Skip to main content
Log in

A Competing Risks Model of Supreme Court Vacancies, 1789–1992

  • Published:
Political Behavior Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

We hypothesize that Supreme Court justices will consider the likely ideological disposition of their successor in their decision to retire or remain on the Court. Furthermore, because a justice's decision to remain on the Court places him or her “at risk” of dying in office, it is necessary to consider a model of both voluntary and involuntary vacancies. Our study examines three broad classes of factors influential to Supreme Court vacancies: personal considerations, institutional context, and political influences. We assess the factors that affect the probability of a vacancy on the U.S. Supreme Court due to mortality and retirement at the individual level from 1789 to 1992, using a competing risk duration model and incorporating time-varying covariates. We find significant differences in the hazards of vacancy due to these two causes, and a number of factors are shown to influence the probability of a vacancy, including a general propensity to retire near the beginning of presidents' second terms. However, we find little evidence of the influence of political factors in either retirement-or death-related vacancies, suggesting that justices who retire do not generally do so for expressly political reasons and those who die in office rarely do so as a result of “holding out” for a like-minded replacement.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

REFERENCES

  • Abraham, Henry J. (1999). Justices and Presidents and Senators: A History ofthe U.S. Supreme Court Appointments from Washington to Clinton, New and Revised ed. New York: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Atkinson, David N. (1976). Retirement and death on the United States Supreme Court: from Van Devanter to Douglas. University ofMissouri Kansas City Law Review 45: 1–27.

    Google Scholar 

  • Atkinson, David N. (1999). Leaving the Bench: Supreme Court Justices at the End. Lawrence: The University Press of Kansas.

    Google Scholar 

  • Barrow, Deborah, and Zuk, Gary. (1990). An institutional analysis of turnover in the lower federal courts. Journal ofPolitics 52: 457–476.

    Google Scholar 

  • Baum, Lawrence. (1992). Membership change and collective voting change in the United States Supreme Court. Journal ofPolitics 54: 3–24.

    Google Scholar 

  • Baum, Lawrence. (1997). The Puzzle ofJudicial Behavior. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Beck, Nathaniel, Katz, Jonathan N., and Tucker, Richard. (1998). Taking time seriously: time-series-cross-section analysis with a binary dependent variable. American Journal of Political Science 42: 1260–1288.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bennett, D. Scott. (1999). Parametric models, duration dependence, and time-varying data revisited. American Journal of Political Science 43: 256–270.

    Google Scholar 

  • Biskupic, Joan. (1994). ”I Am Not an Uncle Tom,” Thomas says at meeting; Justice speaks to select group of blacks. The Washington Post (Oct. 28) 1:A1.

  • Blossfeld, Hans-Peter, and Rohwer, Gö tz. (1995). Techniques of Event History Modeling. Mahwah, NJ: Lawrence Erlbaum.

    Google Scholar 

  • Box-Steffensmeier, Janet M., Arnold, Laura W., and Zorn, Christopher J. W. (1997). The strategic timing of position taking in the U.S. Congress: a study of the North American Free Trade Agreement. American Political Science Review 91: 324–338.

    Google Scholar 

  • Box-Steffensmeier, Janet M., and Jones, Bradford. (1997). Time is of the essence: event history models in political science. American Journal of Political Science 41(October): 1414–1461.

    Google Scholar 

  • Box-Steffensmeier, Janet M., and Jones, Bradford. (2000). Timing and Political Change: Event History Analysis in Political Science. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Butler, J. S., Anderson, Kathryn H., and Burkhauser, Richard V. (1989). Work and health after retirement: a competing risks model with semiparametric unobserved heterogeneity. The Review ofEconomics and Statistics 71: 46–53.

    Google Scholar 

  • Caldeira, Gregory A., and Smith, Charles E., Jr. (1996). Campaigning for the Supreme Court: the dynamics of public opinion on the Thomas nomination. Journal ofPolitics 58: 655–681.

    Google Scholar 

  • Caldeira, Gregory A., Wright, John R., and Zorn, Christopher J. W. (1999). Strategic voting and gatekeeping in the Supreme Court. Journal ofLaw, Economics and Organization 15: 549–572.

    Google Scholar 

  • Caldeira, Gregory A., and Zorn, Christopher J. W. (1998). Of time and consensual norms in the Supreme Court. American Journal ofPolitical Science 42: 874–902.

    Google Scholar 

  • Callen, E., and Leidecker, H., Jr. (1971). A mean life on the Supreme Court. American Bar Association Journal 57: 1188–1192.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cohen, Jeffrey E. (1986). On the tenure of appointive political executives: the American cabinet, 1952–84. American Journal of Political Science 30: 507–516.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cox, D. R. (1972). Regression models and life tables. Journal ofthe Royal Statistical Society, Series B 34: 187–220.

    Google Scholar 

  • Danelski, David J. (1964). A Supreme Court Justice Is Appointed. New York: Random House.

    Google Scholar 

  • David, H. A., and Moeschberger, M. L. (1978). The Theory of Competing Risks. New York: MacMillan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ellis, Richard E. (1992). Gabriel Duvall. In Kermit L. Hall (ed.), The Oxford Companion to the Supreme Court ofthe United States. New York: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Epstein, Lee, and Knight, Jack. (1998). The Choices Justices Make. Washington, DC: Congressional Quarterly Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Filer, Randall K., and Petri, Peter. (1988). A job-characteristics theory of retirement. The Review ofEconomics and Statistics 70: 123–128.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fish, Peter G. (1992). Disability of justices. In Kermit L. Hall (ed.), The Oxford Companion to the Supreme Court ofthe United States. New York: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Flemming, Roy B., and Wood B. Dan. (1997). The public and the Supreme Court: individual justice responsiveness to American policy moods. American Journal of Political Science 41: 468–498.

    Google Scholar 

  • Friedman, Leon, and Israel, Fred L. (1997). The Justices ofthe United States Supreme Court: Their Lives and Major Opinions. New York: Chelsea House.

    Google Scholar 

  • Goldman, Sheldon. (1997). Picking Federal Judges. New Haven: Yale University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gustman, Alan L., and Steinmeier, Thomas L. (1986). A structural retirement model. Econometrica 54: 555–584.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hagle, Timothy M. (1993). Strategic retirements: a political model of turnover on the United States Supreme Court. Political Behavior 15: 25–48.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hall, Richard L., and van Houweling, Robert P. (1995). Avarice and ambition in Congress: representatives' decisions to run or retire from the U.S. House. American Political Science Review 89: 121–136.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hayward, Mark D., Grady, William R., Hardy, Melissa A., and Sommers, David. (1989). Occupational influences on retirement, disability, and death. Demography 26: 393–409.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hibbing, John R. (1982). Voluntary retirement from the U.S. House of Representatives: who quits? American Journal of Political Science 26: 467–484.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kahn, Ronald. (1999). Institutional norms and Supreme Court decision-making: the Rehnquist Court on privacy and religion. In Cornell W. Clayton and Howard Gillman (eds.), Supreme Court Decision Making: New Institutionalist Approaches. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kiewiet, D. Roderick, and Zeng, Langche. (1993). An analysis of congressional career decisions, 1947–1986. American Political Science Review 87: 928–941.

    Google Scholar 

  • King, Gary. (1987). Presidential appointments to the Supreme Court: adding systematic explanation to probabilistic description. American Politics Quarterly 15: 373–386.

    Google Scholar 

  • Laird, Nan, and Oliver, Donald. (1981). Covariance analysis of censored survival data using log-linear analysis techniques. Journal ofthe American Statistical Association 96: 231–240.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lancaster, Tony. (1990). The Econometric Analysis ofTransition Data. New York: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lozier, G. Gregory, and Dooris, Michael. (1991). Projecting faculty retirement: factors influencing individual decisions. The American Economic Review 81: 101–105.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lurie, Jonathan. (1992). William Howard Taft. In Kermit L. Hall (ed.), The Oxford Companion to the Supreme Court ofthe United States. New York: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mason, Alpheus T. (1956). Harlan Fiske Stone: Pillar of the Law. New York: Viking.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mason, Alpheus T. (1964). William Howard Taft: Chief Justice. New York: Simon and Schuster.

    Google Scholar 

  • Moraski, Bryon J., and Shipan, Charles. (1999). The politics of Supreme Court nominations: a theory of institutional constraints and choices. American Journal of Political Science 43: 1069–1095.

    Google Scholar 

  • Murphy, Walter F. (1961). In his own image: Mr. Chief Justice Taft and Supreme Court appointments. In Philip B. Kurland (ed.), The Supreme Court Review. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Murphy, Walter F. (1964). Elements ofJudicial Strategy. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mutran, Elizabeth, and Reitzes, Donald C. (1989). Labor force participation and health: a cohort comparison of older male workers. Social Science Quarterly 70: 449–467.

    Google Scholar 

  • Palmer, Harvey D., and Vogel, Ronald J. (1995). Political opportunity for federal appointment: the case of departing members of the U.S. House of Representatives, 1961– 1992. Journal of Politics 57: 677–695.

    Google Scholar 

  • Reitzes, Donald C., Mutran, Elizabeth J., and Fernandez, Maria E. (1998). The decision to retire: a career perspective. Social Science Quarterly 79: 607–619.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ruckman, P.S., Jr. (1993). The Supreme Court, critical nominations, and the senate confirmation process. Journal of Politics 55: 793–805.

    Google Scholar 

  • Segal, Jeffrey A., Cameron, Charles M., and Cover, Albert D. (1992). A spatial model of roll call voting: senators, constituents, presidents, and interest groups in supreme court confirmations. American Journal of Political Science 36: 96–121.

    Google Scholar 

  • Simon, James F. (1980). Independent Journey. New York: Harper & Row.

    Google Scholar 

  • Spriggs, James F. II, and Wahlbeck, Paul J. (1995). Calling it quits: strategic retirements on the federal courts of appeals, 1893–1991. Political Research Quarterly 48(3): 573–597.

    Google Scholar 

  • Squire, Peverill. (1988). Politics and personal factors in retirement from the United States Supreme Court. Political Behavior 10: 180–190.

    Google Scholar 

  • Stock, James H., and Wise, David A. (1990). Pensions, the option value of work, and retirement. Econometrica 58: 1151–1180.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sueyoshi, Glenn T. (1992). Semiparametric proportional hazards estimation of competing risks models with time-varying covariates. Journal of Econometrics 51: 25–58.

    Google Scholar 

  • Teachman, Jay D., and Hayward, Mark D. (1993). Interpreting hazard rate models. Sociological Methods and Research 21: 340–371.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ulmer, S. Sidney. (1982). Supreme Court Nominations as a Poisson Distribution. American Journal of Political Science 26: 113–116.

    Google Scholar 

  • Walker, Thomas G., Epstein, Lee J., and Dixon, William J. (1988). On the mysterious demise of consensual norms in the United States Supreme Court. Journal of Politics 50: 361–389.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wallis, W.A. (1936). The Poisson distribution and the Supreme Court. Journal of the American Statistical Association 31: 376–380.

    Google Scholar 

  • White, Halbert. (1980). A heteroskedasticity-consistent covariance matrix estimator and a direct test for heteroskedasticity. Econometrica 48: 817–830.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Zorn, C.J.W., Van Winkle, S.R. A Competing Risks Model of Supreme Court Vacancies, 1789–1992. Political Behavior 22, 145–166 (2000). https://doi.org/10.1023/A:1006667601289

Download citation

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1023/A:1006667601289

Keywords

Navigation