{{{\text{d}}{Q^{*}}}}{{{\text{d}}v}}} \\ {\frac{{{\text{d}}{z^{*}}}}{{{\text{d}}v}}} \\ \end{array} } \right) = \left( {\begin{array}{*{20}{c}} 0 \\ {\frac{{R( \cdot )\bar{B}( \cdot )}}{{G( \cdot )}}} \\ \end{array} } \right). $$
(5.33)

So

$$ \frac{{{\text{d}}{Q^{*}}}}{{{\hbox{d}}v}} = - \frac{{{{\bar{J}}_Q}( \cdot )r\bar{B}( \cdot )}}{{\Phi {{[G( \cdot )]}^2}}}R( \cdot )\mathop{ = }\limits^{\rm{sign}} R( \cdot ),\quad \frac{{{\text{d}}{z^{*}}}}{{{\hbox{d}}v}} = \frac{{{{\bar{B}}_{{QQ}}}( \cdot )\bar{B}( \cdot )}}{{\Phi {{[G( \cdot )]}^2}}}R( \cdot )\mathop{ = }\limits^{\rm{sign}} R( \cdot ). $$
(5.34)

Explicit solution

Set \( C(Q) = {Q^{{{\beta_1} + 1}}},{\beta_1} \ >\ 0 \), and \( J(Q) = {Q^{{1 - {\beta_2}}}},{\beta_2} \in (0,1) \).Footnote 15 Writing \( \lambda = {\beta_2}/{\beta_1} \), (5.26a) provides \( {Q^{{{\beta_1} - 1}}} = \lambda {Q^{{ - (1 + {\beta_2})}}}rz \) and (5.26a) and (5.26b) solve as:

$$ \frac{{G({z^{*}};v)}}{{{G_z}({z^{*}};v)}} = (1 + \lambda ){z^{*}}, $$
(5.35a)
$$ {Q^{*}}({z^{*}}) = {(\lambda r{z^{*}})^{{1/({\beta_1} + {\beta_2})}}}. $$
(5.35b)

So for these functional forms, and regardless of the choice of some \( G(z) \) function that supports an interior solution, the \( z \) that minimizes unit cost is independent of unit cost parameter \( r \).

Finally, and as a specification distinct from \( G( \cdot ) = (1 - v){\overset{\lower0.5em\hbox{$\smash{\scriptscriptstyle\frown}$}} {G}} + v\hat{G}( \cdot ) \) previously discussed, let \( G(z;v) = z/[\mu + \sigma (v)z] \). This is the logistic function form. With constant \( \mu\ > \ 0 \ \)and \( \sigma (v) \ >\ 0 \), the external factor influences this distribution through \( {\sigma_v}(v)\ <\ 0 \) so that \( {G_v}( \cdot ) \ >\ 0 \) and an increase in the factor reduces the unit cost of output. Then \( {G_z}( \cdot ) = \mu /{[\mu + \sigma ( \cdot )z]^2} \), \( {G_z}( \cdot )/G( \cdot ) = \mu /\{ z[\mu + \sigma ( \cdot )z]\} \), and \( R( \cdot ) = - \mu {\sigma_v}( \cdot )/{[\mu + \sigma ( \cdot )z]^2} \ >\ 0 \). An improvement in external biosecurity increases productivity, and also the marginal productivity of the biosecurity input when calculated in percent terms.

System (5.35a, b) then solves as

$$ ({Q^{*}},{z^{*}}) \in \left\{ {(0,0),\left( {{{\left( {\frac{{{\lambda^2}\mu r}}{{\sigma ( \cdot )}}} \right)}^{{1/({\beta_1} + {\beta_2})}}},\frac{{\mu \lambda }}{{\sigma ( \cdot )}}} \right)} \right\}. $$
(5.36)

It will be shown later that \( ({Q^{*}},{z^{*}}) = (0,0) \) is not optimal, leaving only the interior solution. Notice that the equilibrium value for productivity is \( G( \cdot ) = \lambda /[(1 + \lambda )\sigma (v)] \), which is increasing in the beneficial external natural or socioeconomic factor, \( v \).

To understand why \( {\hbox{d}}{Q^{*}}/{\hbox{d}}r \ > \ 0 \) in (5.36), consider the direct and indirect effects of an increase in the price of biosecurity. An increase in \( r \) increases the incentive to reduce unit costs by increasing scale. This is the direct effect on scale. The indirect effect, via complementarity relation (5.27), is that a higher value of \( r \) reduces the incentive to use the biosecurity input and this reduces the incentive to increase scale. Relation (5.36) shows that the direct effect wins out.

Expression \( {z^{*}} \) in (5.36) also indicates that the direct and indirect effects of an increase in the value of \( r \) exactly offset. Although (5.36) does not show \( {\hbox{d}}{z^{*}}/{\hbox{d}}r\ > \ 0 \), this is possible, i.e., there could conceivably be a positive own-price effect in long-run equilibrium. The possibility arises because the endogenous scale choice alters the effective unit cost of the input in a manner broadly similar to how the income effect mediates price response in demand theory. As with Giffen goods, the indirect effect can overwhelm the direct effect.

It follows from \( {\sigma_v}( \cdot )\ < \ 0 \) that \( {\hbox{d}}{z^{*}}/{\hbox{d}}v\ > \ 0 \) and \( {\hbox{d}}{Q^{*}}/{\hbox{d}}v \ >\ 0 \), so that more external biosecurity coaxes out more internal biosecurity and increases scale. The example supports the hypothesis that more public health inputs do not crowd out (i.e., do complement) private activities to safeguard animal health but do promote large-scale production. In the example, strengthening the external biosecurity environment complements incentives for internal biosecurity and also encourages a scaling up of production activities. With better external biosecurity, the animal production format is more likely to become industrial than back-yard.

Finding the optimum in the explicit solution: Pose the problem as having two stages:

$$ \mathop{{\min }}\limits_z \mathop{{\min }}\limits_{{Q|z}} T( \cdot ). $$
(5.37)

Upon inserting (5.35b) into the given \( C( \cdot ) \) and \( J( \cdot ) \) functions, cost function (5.25) becomes:

$$ \begin{array}{*{20}{c}} {{\overset{\lower0.5em\hbox{$\smash{\scriptscriptstyle\frown}$}}{T}}( \cdot ) = \frac{{{{({Q^{*}})}^{{{\beta_1}}}} + {{({Q^{*}})}^{{ - {\beta_2}}}}r{z^{*}}}}{{{z^{*}}/[\mu + \sigma ( \cdot ){z^{*}}]}} = \mu \frac{{{{({Q^{*}})}^{{{\beta_1}}}}}}{{{z^{*}}}} + \sigma ( \cdot ){{({Q^{*}})}^{{{\beta_1}}}} + {{({Q^{*}})}^{{ - {\beta_2}}}}r[\mu + \sigma ( \cdot ){z^{*}}]} \\ { = \Gamma \times [\mu {{({z^{*}})}^{{ - {\beta_2}/({\beta_1} + {\beta_2})}}} + \sigma ( \cdot ){{({z^{*}})}^{{{\beta_1}/({\beta_1} + {\beta_2})}}}],\quad \Gamma \equiv [{\lambda^{{{\beta_1}/({\beta_1} + {\beta_2})}}} + {\lambda^{{ - {\beta_2}/({\beta_1} + {\beta_2})}}}]{r^{{{\beta_1}/({\beta_1} + {\beta_2})}}} > 0,} \\ \end{array} $$
(5.38)

which is the solution to the inner conditional optimization problem in (5.37). When \( {z^{*}} = 0 \) then \( {({z^{*}})^{{{\beta_1}/({\beta_1} + {\beta_2})}}} = 0 \) but \( {({z^{*}})^{{ - {\beta_2}/({\beta_1} + {\beta_2})}}} \to \infty \) so that \( ({Q^{*}},{z^{*}}) = (0,0) \) maximizes unit cost and cannot be optimal. To establish the problem’s overall convexity, differentiate the final expression for \( {\overset{\lower0.5em\hbox{$\smash{\scriptscriptstyle\frown}$}} {T}}( \cdot ) \) in (5.38) twice with respect to the remaining endogenous variable, \( z \), and insert \( {z^{*}} = \mu \lambda /\sigma (v) \) to obtain

$$ \frac{{\Gamma {\beta_2}[\mu ({\beta_1} + 2{\beta_2}) - \sigma ( \cdot ){\beta_1}{z^{*}}]{{({z^{*}})}^{{ - (2{\beta_1} + 3{\beta_2})/({\beta_1} + {\beta_2})}}}}}{{{{({\beta_1} + {\beta_2})}^2}}} = \frac{{\Gamma {\beta_2}\mu {{({z^{*}})}^{{ - (2{\beta_1} + 3{\beta_2})/({\beta_1} + {\beta_2})}}}}}{{{\beta_1} + {\beta_2}}} \ >\ 0. $$
(5.39)

Thus the problem is indeed convex and the interior solution is optimal.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2012 Food and Agriculture Organization of the United States

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Hennessy, D.A., Wang, T. (2012). Animal Disease and the Industrialization of Agriculture. In: Zilberman, D., Otte, J., Roland-Holst, D., Pfeiffer, D. (eds) Health and Animal Agriculture in Developing Countries. Natural Resource Management and Policy, vol 36. Springer, New York, NY. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-1-4419-7077-0_5

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics