Skip to main content
Log in

Large-Scale Transition of Economic Systems – Do CEECs Converge Toward Western Prototypes?

  • Original Article
  • Published:
Comparative Economic Studies Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

We analyze potential convergence of Central and Eastern European Countries’ (CEECs) economic systems toward western prototypes. The corresponding comparative capitalism literature identified four prototype economic systems among (traditional) OECD countries: Liberal, Continental, Nordic, and Mediterranean. Based on a comprehensive macroeconomic cluster approach, we are able to confirm these prototype country clusters. At the same time, our results indicate that the economic systems of CEECs have still not completely converged toward these prototypes, but complement them by independent Liberal (CEEC LME) and Continental/Nordic (CEEC CME) varieties, showing no signs of convergence toward the inconsistent and underperforming economic system of Mediterranean countries.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Figure 1
Figure 2
Figure 3
Figure 4

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. We define CEECs as all former socialist countries that had joined the European Union as of 2016.

  2. A CME, for example, combines industrial relations shaped by employer–employee cooperation and higher job security with a focus on firm- and industry-specific skills in their education system. The institutional configuration in one sphere of the economy (job security on labor market) enhances the efficiency of the institutions in another sphere (job security reduces sunk costs of firm/industry-specific education). In a consistent variety of capitalism, i.e., LME or CME, all institutions of the different spheres of the production system are complementary to each other, and these institutional complementarities allow for superior performance (Hall and Soskice, 2001).

  3. The nomenclature for clusters varies in the literature. Therefore, we use our own nomenclature for the clusters in our analysis.

  4. Iversen and Wren (1998) analyzed what they called the “trilemma” problem of postindustrial economies, in which employment growth is concentrated in service sectors with low productivity growth. They argue that tradeoffs involved in achieving employment, equality, and stability lead to different solutions depending on economic systems. The Liberal response allows service sector wages to decrease, which will lower relative prices and lead to growing demand and employment while maintaining budgetary restraint at the cost of increasing income inequality. The Christian democratic (Continental) response prevents service sector wages from decreasing, subsequently sustaining income equality and budgetary restraint at the cost of lower employment and demand. Finally, the social democratic (Nordic) response maintains high wages for service sector workers, which are increasingly employed in the public sector and thereby increases employment and demand while maintaining income equality at the cost of declining fiscal stability (higher taxes and/or debt).

  5. Kitschelt (2006), closer to our comprehensive analysis of economic systems, explains a different variant of the “trilemma” of macroeconomic targets. He focuses on innovation capacity, which is closely linked to employment creation/economic growth. He concludes that the Nordic is superior to the Continental model because there, redistribution is much more efficient on the macrolevel allowing for both fiscal stability and a low level of regulation supporting innovation and growth, while still upholding a comparatively equal income distribution. In achieving this, the Nordic countries have managed to escape the “trilemma” of macroeconomic targets to a certain degree, whereas the Continental countries find themselves in a state requiring reform steps either in a more Liberal or Nordic direction.

  6. Traditionally, cluster studies have figured prominently in analyses on WWS typology. Saint-Arnaud and Bernard (2003), for example, used a dataset of 36 variables on the political and social situations in 20 OECD countries and identified the three groups proposed by the WWS approach plus one cluster of Mediterranean countries. Bambra (2007), Danforth (2014), Gough (2001), Kangas (1994), Kautto (2002), Powell and Barrientos (2004) also conducted cluster analyses based on welfare state characteristics and arrived at comparable results: Esping-Andersen’s hypothesis of three distinct models of welfare state provision is supported. Only a few cluster studies on VoC typology exist, including Schneider and Paunescu (2012) and Hassel (2014). Most studies confirm the LME-CME pattern predicted by Hall and Soskice, but also identify a cluster of Mediterranean countries, whose model of production and welfare state provision apparently differ from those of other European countries.

  7. An exceptional study is provided by Pryor (2006) because only developing countries are considered in the analysis. Doing this, Pryor identifies somewhat different models: Business, Labor, Statist, and Traditional.

  8. Studies investigating the CEECs’ economic systems (not employing cluster analysis) are offered by Babos (2010), Bartlett (2007), Cernat (2006), Crowley (2008), Feldmann (2006), King (2008), Knell and Srholec (2007), Myant (2007) and Mykhnenko (2007). These studies in part arrive at differing results for several countries. Exceptions are Slovenia and Estonia, since for these two, fairly advanced, CEECs, clearer results emerged from an application of the VoC approach. Following the results of Feldmann (2008) and Buchen (2007), Slovenia (CME) and Estonia (LME) quite closely resemble VoC prototypes.

  9. Exceptions are Castles and Obinger (2008) and Schneider and Paunescu (2012), who examined more than one period for traditional OECD countries. Schneider and Paunescu (2012) conducted separate cluster analyses for five periods between 1990 and 2005. Considering the time dimension reveals some interesting and unconventional insights. Spain, Denmark, Finland, the Netherlands, and Sweden are assigned to the LME cluster in the most recent period. They interpret this as a result of liberalization efforts in these countries. Furthermore, Danforth (2014), not considering CEECs, tests the validity of the WWS grouping across time, conducting cluster analysis for each 5-year interval between 1950 and 2000. His analysis confirms the hypothesis of three distinct welfare state models among the fully developed OECD countries, which emerged in the mid-1970s and have remained stable since.

  10. Strictly speaking, we consider the 10 CEECs plus Croatia. For reasons of simplicity, we refer to this subsample as CEECs.

  11. An additional advantage of our empirical strategy is that it would allow us to extend the country sample well beyond OECD countries in future studies.

  12. While income and distribution of income are established target variables, we also tested inflation and fiscal deficit as alternative stability indicators. However, analyzing rather stable institutional designs using variables influenced by business cycles leads to distorted results.

  13. We measure innovative capacity by an aggregated indicator of the World Bank’s Knowledge Assessment Methodology based on several innovation parameters. This variable is supposed to capture a country’s "capacity” to innovate, i.e., the degree to which it is capable of producing new technologies/products/etc., which enables it to achieve economic growth in the future.

  14. The results for the PC analyses of the previous periods are available upon request. As mentioned, the correlations between PCs and initial variables remain remarkably stable for 2000–2003 and 2004–2006. The results of the principal component analysis for the first period (1995), however, have been strikingly different. In this period, CEECs still constituted extreme cases of redistribution positively correlated with both spending and regulation. At the same time, innovation has been positively correlated with transfers. Arguably, early transition of the CEECs in the mid-1990s after the disintegration of the Eastern Bloc distorted the result to a great extent because economic systems were apparently not comparable at that point in time.

References

  • Acemoglu, D, Robinson, J and Verdier, T. 2012: Can’t we all be more like Scandinavians? Asymmetric growth and institutions in an interdependent world. NBER Working Paper 18441, National Bureau of Economic Research.

  • Ahlquist, J and Breunig, C. 2009: Country clustering in comparative political economy. MPIfG Discussion Paper 09(5), Max Planck Institute for the Study of Societies.

  • Amable, B. 2003: The diversity of modern capitalism. Oxford University Press: Oxford.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Babos, P. 2010: Varieties of capitalism in central and Eastern Europe: Measuring the co-ordination index of a national economy. SEER: Journal for labour and social affairs in Eastern Europe 13(4): 439–457.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bambra, C. 2007: Defamilisation and welfare state regimes: A cluster analysis. International Journal of Social Welfare 16(4): 326–338.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bartlett, W. 2007: The western Balkans. In Varieties of Capitalism in Post-Communist countries, Lane, D and Myant, M (eds) Palgrave Macmillan: Basingstoke, pp. 201–220.

  • Bohle, D and Greskovits, B. 2012: Capitalist diversity at Europe’s periphery. Cornell University Press: Ithaca.

    Google Scholar 

  • Buchen, C. 2007: Estonia and Slovenia as antipodes. In Varieties of Capitalism in Post-Communist Countries, Lane, D and Myant, M (eds) Palgrave Macmillan: Basingstoke, pp. 65–89.

  • Castles, F and Obinger, H. 2008: Worlds, families, regimes: Country clusters in European and OECD area public policy. West European Politics 31(1–2): 321–344.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cernat, L. 2006: Europeanization, Varieties of Capitalism and economic performance in Central and Eastern Europe. Palgrave Macmillan: Basingstoke.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Crowley, S. 2008: Does labour still matter? East European labour and varieties of capitalism. NCEEER Working Paper, The National Council for Eurasian and East European Research.

  • Danforth, B. (2014) Worlds of welfare in time: A historical reassessment of the three-world typology. Journal of European Social Policy 24(2): 164–182.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Eckey, H, Kosfeld, R and Rengers, M. 2002: Multivariate Statistik: Grundlagen, Methoden, Beispiele. Gabler: Wiesbaden.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Esping-Andersen, G. 1990: The Three Worlds of Welfare Capitalism. Princeton University Press: Princeton.

    Google Scholar 

  • Farkas, B. 2011: The Central and Eastern European model of capitalism. Post-Communist Economies 23(1): 15–34.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Feldmann, M. 2006: Emerging varieties for capitalism in transition countries: Industrial relations and wage bargaining in Estonia and Slovenia. Comparative Political Studies 39(7): 829–854.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Feldmann, M. 2008: The origins of VoC: Lessons from post-socialist transition in Estonia and Slovenia. In: Beyond Varieties of Capitalism: Conflict, contradictions and complementarities in the European economy. Hancké, B, Rhodes, M amd Thatcher, M (eds) Oxford University Press: Oxford, pp. 328–351.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fenger, M. 2007: Welfare regimes in Central and Eastern Europe: Incorporating post-communist countries in a welfare regime typology. In Contemporary Issues and Ideas in Social Sciences, Ministry of Social Affairs and Employment: The Netherlands.

    Google Scholar 

  • Foders, F, Piazolo, D and Schweickert, R. 2002: Ready to join the EU? On the status of reform in the candidate countries. World Economics 3(4): 43–72.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gough, I. 2001: Social assistance regimes: a cluster analysis. Journal of European Social Policy 11(2): 165–170.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hall, P. 2012: The economics and politics of the Euro Crisis. German Politics 21(4): 355–371.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hall, P and Soskice, D. 2001: An introduction to varieties of capitalism. In: Varieties of Capitalism: The institutional Foundations of Comparative Advantage. Hall, P and Soskice, D (eds) Oxford University Press: Oxford, pp. 1–68.

  • Hancké, B. 2013: Unions, Central Banks and the EMU: Labour Market Institutions and Monetary Integration in Europe. Oxford University Press: Oxford.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Hassel, A. 2014: Adjustments in the Eurozone: Varieties of capitalism and the crisis in Southern Europe. LSE Europe in Question Discussion Paper Series No. 76/2014, London School of Economics.

  • Iversen, T and Wren, A. 1998: Equality, employment and budgetary restraint: The trilemma of the service economy. World Politics 50(4): 507–546.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Johnston, A, Hancké, B and Pant, S. 2014: Comparative institutional advantage in Europe’s sovereign debt crisis. Comparative Political Studies 47(13): 1771–1800.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kangas, O. 1994: The politics of social security: on regressions, qualitative comparisons, and Cluster Analysis. In The Comparative Political Economy of the Welfare State. Janoski, T and Hicks, A (eds) Cambridge University Press: Cambridge, pp. 346–364.

  • Kautto, M. 2002: Investing in services in West European welfare states. Journal of European Social Policy 12(1): 53–65.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • King, L. 2008: Central European Capitalism in comparative perspective. In Beyond Varieties of Capitalism: Conflict, Contradictions and Complementarities in the European Economy. Hancké, B, Rhodes, M and Thatcher, M. (eds) Oxford University Press: Oxford, pp. 307–327.

  • Kitschelt, H. 2006: Leistungs- und Innovationsprobleme konservativer Sozialstaaten mit koordinierten Marktwirtschaften. In Transformationen des Kapitalismus: Festschrift für Wolfgang Streeck zum sechzigsten Geburtstag. Beckert, J (ed) Frankfurt am Main: Campus Verlag, pp. 61–90.

  • Knell, M and Shrolec, M. Diverging pathways in Central and Eastern Europe. In Varieties of Capitalism in Post-Communist countries. Lane, D and Myant, M (eds) Palgrave Macmillan: Basingstoke, pp. 40–64.

  • McMenamin, I. 2004: Varieties of Capitalist democracy: What difference does East-Central Europe Make? Journal of Public Policy 24(3): 259–274.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Molina, Ó and Rhodes, M. 2008: The political economy of adjustment in Mixed Market Economies: A study of Spain and Italy. In Beyond Varieties of Capitalism: Conflict, contradictions and complementarities in the European economy. Hancké, B, Rhodes, M and Thatcher, M (eds) Oxford University Press: Oxford, pp. 223–252.

  • Myant, M. 2007: The Czech Republic: From ‘Czech’ capitalism to ‘European’ capitalism. In Varieties of Capitalism in Post-Communist countries. Lane, D and Myant, M (eds) Palgrave Macmillan: Basingstoke, pp. 105–123.

  • Mykhnenko, V. 2007: Poland and Ukraine: Institutional structures and economic performance. In Varieties of Capitalism in Post-Communist countries. Lane, D and Myant, M (eds) Palgrave Macmillan: Basingstoke, pp. 124–145.

  • Nölke, A and Vliegenthart, A. 2009: Enlarging the varieties of capitalism: The emergence of Dependent Market Economies in East Central Europe. World Politics 61(4): 670–702.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Obinger, H and Wagschal, U. 2001 Families of nations and public policy. West European Politics 24(1): 99–114.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Powell, M and Barrientos, A. Welfare regimes and the welfare mix. European Journal of Political Research 43(1): 83–105.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pryor, F. 2005: Market economic systems. Journal of Comparative Economics 33(1): 25–46.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pryor, F. 2006: Economic systems of developing nations. Comparative Economic Studies 48(1): 77–99.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pryor, F. 2008: System as a causal force. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization 67(3–4), 545–559.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Saint-Arnaud, S and Bernard, P. 2003: Convergence or resilience? A hierarchical cluster analysis of the welfare regimes in advanced countries. Current Sociology 51(5): 499–527.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schneider, M and Paunescu, M. Changing varieties of capitalism and revealed comparative advantage from 1990 to 2005: A test of the Hall and Soskice claims. Socio-economic Review 10(4): 731–753.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schröder, M. 2013: Integrating Varieties of Capitalism and Welfare State Research: A Unified Typology of Capitalisms. Palgrave Macmillan: Basingstoke.

    Book  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgments

Rainer Schweickert received funding for this research from the European Union’s Seventh Framework Programme for research, technological development and demonstration under grant agreement no. 290647.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Markus Ahlborn.

Appendix

Appendix

Appendix Table 4

Table 4 Cluster history, 1995–2009

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Ahlborn, M., Ahrens, J. & Schweickert, R. Large-Scale Transition of Economic Systems – Do CEECs Converge Toward Western Prototypes?. Comp Econ Stud 58, 430–454 (2016). https://doi.org/10.1057/s41294-016-0009-x

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1057/s41294-016-0009-x

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation