Skip to main content
Log in

Political Competition and Pork-Barrel Politics in the Allocation of Public Investment in Mexico

  • Published:
Public Choice Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This paper examines theeffect of political competition in localelections in regional allocation of publicinvestment. The study employs data onMexican elections covering the period 1990–95, characterisedby an increase in electoral competition and coupled withincreasing demands for decentralisationthroughout the states. Empirical evidencesupports the hypothesis that regionalallocation of public investment by centralgovernment was driven by `politicalopportunism' and `local pork-barrelpolitics'. A positive relationship wasfound between the regional allocation ofpublic investment and support for thecentral ruling party. This might indicatethat local spending inefficiencies werepartially explained by the specific supportfor the incumbent party.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

References

  • Aguilar Camin, H. and Meyer, L. (1993). The shadow of the Mexican revolution: Contemporary Mexican history 1910–1989. University of Texas.

  • Alesina, A. and Tabellini, G. (1990). A positive theory of fiscal deficits and government debt.Review of Economic Studies 57: 403–414.

    Google Scholar 

  • Alesina, A., Cohen, G.D. and Roubini, N. (1991). Macroeconomic policy and elections in OECD democracies. NBER Working Paper 3830. Cambridge, MA: NBER.

    Google Scholar 

  • Banamex (1995). Data Bank, Economic Studies Department.

  • Bhargava, A.L., Franzini, L. and Narendranathan, W. (1982). Serial correlation and fixed effects model. Review of Economic Studies 49: 533–549.

    Google Scholar 

  • Barro, R. and Gordon, D. (1983). Rules, discretion, and reputation in a model of monetary policy. Journal of Monetary Economics 12: 101–122.

    Google Scholar 

  • Becker, G.S. (1983). A theory of competition among pressure groups for political influence. Quarterly Journal of Economics 98: 371–400.

    Google Scholar 

  • Besley, T. and Case, A. (1993). Does electoral accountability affect economic policy choices? Evidence from gubernatorial term limits. NBER Working papers 4575. Cambridge, MA: NBER.

    Google Scholar 

  • Besley, T. and Case, A. (1995). Incumbent behaviour: Vote-seeking, tax-setting, and yardstick competition. American Economic Review 85: 25–45.

    Google Scholar 

  • Breton, A. (1996). Competitive governments: An economic theory of politics and public finance. University of Toronto.

  • Buchanan, J.M. and Wagner, R.E. (1977). Democracy in deficit. New York: Academic Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Coughlin, P. (1982). Expectations about voter choices. Public Choice 44: 49–59.

    Google Scholar 

  • Coughlin, P. (1984). Elections and income redistribution. Public Choice: 50: 27–91.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cukierman, A. (1992). Central Bank strategy, credibility and independence: Theory and evidence. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Downs, A. (1957). An economic theory of democracy. New York: Harper and Row.

    Google Scholar 

  • Enelow, J.M. and Hinich, M.J. (1984). The spatial theory of voting. Cambridge University Press.

  • Hibbs, D. (1977). Political parties and macroeconomic policy. The American political science review 71: 1467–1487.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hibbs, D. (1987). The American political economy. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hirschman, A.O. (1958). The strategy of economic development. New Haven: Yale University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Katz, I. (1986). Party government: Rationalistic conception. In Castles, F.G. and Wilderman, R. (Eds.), Visions and realities of party government. Berlin: de Gryteer.

    Google Scholar 

  • Katz, I. (1999). La constitución y el desarrollo económico de México. Mexico City: Cal y Arena-CIDAC.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kyland, F. and Prescott, E. (1977). Rules rather than discretion: The inconsistency of optimal plans. Journal of Political Economy 85: 473–492.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lisomani, M. and Navarra, P. (2001). Local pork-barrel politics in national pre-election dates: The case of Italy. Public Choice 106: 317–326.

    Google Scholar 

  • Loaeza, S. (1995). Context of Mexican policy. MIMEO.

  • Lujambio, A. (1995). Federalismo y congreso en el cambio político de México. UNAM: Instituto de Investigaciones Jurídicas).

    Google Scholar 

  • Migué, J.L. (1997). Public choice in a federal system. Public Choice 90: 235–254.

    Google Scholar 

  • Molinar, J. and Weldon, J. (1994). Electoral determinants and consequences of national solidarity.In Cornelius, N., Craig, A. and Fox, J. (Eds.), Transforming state-society relations in Mexico, the national solidarity strategy. San Diego: Center for US-Mexican Studies, University of California).

    Google Scholar 

  • Mueller, D.C. and Murrell, P. (1986). Interest groups and the size of government. Public Choice 48: 125–145.

    Google Scholar 

  • Musgrave, R. (1969). Fiscal systems. New Haven: Yale University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Nordhaus, W. (1975). The political business cycle. The Review of Economic Studies 42: 169– 190.

    Google Scholar 

  • Nordhaus, W. (1989). Alternative approaches to the political business cycle. Brooking Papers on Economic Activity 2: 1–68.

    Google Scholar 

  • Oates, W. (1968). The theory of public finance in a federal system. Canadian Journal of Economics 1: 37–54.

    Google Scholar 

  • Oates, W. (1990). Decentralization of the public sector: An overview. In Bennet, R. (Ed.), Decentralization, local governments and markets: Towards a post-welfare agenda?.Oxford.

  • Ordeshook, P.C. (1997). The spatial analysis of elections and committees: Four elections of research. In Mueller, D.C. (Ed.), Perspectives on public choice: A handbook, 247–270.Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Person, T. and Svensson, L. (1989). Why a stubborn conservative would run a deficit: Policy with time consistent preferences. Quarterly Journal of Economics 104: 325–345.

    Google Scholar 

  • Petchey, J. (2000). Political competition and voter mobility. Public Choice 105: 231–243.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rodriguez, V. (1999). Decentralization in Mexico, from reforma municipal to solidaridad to nuevo federalismo. Boulder: Westview Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rodriguez-Oreggia, E. and Costa-Font, J. (2001). Desigualdades regionales e integracion económica: México y España. Comercio Exterior 51: 457–461.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rogers, D.L. and Rogers, J.H. (2000). Political competition and state government size: Do tighter elections produce looser budgets?. Public Choice 105: 1–21.

    Google Scholar 

  • Schumpeter, J. (1942). Capitalism, socialism and democracy. New York: Harper.

    Google Scholar 

  • Stevens, J. (1993). The economics of collective choice. Boulder, Westview Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tiebout, C. (1956). A pure theory of local expenditures. Journal of Political Economy 64: 416–424.

    Google Scholar 

  • World Bank (1999). Beyond the center: Decentralizing the state. Washington, DC: World Bank Latin American and Caribbean Studies.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Costa-i-Font, J., Rodriguez-Oreggia, E. & Lunapla, D. Political Competition and Pork-Barrel Politics in the Allocation of Public Investment in Mexico. Public Choice 116, 185–204 (2003). https://doi.org/10.1023/A:1024263208736

Download citation

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1023/A:1024263208736

Keywords

Navigation