Skip to main content

Part of the book series: Replacement of Neanderthals by Modern Humans Series ((RNMH))

Abstract

Social learning has been identified as one of the fundamentals of culture and therefore the understanding of why and how individuals use social information presents one of the big questions in cultural evolution. To date much of the theoretical work on social learning has been done in isolation of data. Evolutionary models often provide important insight into which social learning strategies are expected to have evolved but cannot tell us which strategies human populations actually use. In this chapter we explore how much information about the underlying learning strategies can be extracted by analysing the temporal occurrence or usage patterns of different cultural variants in a population. We review the previous methodology that has attempted to infer the underlying social learning processes from such data, showing that they may apply statistical methods with insufficient power to draw reliable inferences. We then introduce a generative inference framework that allows robust inferences on the social learning processes that underlie cultural frequency data. Using developments in population genetics—in the form of generative simulation modelling and approximate Bayesian computation—as our model, we demonstrate the strength of this method with an example based on simulated data.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

eBook
USD 16.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 54.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD 54.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

References

  • Acerbi A, Bentley RA (2014) Biases in cultural transmission shape the turnover of popular traits. Evol Hum Behav 35:228–236

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Akaike H (1974) A new look at the statistical model identification. IEEE Trans Autom Control 19:716–723

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Aoki K, Wakano JY, Feldman MW (2005) The emergence of social learning in a temporally changing environment: a theoretical model. Curr Anthropol 46:334–340

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bass FM (1969) A new product growth model for consumer durables. Manag Sci 15:215–227

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baum WM, Richerson PJ, Efferson CM, Paciotti BM (2004) Cultural evolution in laboratory microsocieties including traditions of rule giving and rule following. Evol Hum Behav 25:305–326

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Beaumont MA (2010) Approximate Bayesian computation in evolution and ecology. Annu Rev Ecol Evol Syst 41:379–406

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Beaumont MA, Zhang W, Balding DJ (2002) Approximate Bayesian computation in population genetics. Genetics 162(4):2025–2035

    Google Scholar 

  • Beaumont MA, Nielsen R, Robert C, Hey J, Gaggiotti O, Knowles L, Estoup A, Panchal M, Corander J, Hickerson M, Sisson SA, Fagundes N, Chikhi L, Beerli P, Vitalis R, Cornuet J-M, Huelsenbeck J, Foll M, Yang Z, Rousset F, Balding D, Excoffier L (2010) In defence of model-based inference in phylogeography. Mol Ecol 19:436–446

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Beheim BA, Thigpen C, McElreath R (2014) Strategic social learning and the population dynamics of human behavior: the game of Go. Evol Hum Behav 35:351–357. doi:10.1016/j.evolhumbehav.2014.04.001

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bentley RA, Shennan SJ (2003) Cultural transmission and stochastic network growth. Am Antiq 68:459–485

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bentley RA, Hahn MW, Shennan SJ (2004) Random drift and culture change. Proc R Soc B 271:1443–1450

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bentley RA, Lipo CP, Herzog HA, Hahn MW (2007) Regular rates of popular culture change reflect random copying. Evol Hum Behav 28:151–158

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Boyd R, Richerson PJ (1985) Culture and the evolutionary process. The University of Chicago Press, Chicago

    Google Scholar 

  • Boyd R, Richerson PJ (1988) An evolutionary model of social learning: the effects of spatial and temporal variation. In: Zentall T, Galef BG Jr (eds) Social learning. Erlbaum, Hillsdale, pp 29–48

    Google Scholar 

  • Burnham K, Anderson D (2002) Model selection and multi-model inference: a practical information-theoretic approach. Springer, Berlin

    Google Scholar 

  • Caldwell CA, Millen AE (2008) Experimental models for testing hypotheses about cumulative cultural evolution. Evol Hum Behav 29:165–171

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cavalli-Sforza L, Feldman MW (1981) Cultural transmission and evolution: a quantitative approach. Princeton University Press, Princeton

    Google Scholar 

  • Clauset A, Shalizi CR, Newman MEJ (2009) Power-law distributions in empirical data. Soc Ind Appl Math Rev 51(4):661–703

    Google Scholar 

  • Coultas JC (2004) When in Rome … an evolutionary perspective on conformity. Group Process Intergroup Relations 7(4):317–331

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Crema ER, Edinborough K, Kerig T, Shennan SJ (2014) An approximate Bayesian computation approach for inferring patterns of cultural evolutionary change. J Archaeol Sci 50:160–170

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Currat M, Ray N, Excoffier L (2004) Splatche: a program to simulate genetic diversity taking into account environmental heterogeneity. Mol Ecol Notes 4(1):139–142

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Del Moral P, Doucet A, Jasra A (2012) An adaptive sequential Monte Carlo method for approximate Bayesian computation. Stat Comput 22(5):1009–1020

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Efferson C, Lalive R, Richerson PJ, McElreath R, Lubell M (2008) Conformists and mavericks: the empirics of frequency-dependent cultural transmission. Evol Hum Behav 29:56–64

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Epstein JM (2007) Generative social science: studies in agent-based computational modeling. Princeton University Press, Princeton

    Google Scholar 

  • Epstein JM, Axtell RL (1996) Growing artificial societies: social science from the bottom up. MIT and Brookings Institution, Washington, DC

    Google Scholar 

  • Eriksson K, Enquist M, Ghirlanda S (2007) Critical points in current theory of conformist social learning. J Evol Psychol 5(1–4):67–87

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Eriksson A, Betti L, Friend AD, Lycett SJ, Singarayer JS, von Cramon-Taubadel N, Valdes PJ, Balloux F, Manica A (2012) Late Pleistocene climate change and the global expansion of anatomically modern humans. Proc Natl Acad Sci U S A 109:16089–16094

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ewens WJ (2004) Mathematical population genetics, 2nd edn. Springer, New York

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Fearnhead P, Prangle D (2012) Constructing summary statistics for approximate Bayesian computation: semi-automatic approximate Bayesian computation. J R Stat Soc Ser B 74:419–474

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Feldman MW, Aoki K, Kumm J (1996) Individual versus social learning: evolutionary analysis in a fluctuating environment. Anthropol Sci 104:209–232

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fisher RA (1930) The genetical theory of natural selection. Clarendon, Oxford

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Frank SA (2009) The common patterns of nature. J Evol Biol 22:1563–1585

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Franz M, Nunn CL (2009) Network-based diffusion analysis: a new method for detecting social learning. Proc R Soc B 276(1663):1829–1836

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Giraldeau L-A, Valone TJ, Templeton JJ (2002) Potential disadvantages of using socially acquired information. Philos Trans R Soc Lond B 357:1559–1566. doi:10.1098/rstb.2002.1065

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Green RE, Krause J, Briggs AW et al (2010) A draft sequence of the Neandertal genome. Science 328:710–722

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gutenberg B, Richter CF (1944) Frequency of earthquakes in California. Bull Seismol Soc Am 34:185–188

    Google Scholar 

  • Hahn MW, Bentley RA (2003) Drift as a mechanism for cultural change: an example from baby names. Proc R Soc B 270:120–123

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hellenthal G, Busby GBJ, Band G, Wilson JF, Capelli C, Falush D, Myers S (2014) A genetic atlas of human admixture history. Science 343(6172):747–751

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Henrich J (2001) Cultural transmission and the diffusion of innovations: adoption dynamic indicate that biased cultural transmission is the predominant force in behavioural change. Am Anthropol 103(4):992–1013

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Henrich J, Boyd R (1998) The evolution of conformist transmission and the emergence of between-group differences. Evol Hum Behav 19:215–241

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Henrich J, Broesch J (2011) On the nature of cultural transmission networks: evidence from Fijian villages for adaptive learning biases. Philos Trans R Soc B 366:1139–1148

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Herzog HA, Bentley RA, Hahn MW (2004) Random drift and large shifts in popularity of dog breeds. Proc R Soc B 271:1443–1450

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Heyes CM (1994) Social learning in animals: categories and mechanisms. Biol Rev 69:207–231

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hoppitt WJE, Laland KN (2013) Social learning: an introduction to mechanisms, methods, and models. Princeton University Press, Princeton

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Hoppitt WJE, Boogert NJ, Laland KN (2010a) Detecting social transmission in networks. J Theor Biol 263(4):544–555

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hoppitt WJE, Kandler A, Kendal JR, Laland KN (2010b) The effect of task structure on diffusion dynamics: implications for diffusion curve and network-based analyses. Learn Behav 38(3):243–251

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hudson RR (1983) Properties of a neutral allele model with intragenic recombination. Theor Popul Biol 23:183–201

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Itan Y, Powell A, Beaumont MA, Burger J, Thomas MG (2009) The origins of lactase persistence in Europe. PLoS Comput Biol 5:e1000491

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Joyce P, Marjoram P (2008) Approximately sufficient statistics and Bayesian computation. Stat Appl Genet Mol Biol 7:26

    Google Scholar 

  • Kandler A, Laland KN (2013) Tradeoffs between the strength of conformity and number of conformists in variable environments. J Theor Biol 332:191–202

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kandler A, Steele J (2010) Social learning, economic inequality and innovation diffusion. In: O'Brian MJ, Shennan S (eds) Innovation in cultural systems. The MIT Press, Cambridge, MA, pp 193–214

    Google Scholar 

  • Kendal JR, Kendal RL, Laland KN (2007) Quantifying and modelling social learning processes in monkey populations. Int J Psychol Psychol Ther 7(2):123–138

    Google Scholar 

  • Kendal JR, Giraldeau L-A, Laland KN (2009) The evolution of social learning rules: payoff-biased and frequency-dependent biased transmission. J Theor Biol 260:210–219

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kimura M, Crow JF (1964) The number of alleles that can be maintained in a finite population. Genetics 49:725–738

    Google Scholar 

  • Kingman JFC (1982) The coalescent. Stochastic Process Appl 13:235–248

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kirby S, Cornish H, Smith K (2008) Cumulative cultural evolution in the laboratory: an experimental approach to the origins of structure in human language. Proc Natl Acad Sci U S A 105(31):10681–10686

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kohler TA, Van Buskirk S, Ruscavage-Barz S (2004) Vessels and villages: evidence for conformist transmission in early village aggregations on the Pajarito Plateau, New Mexico. J Anthropol Archaeol 23:100–118

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Laland KN (2004) Social learning strategies. Learn Behav 32(1):4–14

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Laland KN, Richerson PJ, Boyd R (1996) Developing a theory of animal social learning. In: Heyes CM, Galef BG Jr (eds) Social learning in animals: the roots of culture. Academic Press, London, pp 129–154

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Laland KN, Odling-Smee FJ, Myles S (2010) How culture shaped the human genome: bringing genetics and the human sciences together. Nat Rev Genet 11:137–148

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mahajan V, Muller E, Bass FM (1995) Diffusion of new products: empirical generalizations and managerial uses. Mark Sci 14(3):79–88

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • MalĂ©cot G (1948) The mathematics of heredity (trans: Yermanos DM 1969). WH Freeman, San Francisco

    Google Scholar 

  • Marjoram P, Wall JD (2006) Fast “coalescent” simulation. BMC Genet 7:16

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Maynard Smith J (1978) Optimization theory in evolution. Annu Rev Ecol Syst 9:31–56

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • McElreath R, Bell AV, Efferson C, Lubell M, Richerson PJ, Waring T (2008) Beyond existence and aiming outside the laboratory: estimating frequency-dependent and pay-off-biased social learning strategies. Philos Trans R Soc B 363:3515–3528

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • McElreath R, Fasolo B, Wallin A (2011) The evolutionary rationality of social learning. In: Hertwig R, Hoffrage U (eds) Simple heuristics in a social world. Oxford University Press, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • McVean GAT, Cardin NJ (2005) Approximating the coalescent with recombination. Philos Trans R Soc B 360:1387–1393

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mesoudi A, Lycett SJ (2009) Random copying, frequency-dependent copying and culture change. Evol Hum Behav 30(1):41–48

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mesoudi A, O’Brien MJ (2008) The cultural transmission of great basin projectile-point technology I: an experimental simulation. Am Antiq 73(1):3–28

    Google Scholar 

  • Morgan TJH, Rendell L, Ehn M, Hoppitt WJE, Laland KN (2012) The evolutionary basis of human social learning. Proc R Soc B 279:653–662

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nakahashi W (2007) The evolution of conformist transmission in social learning when the environment changes periodically. Theor Popul Biol 72:52–66

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nakahashi W, Wakano JY, Henrich J (2012) Adaptive social learning strategies in temporally and spatially varying environments. Hum Nat 23:386–418

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Neiman FD (1995) Stylistic variation in evolutionary perspective: inferences from decorative diversity and interassemblage distance in Illinois woodland ceramic assemblages. Am Antiq 60:7–36

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nielsen R, Beaumont MA (2009) Statistical inferences in phylogeography. Mol Ecol 18(6):1034–1047

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nunes MA, Balding DJ (2010) On optimal selection of summary statistics for approximate Bayesian computation. Stat Appl Genet Mol Biol 9:34

    Google Scholar 

  • Powell A, Shennan SJ, Thomas MG (in prep) The power of power-laws in cultural evolution

    Google Scholar 

  • Pritchard JK, Seielstad MT, Perez-Lezaun A, Feldman MW (1999) Population growth of human Y chromosomes: a study of Y chromosome microsatellites. Mol Biol Evol 16(12):1791–1798

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rasteiro R, Bouttier P-A, Sousa V, Chikhi L (2012) Investigating sex-biased migration during the Neolithic transition in Europe. Proc R Soc B 279:2409–2416

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Reader SM (2004) Distinguishing social and asocial learning using diffusion dynamics. Anim Learn Behav 32(1):90–104

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rendell L, Boyd R, Cowden D, Enquist M, Eriksson K, Feldman MW, Fogarty L, Ghirlanda S, Lillicrap T, Laland KN (2010) Why copy others? Insights from the social learning strategies tournament. Science 328(5975):208–213

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rendell L, Fogarty L, Hoppitt WJE, Morgan TJH, Webster MM, Laland KN (2011) Cognitive culture: theoretical and empirical insights into social learning strategies. Trends Cogn Sci 15(2):68–76

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Robert CP, Corneut J-M, Marin J-M, Pillai NS (2011) Lack of confidence in approximate Bayesian computation model choice. Proc Natl Acad Sci U S A 108:15112–15117

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rogers AR (1988) Does biology constrain culture? Am Anthropol 90:819–831

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rogers EM (2003) Diffusion of innovations, 5th edn. Free Press, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Shennan SJ, Wilkinson JR (2001) Ceramic style change and neutral evolution: a case study from Neolithic Europe. Am Antiq 66:577–594

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Templeton AR (2009) Statistical hypothesis testing in intraspecific phylogeography: nested clade phylogeographical analysis vs. approximate Bayesian computation. Mol Ecol 18:319–331

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Toni T, Stumpf MPF (2010) Simulation-based model selection for dynamical systems in systems and population biology. Bioinformatics 26(1):104–110

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Toni T, Welch D, Strelkowa N, Ipsen A, Stumpf MPH (2009) Approximate Bayesian computation scheme for parameter inference and model selection in dynamical systems. J R Soc Interface 6:187–202

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Van der Bulte C, Stremersch S (2004) Social contagion and income heterogeneity in new product diffusion: a meta-analytic test. Mark Sci 23(4):530–544

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Veeramah KR, Wegmann D, Woerner A, Mendez F, Watkins J, Destro-Bisol G, Soodyall H, Louie L, Hammer MF (2012) An early divergence of KhoeSan ancestors from those of other modern humans is supported by an ABC-based analysis of autosomal resequencing data. Mol Biol Evol 29:617–630

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wakano JY, Aoki K (2007) Do social learning and conformist bias coevolve? Henrich and Boyd revisited. Theor Popul Biol 72:504–512

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wilde S, Timpson A, Kirsanow K, Kaiser E, Kayser M, Unterlaender M, Hollfelder N, Potekhina ID, Schier W, Thomas MG, Burger J (2014) Direct evidence for positive selection of skin, hair, and eye pigmentation in Europeans during the last 5,000y. Proc Natl Acad Sci U S A 111(13):4832–4837

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wright S (1931) Evolution in Mendelian populations. Genetics 16:97–159

    Google Scholar 

  • Zipf GK (1929) Relative frequency as a determinant of phonetic change. Harv Stud Class Philol 15:1–95

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgement

We thank Kenichi Aoki and Jeremy Kendal for their constructive comments which helped improving this chapter.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Anne Kandler .

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

Appendix

Appendix

In this chapter we assume that asocial and social learning strategies cause the cultural variants to change in frequency and describe those changes using a reaction–diffusion framework of the form

$$ \begin{aligned}[b]\frac{\partial {u}_i}{\partial t}\left(t,x\right)&=d\Delta {u}_i\left(t,x\right)-\nu {u}_i\left(t,x\right)+\xi \left(\mathrm{asocial}\ \mathrm{learning}\right) \\ &\quad +\left(1-\xi \right)\left(\mathrm{social}\ \mathrm{learning}\right),\ i=1,\dots, k\\ \frac{\partial K}{\partial t}\left(t,x\right)&=d\Delta K\left(t,x\right)+\left(\lambda -\nu \right)\\ &\quad \times K\left(t,x\right)\left(1-K\left(t,x\right)\right).\raisetag{16pt}\end{aligned} $$
(7.2)

Thereby the variable u i describes the frequency of variant i at time t in the population, or in other words the fraction of the population that has adopted variant i. The variable K denotes the population size at location x and in the following we assume the population size to be the same for all locations x. It follows from the second equation in model (7.2) that \( K\left(t,x\right)\le 1,\ \forall t \) and further, it holds \( {\displaystyle {\sum}_{i=1}^k{u}_i\left(t,x\right)\le K\left(t,x\right)} \). The diffusion coefficient d describes the scale of spatial interactions, λ and ν the birth and death rates, respectively and ξ the reliance of the population on asocial learning. For sake of simplicity we stated the non-spatial version in the main text. All dynamics describes below hold in a similar way for this model.

In more detail, learning in various forms can increase or decrease the frequency of variant i. Asocial learning is based on the judgement about the benefit of specific variants in observed environmental conditions and consequently has two error sources: misjudgement of the current environmental condition and misjudgement of the adaptation levels of the different variants. Despite the conceptual differences both error sources lead to the same outcome in the modelling framework: a variant i is chosen for which holds \( {\mu}_i\ne e \). Therefore the inaccuracy of asocial learning is modelled by assuming that asocial learning is based on \( \overline{e}=e+\omega \) with \( \omega \sim \mathcal{N}\left(0,{\sigma}_{\omega}^2\right) \). However, besides being error-prone asocial learning can lead to the introduction of new variants and its dynamic is modelled by (for sake of shortness we write \( \overline{e}=\overline{e}\left(t,x\right) \))

$$ \begin{aligned}[b]&{P}_i\left({a}_i\left(\overline{e}\right)\right)\left(K\left(t,x\right)-{\displaystyle {\sum}_{j=1}^k{u}_j}\right) \\ &\quad +\displaystyle {\sum}_{j=1,j\ne i}^k\left({P}_{ji}\left({a}_i\left(\overline{e}\right),{a}_j\left(\overline{e}\right)\right){u}_j\left(t,x\right)\right. \\ &\quad \left.-{P}_{ij}\left({a}_i\left(\overline{e}\right),{a}_j\left(\overline{e}\right)\right){u}_i\left(t,x\right)\right)\end{aligned} $$
(7.3)

The parameter P i describes the rate at which the fraction of the population which has not yet adopted a variants (described by the difference between the population size K(t, x) at time t and the sum of the fractions of the population which have adopted one of the k variants, \( K\left(t,x\right)-{\displaystyle {\sum}_{j=1}^k{u}_j\left(t,x\right)} \)) learns variant i asocially. P i depends on the adaption level a i (ē) meaning that asocial learning is not completely random: the higher the adaptation level in the estimated environment ē the higher is the adoption rate. Further, we allowed for the switching of variants which describes the process that individuals who already have adopted a cultural variant can switch to adopting a different variant. The coefficient P ij models the rate at which the fraction of the population which has adopted variant i switches to variant j due to the evaluation of environmental cues. Again it holds the larger the difference \( {a}_j\left(\overline{e}\right)-{a}_i\left(\overline{e}\right) \) between the estimated adaption levels the higher is the switching rate. Contrary to asocial learning, social learning is based on social cues and therefore can only lead to learning of variants which are already present in the considered location. In the considered framework we only considered two social learning strategies: direct biased social learning and conformist social learning. Direct biased social learning is modelled by (for sake of shortness we write \( e=e\left(t,x\right) \))

$$ \begin{aligned}[b]&{r}_i\left({a}_i(e)\right){u}_i\left(t,x\right)\left(1-\frac{u_i\left(t,x\right)}{K\left(t,x\right)-\displaystyle {\sum}_{j=1,j\ne i}^k{u}_j\left(t,x\right)}\right) \\ &\quad +\displaystyle {\sum}_{j=1,j\ne i}^k\left({c}_{ji}\left({a}_i(e),{a}_j(e)\right)\right. \\ &\quad \left.-{c}_{ij}\left({a}_i(e),{a}_j(e)\right)\right){u}_i\left(t,x\right){u}_j\left(t,x\right).\raisetag{12pt}\end{aligned} $$
(7.4)

Similarly to the dynamic of asocial learning the first term

$$ {r}_i\left({a}_i(e)\right){u}_i\left(t,x\right)\left(1-\frac{u_i\left(t,x\right)}{K\left(t,x\right)-{\displaystyle {\sum}_{j=1,j\ne i}^k}{u}_j\left(t,x\right)}\right) $$

models the adoption of variant i by the population which has not adopted any variants yet. However contrary to asocial learning, this term is frequency-dependent. It is a logistic growth process with adoption rate (or intrinsic rate of increase) r i and broadly speaking describes cultural reproduction. Per definition, the population size K(t, x) at location x is the upper limit of the total fraction of adopters in the population at this location (given by \( {\displaystyle {\sum}_{j=1}^k{u}_j\left(t,x\right)} \)), regardless of the adopted variant. Consequently, the upper limit for the fraction of the population that has adopted variants i is given by \( K\left(t,x\right)={\displaystyle {\sum}_{j=1}^k{u}_j\left(t,x\right)} \) (i.e. we assume that our cultural variants compete for a common pool of adopters). The adoption rate r i is assumed to be proportional to the adaptation level a i in the currently experienced environmental condition e. It holds: The higher the adaptation level the higher is the adoption rate. The second term

$$ {\displaystyle {\sum}_{j=1,j\ne i}^k\left({c}_{ji}\left({a}_i(e),{a}_j(e)\right)\right.}\\{\left.-{c}_{ij}{a}_i(e),{a}_j(e)\right){u}_i\left(t,x\right){u}_j\left(t,x\right)} $$

describes the switching dynamic between the fractions of the population which has already adopted a variant. Again we assumed that individuals who have already adopted a variant have the chance to switch to another variant and therefore the different cultural variants compete with each other for use. These interactions between the variants are described by the terms c ij (a i (e), a j (e))u i (t, x)u j (t, x) which model the switch process from variant i to variant j. The strength of this process is determined by the rate c ij and it holds: The higher the difference \( {a}_j(e)-{a}_i(e) \) of the adaptation levels of both variants the higher is the switching rate. In order to include conformist social learning we allowed these model parameters to be frequency-dependent. We assumed

$$ \begin{aligned}\tilde{r}_i&=\left(1-b\right){r}_i\left({a}_i(e)\right)+b\left({u}_i\left(t,x\right)-{c}_bK\left(t,x\right)\right)\ \mathrm{and}\\ {\tilde{c}}_{ij}&={\left[\left(1-b\right){c}_{ij}\left({a}_i(e),{a}_j(e)\right)+b\left({u}_j\left(t,x\right)\right.\right.}\\ &\quad\quad {\left.\left.-{c}_bK\left(t,x\right)\right)\right]}^{+}\end{aligned} $$

where b controls the reliance on adaptation information and frequency information, respectively. For b = 0 we obtain direct biased learning while b > 0 supports variants with a frequency higher than the commonness threshold c b K(t, x). In this case the difference \( \left({u}_i\left(t,x\right)-{c}_bK\left(t,x\right)\right) \) is positive and the adoption rate \( {\tilde{r}}_i \) is increased. Contrary if \( \left({u}_i\left(t,x\right)-{c}_bK\left(t,x\right)\right) \) is negative (and therefore variant i has a relatively small frequency) the adoption rate \( {\tilde{r}}_i \) is decreased. A similar dynamic applies to the switching rate \( {\tilde{c}}_{ij} \). If the frequency of variant j (the target of the switch process) exceeds the commonness threshold c b K(t, x) then the rate \( {\tilde{c}}_{ij} \) with which variant i is substituted by variant j is increased. The symbol \( {\left[.\right]}^{+} \) denotes the positive part of any real number (e.g. \( {\left[3.4\right]}^{+}=3.4 \) but \( {\left[-3.4\right]}^{+}=0 \)) ensures that there is no reversal of the switch direction.

We note that when considering a single cultural variant the dynamic of asocial learning (7.3) results in r-shaped adoption curve while the dynamic of asocial learning (7.4) results in a S-shaped curve whereby the existence of a conformist tendency (b > 0) produces long tails at the beginning and an accelerated adoption behaviour when the commonness threshold is exceeded. System (7.2) can be solved using the Finite-Element method and we obtain the time course of the frequencies u i . of each cultural variant that are expected under the assumed learning hypothesis and environmental change.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2015 Springer Japan

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Kandler, A., Powell, A. (2015). Inferring Learning Strategies from Cultural Frequency Data. In: Mesoudi, A., Aoki, K. (eds) Learning Strategies and Cultural Evolution during the Palaeolithic. Replacement of Neanderthals by Modern Humans Series. Springer, Tokyo. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-4-431-55363-2_7

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics