Skip to main content

The Difference Between Answering a ‘Why’ Question and Answering a ‘How Much’ Question

  • Chapter
Simulation

Part of the book series: Sociology of the Sciences Yearbook ((SOSC,volume 25))

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

eBook
USD 16.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 109.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD 109.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Preview

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

References

  • Adelman, I. (1968). “Simulation: Economic processes”, in D.L. Sills (ed.), International Encyclopedia of the Social Sciences, vol. 14, New York: Macmillan and The Free Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Adelman, I. and F.L. Adelman (1959). “The dynamic properties of the Klein-Goldberger model”, Econometrica, 27: 596–625.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Barlas, Y. (1996). “Formal aspects of model validity and validation in system dynamics”, System Dynamics Review, 12.3: 183–210.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Burns, A.F. and W.C. Mitchell (1946). Measuring Business Cycles, New York: National Bureau of Economic Research.

    Google Scholar 

  • Christ, C.F. (1994). “The Cowles Commission’s contributions to econometrics at Chicago, 1939–1955”, Journal of Economic Literature 32: 30–59.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cooley, T.F. (ed.), (1995). Frontiers of Business Cycle Research, Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cooley, T.F. ( 1997). “Calibrated models”, Oxford Review of Economic Policy, 13.3: 55–69.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cooley, T.F. and E.C. Prescott (1995). “Economic growth and business cycles”, in T.F. Cooley (ed.), Frontiers of Business Cycle Research, Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press. pp. 1–38.

    Google Scholar 

  • Van Daalen, C.E., W.A.H. Thissen, and A. Verbraeck (1999). “Methods for the modeling and analysis of alternatives”, in A.P Sage and W.B. Rouse (eds.), Handbook of Systems Engineering and Management, New York et al.: Wiley, pp. 1037–1076.

    Google Scholar 

  • Van Fraassen, B.C. (1988). “The pragmatic theory of explanation”, in J.C. Pitt (ed.), Theories of Explanation, Oxford, UK: Oxford University Press, pp. 136–155.

    Google Scholar 

  • Franklin, A. (1997). “Calibration”, Perspectives on Science, 5: 31–80.

    Google Scholar 

  • Friedman, M. and A.J. Schwartz (1963). A Monetary History of the United States, 1867-1960, New York: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Haavelmo, T. (1944). “The probability approach in econometrics”, supplement to Econometrica, 12.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hertz, H. ([1899] 1956). The Principles of Mechanics Presented in a New Form, New York: Dover.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hertz, H. ([1893] 1962). Electric Waves, New York: Dover.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hoover, K.D. (1995a). “Facts and artifacts: Calibration and the empirical assessment of real-business-cycle models”, Oxford Economic Papers, 47: 24–44.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hoover, K.D. (1995b). “The problem of macroeconometrics”, in K.D. Hoover (ed.),Macroeconometrics, Developments, Tensions and Prospects, Boston: Kluwer, pp. 1–12.

    Google Scholar 

  • IVM (1993). International Vocabulary of Basic and General Terms in Metrology, 2nd ed., Geneva, Switzerland: International Organization for Standardization.

    Google Scholar 

  • King, R.G. and C.I. Plosser (1994). “Real business cycles and the test of the Adelmans”, Journal of Monetary Economics, 33: 405–438.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • King, R.G., C.I. Plosser, and S.T. Rebelo (1988). “Production, growth and business cycles, I. The basic neoclassical model”, Journal of Monetary Economics, 21: 195–232.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Klamer, A. (1984). The New Classical Macroeconomics. Conservations with the new classical economists and their opponents, Brighton, Sussex: Harvester Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Klein, L.R. and A.S. Goldberger (1955). An Econometric Model of the United States, 1929-1952, Amsterdam: North-Holland.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kydland, F.E. and E.C. Prescott (1982). “Time to build and aggregate fluctuations”, Econometrica, 50: 1345–1370.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kydland, F.E. and E.C. Prescott (1991). “The econometrics of the general equilibrium approach to business cycles”, Scandinavian Journal of Economics, 93: 161–178.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kydland, F.E. and E.C. Prescott (1996). “The computational experiment: An econometric tool”, Journal of Economic Perspectives, 10.1: 69–85.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kydland, F.E. and E.C. Prescott (1997). “A response from Finn E. Kydland and Edward C. Prescott”, Journal of Economic Perspectives, 11.1: 210–211.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lucas, R.E. (1976). “Econometric policy evaluation: A critique”, in K. Brunner and A.H. Meltzer (eds.),The Phillips Curve and Labor Markets, Amsterdam: North-Holland, pp. 19–46.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lucas, R.E. (1977). “Understanding business cycles”, in K. Brunner and A.H. Meltzer (eds.),Stabilization of the Domestic and International Economy, Amsterdam: North-Holland, pp. 7–29.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lucas, R.E. (1980). “Methods and problems in business cycle theory”, Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking, 12: 696–715.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lucas, R.E. (1987). “Adaptive behavior and economic theory”, in R.M. Hogarth and M.W. Reder (eds.),Rational Choice: The contrast between economics and psychology, Chicago, IL: The University of Chicago Press, pp. 217–242.

    Google Scholar 

  • Maxwell, J.C. ([1855] 1965). “On Faraday’s lines of force”, in W.D. Niven (ed.),The Scientific Papers of James Clerk Maxwell, vol. I, New York: Dover, pp. 155–229.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mitchell, W.C. (1951). What Happens During Business Cycles, New York: National Bureau of Economic Research.

    Google Scholar 

  • Morgan, M.S. (1990). The History of Econometric Ideas, Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Orcutt, G.H. (1960). “Simulation of economic systems”, The American Economic Review, 50.5: 893–907.

    Google Scholar 

  • Simon, H.A. (1969). The Sciences of the Artificial, Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Stokey, N.L. and R.E. Lucas, with E.C. Prescott (1989). Recursive Methods in Economic Dynamics, Cambridge, MA, and London: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Turing, A.M. (1950). “Computing machinery and intelligence”, Mind, 59: 433–460.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • White, K.P. (1999). “System design”, in A.P Sage and W.B. Rouse (eds.), Handbook of Systems Engineering and Management, New York et al.: Wiley, pp. 455–481.

    Google Scholar 

  • Woodward, J. (2000). “Explanation and invariance in the special sciences”, The British Journal for the Philosophy of Science, 51: 197–254.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2006 Springer

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Boumans, M. (2006). The Difference Between Answering a ‘Why’ Question and Answering a ‘How Much’ Question. In: Lenhard, J., Küppers, G., Shinn, T. (eds) Simulation. Sociology of the Sciences Yearbook, vol 25. Springer, Dordrecht. https://doi.org/10.1007/1-4020-5375-4_7

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics